Classical economics

From New World Encyclopedia


Schools of economics

History of economic thought

Pre-modern

Early economic thought

Early Modern

Mercantilism · Physiocrats

Modern

Classical Economics
English historical school · German historical school
Socialist economics · Neoclassical economics
Lausanne school · Austrian school

Twentieth-century

Institutional economics · Stockholm school
Keynesian economics · Chicago school

Classical economics is widely regarded as the first modern school of economic thought. Its major developers include Adam Smith, David Ricardo, Thomas Malthus and John Stuart Mill.


The term 'Classical' refers to work done by a group of economists in the 18th and 19th centuries. Much of this work was developing theories about the way markets and market economies work. Much of this work has subsequently been updated by modern economists and they are generally termed neo-classical economists, the word neo meaning 'new'.

Foundations

Classical economics refers to the school of economic thought that arose in Great Britain in the latter part of the eighteenth century. In the year 1776, David Hume died while Jacques Turgot and Marquis de Condorcet left their government posts. In that same year, though, the intellectual revolution they had contributed to, the Enlightenment, began to bear its principal fruit. It was a year of grand treatises. Adam Smith published his Wealth of Nations, the Abbé de Condillac his Commerce et le Gouvernement, Jeremy Bentham his Fragments on Government, and Tom Paine his Common Sense.

It was Smith's work that has been seen as laying the foundation of economics as a separate academic discipline. The central messages of his Wealth of Nations (1776) were laissez-faire—the virtues of specialization, free trade and competition, and so forth. Smith's vision of a free market economy, based on secure property, capital accumulation, widening markets, and a division of labor contrasted with the mercantilist tendency to attempt to "regulate all evil human actions" (Smith 1776).

Essentially this approach places total reliance on markets, and anything that prevent markets clearing properly should be done away with. The earlier belief that agriculture was the chief determinant of economic health was also rejected in favor of the development of manufacturing, and the importance of labor productivity was stressed. The theories put forward by the classical economists still influence economics to this day.

The classical economists strongly believed that the government should not intervene to try to correct this as it would only make things worse and so the only way to encourage growth was to allow free trade and free markets. Much of Adam Smith's early work was on this theme, and he introduced the notion of an "invisible hand" that guided economic activity and led to the optimum equilibrium.

Following Smith, in the struggle for succession as the voice of economic theorizing, three names emerged as strong contenders:

These three had very different visions. Say (1803) wanted to take economic thought back towards the French-Italian demand-and-supply tradition. Malthus (1798, 1820) wanted to add a whole new emphasis, away from the obsessive intricacies of "value" and towards a more macroeconomic (and "dynamic") perspective. As Smith's laissez-faire approach, including specialization, free trade, and so forth, did not anticipate the magnitude of the economic and social upheavals that the industrial era was about to unleash, a new version, corrected, extended, and updated, was clearly needed. Ricardo (1817) wanted to do Smith all over again, but to do it properly this time.

Hence, out of these three, David Ricardo turned out to be the most successful and influential. With his 1817 treatise, Ricardo took economics to an unprecedented degree of theoretical sophistication. Ricardo's theory, the most clearly and consistently formalized of them all, became the Classical system.

Coming at the end of the Classical tradition, John Stuart Mill parted company with the earlier classical economists on the inevitability of the distribution of income produced by the market system. Mill pointed to a distinct difference between the market's two roles: allocation of resources and distribution of income. The market might be efficient in allocating resources but not in distributing income, he wrote, making it necessary for society to intervene.

Adam Smith

Main article: Adam Smith
Adam Smith

Adam Smith was a Scottish political economist, lecturer, and essayist. His An Inquiry in to the Cause of the Wealth of Nations (1776) represents a highly critical commentary on mercantilism, the prevailing economic system of Smith's day. Mercantilism emphasized the maximizing of exports and the minimizing of imports. In Wealth of Nations Smith argued that everyone benefits from the removal of tariffs and other barriers to trade. Because of supply and demand, production will increase as demand increases. This may lead to new employment opportunities for the workforce and to collateral industries emerging in response to new demands. For example, an increase in France's wine production would also lead to an increased demand for bottles, for barrels, for cork, and an increase in shipping, thus leading to a variety of new employment opportunities.

Adam Smith was convinced that the market would stimulate development, improve living conditions, reduce social strife, and create an atmosphere that was conducive to peace and human cooperation. In his view, a balance had to exist between self interest and sympathy, with sympathy being the guiding moral imperative. Competition would emerge and serve as a check to profiteering and unfair pricing. Smith made compelling arguments for the free market and his economic and moral writings remain relevant today. Wealth of Nations serves as one of the most elegant explanations for the rapid economic growth experienced by the United States and other industrial powers in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries.

Jean-Baptiste Say

Main article: Jean-Baptiste Say
File:Jean-Baptiste Say.png
Jean-Baptiste Say

Jean-Baptiste Say (1767-1832) was a Frenchman, born in Lyon who helped to popularize Adam Smith's work in France (Fusfeld 1994, 47). He had classically liberal views and argued in favor of competition, free trade, and lifting restraints on business. Say did not, however, agree with Smith's labor theory of value that the value of a commodity depends on the labor involved in its production, arguing instead that value derives from its ability to satisfy the desires or needs of the consumer.

His most significant contribution is the thesis contained in his book, A Treatise on Political Economy (1803), that supply creates its own demand. This later became orthodoxy in political economics until the Great Depression and known as Say's Law of markets. Say argued that there could never be a general deficiency of demand or a general glut of commodities in the whole economy. Thus he supported the laissez-faire position of Adam Smith, stating that overproduction in one market will naturally return to balance without government interference as the producer will either adjust production to different items or adjust prices until the goods sell. He argued that production is not a question of supply, but an indication of producers demanding goods. Production is demand, so it is impossible for production to outrun demand, or for there to be a "general glut" of supply. At most, there will be different economic sectors whose demands are not fulfilled. But over time supplies will shift, businesses will retool for different production, and the market will correct itself. An example of a "general glut" could be unemployment, in other words, too great a supply of workers, and too few jobs. Say's Law advocates would suggest that this necessarily means there is an excess demand for other products that will correct itself. This remained a foundation of economic theory until the 1930s. However one political economist, Malthus, was unconvinced.

Thomas Robert Malthus

Main article: Thomas Robert Malthus
Malthus cautioned law makers on the effects of poverty reduction policies

Thomas Robert Malthus (1766-1834) was a Tory minister in the United Kingdom Parliament who, contrasting to Bentham, believed in strict government abstention from social ills. Malthus devoted the last chapter of his book Principles of Political Economy (1820) to rebutting Say's law, and argued that the economy could stagnate with a lack of "effectual demand." In other words, wages if less than the total costs of production cannot purchase the total output of industry and that this would cause prices to fall. Price falls cause incentives to invest, and the spiral could continue indefinitely. Malthus is more notorious however for his earlier work, An Essay on the Principle of Population. This argued that intervention was impossible because of two factors. "Food is necessary to the existence of man," wrote Malthus. "The passion between the sexes is necessary and will remain nearly in its present state," he added, meaning that the "power of the population is infinitely greater than the power in the Earth to produce subsistence for man." Nevertheless growth in population is checked by "misery and vice." Any increase in wages for the masses would cause only a temporary growth in population, which given the constraints in the supply of the Earth's produce would lead to misery, vice and a corresponding readjustment to the original population. However more labor could mean more economic growth, either one of which was able to be produced by an accumulation of capital.

David Ricardo

Main article: David Ricardo
Ricardo is renowned for his law of comparative advantage

David Ricardo (1772-1823) was born in London, and by the age of 26 had become a wealthy stock market trader. He bought himself a constituency seat in Ireland to gain a platform in the House of Commons in the Parliament of the United Kingdom. Ricardo's best known work is his Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, which contains his critique of barriers to international trade. The Corn Laws of the UK had been passed in 1815, setting a fluctuating system of tariffs to stabilize the price of wheat in the domestic market. Ricardo argued that raising tariffs, despite being intended to benefit the incomes of farmers, would merely produce a rise in the prices of rents that went into the pockets of landowners. Furthermore, extra labour would be employed leading to an increase in the cost of wages across the board, and therefore reducing exports and profits coming from overseas business. Economics for Ricardo was all about the relationship between the three "factors of production" - land, labor and capital. Ricardo demonstrated mathematically that the gains from trade would outweigh the perceived advantages of protectionist policy. The law of comparative advantage suggests that even if one country is inferior at producing all of its goods than another, it may still benefit from opening its borders since the inflow of good produced more cheaply than at home produces a gain for domestic consumers. Say that in two days in England an average worker produces a bushel of wheat and in one day a yard of cloth, while the average French worker can do either in just a day. If England swops the wheat it produces (one day's production) for French cloth (while English cloth takes two days) then both sides can strike a bargain between the margin that is mutually beneficial. England by selling its wheat can get its cloth in a day, rather than two days, and France can get an extra bushel of wheat for selling its more efficiently produced cloth. This would lead to a shift in prices so that eventually England would be producing goods in which its comparative advantages were the highest.

John Stuart Mill

Main article: John Stuart Mill
Mill, brought up on the philosophy of Jeremy Bentham, wrote the most authoritative economics text of the time

John Stuart Mill (1806-1873) was the dominant figure of political economic thought of his time, as well as being a Member of Parliament for the seat of Westminster, and a leading political philosopher. Mill was a child prodigy, reading Ancient Greek from the age of 3, and being vigorously schooled by his father James Mill. Jeremy Bentham was a close mentor and family friend, and Mill was heavily influenced by David Ricardo. Mill's textbook, first published in 1848 and titled Principles of Political Economy was essentially a summary of the economic wisdom of the mid nineteenth century (Pressman 2006, 44). It was used as the standard texts by most universities well into the beginning of the twentieth century. On the question of economic growth Mill tried to find a middle ground between Adam Smith's view of ever expanding opportunities for trade and technological innovation and Thomas Malthus' view of the inherent limits of population. In his fourth book Mill set out a number of possible future outcomes, rather than predicting one in particular. The first followed the Malthusian line that population grew quicker than supplies, leading to falling wages and rising profits. The second, per Smith, said if capital accumulated faster than population grew then real wages would rise. Third, echoing David Ricardo, should capital accumulate and population increase at the same rat, yet technology stay stable, there would be no change in real wages because supply and demand for labor would be the same. However growing populations would require more land use, increasing food production costs and therefore decreasing profits. The fourth alternative was that technology advanced faster than population and capital stock increased. The result would be a prospering economy. Mill felt the third scenario most likely, and he assumed technology advanced would have to end at some point (Pressman 2006, 45). But on the prospect of continuing economic growth, Mill was more ambivalent.

"I confess I am not charmed with the ideal of life held out by those who think that the normal state of human beings is that of struggling to get on; that the trampling, crushing, elbowing, and treading on each other's heels, which form the existing type of social life, are the most desirable lot of human kind, or anything but the disagreeable symptoms of one of the phases of industrial progress (Mill 1871).

Mill is also credited with being the first person to speak of supply and demand as a relationship rather than mere quantities of goods on markets (Stigler 1965, 1-15) the concept of opportunity cost and the rejection of the wage fund doctrine (Pressman 2006, 46).

Classical Theory

Classical theories revolved mainly around the role of markets in the economy. If markets worked freely and nothing prevented their rapid clearing then the economy would prosper. Any imperfections in the market that prevented this process should be dealt with by government. The main roles of government are therefore to ensure the free workings of markets using 'supply-side policies' and to ensure a balanced budget.

The main theories used to justify this view were the "Free market theory," "Say's Law," and the "Quantity theory of money."

Free market theory

Classical economists assumed that if the economy was left to itself, then it would tend to full employment equilibrium. This would happen if the labor market worked properly. If there was any unemployment, then the following would happen:

UNEMPLOYMENT ——>INCREASED DEMAND FOR LABOR ——>FALL IN WAGES ——>EQUILIBRIUM RESTORED

As the "Demand curve" illustrates, it is argued that there is an inverse relationship between the wage rate (or price of labor) , depicted on the vertical (price) axis P, and the quantity of labor demanded, which is depicted (as quantity of any other goods) on the horizontal (quantity) axis Q. There is also a “supply” (of labor) curve S in this Diagram.

An example of a "Demand curve" following the classical economics view. The demand curve is defined as the graph depicting the relationship between the price of a certain commodity, and the amount of it that consumers are willing and able to purchase at that given price.

This negative relationship between the wage and the quantity of labor demanded is the result of two effects:

A substitution effect

Suppose that the wage rate increases in the “demand” curve from D1 to D2. The substitution effect of the wage increase involves the substitution of other resources (such as capital, energy, materials, and other categories of labor) for the category of labor that has become more expensive. As the wage rate rises from P1 to P2, the substitution effect results in a reduction in the quantity of labor demanded; from Q2 to Q1. Note that the “supply” of labor S is constant all through the process.

An equilibrium occurs in a labor market at the combination of wages and employment at which market demand and supply intersect (as illustrated in the diagram).

If the wage rate is above the equilibrium, the quantity of labor supplied exceeds the quantity demanded and a surplus occurs. In this case, the existence of unemployed workers will be expected to result in downward pressure on the wage rate until an equilibrium is restored.

If the wage rate is below the equilibrium, a labor shortage will occur. Competition among firms for workers is expected to result in increases in the wage until an equilibrium occurs.

A scale effect

The scale effect resulting from a wage increase is a bit more complex. As the wage rate rises, the scale effect involves the following chain of effects:

  1. higher wages result in higher average and marginal costs of production,
  2. higher average and marginal and average costs result in an increase in the equilibrium price of the product,
  3. as the price of the product rises, the equilibrium quantity of the product demanded declines (a reduction in the "scale" of production), and
  4. the reduction in output results in a reduction in the quantity of all inputs used to produce this product (including this category of labor).

Say’s Law: Supply-side policies

Hence, classical economists were of the view that the economy is self-adjusting. In fact, in their view, because the economy tends to full-employment, there is no need for government to actively intervene. In fact intervention may simply be destabilizing and inflationary. The key to long-term stable economic growth is therefore:

  • Ensure free markets with no imperfections (through supply-side policies); and
  • control the growth of the money supply to ensure low inflation.

Jean-Baptiste Say was adamant in his opposition to government intervention into the economy. Most succinctly stated, he declared that self-interest and the search for profits will push entrepreneurs toward satisfying consumer demand. "the nature of the products is always regulated by the wants of society," therefore "legislative interference is superfluous altogether" (Say 1803, 144).

It was in his Treatise (Say 1803) that Say outlined his famous Law of Markets. Roughly stated, Say's Law claims that total demand in an economy cannot exceed or fall below total supply in that economy or, as James Mill was to restate it, "supply creates its own demand." In Say's language, "products are paid for with products" (Say 1803, 153) or "a glut can take place only when there are too many means of production applied to one kind of product and not enough to another" (Say 1803, 178-179).

Using supply-side policies can be seen in the above Diagram when we assume only one price level, say, P1 and we increase the level of output from Q1 to Q2, while the price level P1 has remained stable. Supply-side policies as we have said are ones that reduce market imperfections. They may include:

  • Improving education and training to make the work-force more occupationally mobile,
  • reducing the level of benefits to increase the incentive for people to work,
  • reducing taxation to encourage enterprise and encourage hard work,
  • policies to make people more geographically mobile (ending rent controls, simplifying house buying, and so forth),
  • reducing the power of trade unions to allow wages to be more flexible,
  • removing any capital controls, and
  • removing unnecessary regulations.

For Say, the foundation of value is utility, or the capacity of a goods or services to satisfy some human desire. Those desires and the preferences, expectations, and customs that lie behind them must be taken as givens, as data, by the analyst. The task is to reason from those data. Say is most emphatic in denying the claims of Adam Smith, David Ricardo, and others that the basis for value is labor, or "productive agency" (Say 1803, 348).

Quantity theory of money

Classical economists were concerned to control monetary growth. In this way as predicted by the Quantity theory of money they would be able to maintain low inflation.

The Quantity Theory of Money (QTM) states that there is a direct relationship between the quantity of money in an economy and the level of prices of goods and services sold. According to QTM, if the amount of money in an economy doubles, price levels also double, causing inflation (the percentage rate at which the level of prices is rising in an economy). The consumer therefore pays twice as much for the same amount of the good or service.

In its simplest form, the theory is expressed as

  • MV = PT (the Fisher Equation).

Each variable denotes the following:

M = Money Supply

V = Velocity of Circulation (the number of times money changes hands)

P = Average Price Level

T = Volume of Transactions of Goods and Services.

The original theory was considered orthodox among 17th century classical economists and was overhauled by 20th-century economists Irving Fisher, who formulated the above equation, and Milton Friedman ( Friedman, 1987 ). It is built on the principle of equation of exchange:


  • Amount of Money x Velocity of Circulation = Total Spending

Another way to understand this theory is to recognize that money is like any other commodity:

".....Money increases in its supply decrease marginal value (the buying capacity of one unit of currency)....."

So an increase in money supply causes prices to rise (inflation) as they compensate for the decrease in money’s marginal value.

Policies might include:

  • Open-market operations.
  • Funding.
  • Monetary-base control.
  • Interest rate control.

Classical Economics vs. "The Exploitation Theory"

Impact of classical economics in the 19th century: The Rationality Principle

The Ricardian notions of the limitations of the labour theory of value and, on the other side, of the comparative advantages in international trade ( Ricardo, 1951) rest on the idea that people are rational. In the first case, it is implied that people are not stupid enough to keep producing in an industry whose rate of profit would fall below the rate offered by another one employing less capital proportionally. In the second case, it is implied that traders are not stupid enough to keep producing themselves a good that they can trade with another good that they can produce. Couple of examples should clear this idea:

(1) Let us take Ricardo’s famous rent theory as another example: how could Ricardo be so sure that the farmers exploiting land of a higher quality would freely accept to pay a rent to their landowner if not because he postulates that these farmers are not stupid enough to take trouble to move to land of such a lower quality that their net profit would not be higher than the profit they presently obtain even after paying the required rent?

(2) "…..If one of the wine sellers were offering only four quarts for a bushel, the owner of the wheat will not give it to this wine seller if he knows that another will give him six or eight quarts for the same bushel……." (Lagueux , 1997 )

Similar thinking is neatly illustrated by the saga of the British Corn Laws ( enacted in 1815) and its eventual repealing thirty years later.

The Corn Laws, adopted by the Conservatives who represented the landed class who greatly benefited from the agricultural protections, were designed to keep prices high after the Napoleonic War and therefore many feared a substantial drop in prices (which in fact didn't happen). The Whigs, a competing political party in England at the time, however, were business owners.

Following David Ricardo's economic views they believed a decrease in the price of grain would allow them to lower wages and increase profits. Eventually Sir Robert Peel, the Conservative Prime Minister pushed the bill to repeal the Corn Law, through Commons and House of Lord, in 1846.


Value of Classical economic principles in today’s world: The Exploitation Theory

There are three aspects of classical economics which contribute to the exploitation theory. The two best known are:


  • The labor theory of value and
  • the iron law of wages.


Somewhat less prominent, but no less important, is the conceptual framework within which the exploitation theory is advanced. This framework is the belief that:


  • Wages are the original and primary form of income, from which profits and all other non-wage incomes emerge as a deduction with the coming of capitalism and businessmen and capitalists.


It is on the basis of these beliefs that Adam Smith opens his chapter on wages in "The Wealth of Nations" with the words:


“…..The produce of labour constitutes the natural recompense or wages of labour. In that original state of things, which precedes both the appropriation of land and the accumulation of stock, the whole produce of labour belongs to the labourer. He has neither landlord nor master to share with him…..”


In these, and other passages, Smith clearly advances the primacy of wages doctrine. That is, the doctrine that--- in a pre-capitalist economy,i.e in the "early and rude state of society" --- workers simply produce and sell commodities and do not buy in order to sell, the incomes the workers receive are wages.


“….Wages are the original income…,” according to Smith. “…..All income in the pre-capitalist society is supposed to be wages, and no income is supposed to be profit….,” according to Smith ( in op.cit. ), “…..because workers are the only recipients of income….”


At the same time, Smith advances the corollary doctrine that "...profit emerges only with the coming of capitalism and is a deduction from what is naturally and, by implication, rightfully wages...."


Within this framework, Marx applies the labor theory of value and the iron law of wages, and arrives at the exploitation theory.

Critique of the Exploitation Theory

Within this same framework, Böhm-Bawerk applies the discounting approach, and criticizes the exploitation theory ( Bohm-Bawerk, 1959. )

For classical economics implies that it is false to claim that wages are the original form of income and that profits are a deduction from them. This becomes apparent, as soon as we define our terms along classical lines:


  • "Profit" is the excess of receipts from the sale of products over the money costs of producing them—over, it must be repeated, the money costs of producing them.
  • A "capitalist" is one who buys in order subsequently to sell for a profit.


  • "Wages" are money paid in exchange for the performance of labor—not for the products of labor, but for the performance of labor itself.


On the basis of these definitions it follows that, if there are merely workers producing and selling their products, the money which they receive in the sale of their products is not wages.


"…Demand for commodities….," to quote John Stuart Mill, "….is not demand for labour….. in buying commodities, one does not pay wages, and in selling commodities, one does not receive wages. …..”( Mill, 1976. )

And in Hayek, there we find such statements as: "….The actual history of the connection between capitalism and the rise of the proletariat is almost the exact opposite of that which these theories of the expropriation of the masses suggest….." And: "……The proletariat which capitalism can be said to have 'created' was thus not a proportion of the population which would have existed without it and which it degraded to a lower level; it was an additional population which was enabled to grow up by the new opportunities for employment which capitalism provided….” ( Hayek, 1954) Finally, on the doctrine of “iron law of wages,“ the following can be said. The rising productivity of labor and correspondingly falling product prices that the businessmen and capitalists achieve take place in this context of wage rates that are determined by the independent supply of and demand for labor. Thus, as product prices fall, wage rates do not fall, and, therefore, real wages rise. (If, the quantity of money and volume of spending in the economic system remaining the same, there is a growing supply of labor while the productivity of labor rises, money wage rates fall, but prices fall by more.) Of course, to the extent that the quantity of money increases while the productivity of labor rises, the demand for labor and products both increase. As a result, the rise in real wages may be accompanied by rising money wage rates and by constant or even rising product prices. But the relationship between wages and prices will reflect the change in the productivity of labor, for that reduces product prices relative to wages, while the increase in the quantity of money operates to affect both of them more or less equally. So much for the "iron law of wages" in all its variations ( Reisman 1985.)

Summary and Conclusion

Despite the support which it seems to be giving to the exploitation theory, classical economics provides the basis for turning the exploitation theory upside down. On the basis of Ricardo's concept of profit and J. S. Mill's proposition that "demand for commodities is not demand for labour," it makes it possible to show how profits, not wages, must be regarded as the original and primary form of income, from which other incomes emerge as a deduction. Also, how the labor of businessmen and capitalists has more fundamental responsibility for the production of products than the labor of wage earners, with the result that "labor's right to the whole produce" should mean the right of businessmen and capitalists to the sales receipts—a right which is accepted as a norm every day, in the normal operations of a capitalist economy. And finally, the classical doctrines of supply and demand, the wage fund, the distinction between value and riches, and the labor theory of value ─ modified along lines suggested by Ricardo and J. S. Mill and incorporating the advances in price theory made by Böhm-Bawerk ─ make possible an explanation of real wages. Real wages, based on the productivity of labor, which, as the economic function of businessmen and capitalists, steadily increases.

References
ISBN links support NWE through referral fees

  • Böhm-Bawerk, E. von.,Capital and Interest, op. cit., Vol. I, pp. 263-71; Vol. II, pp. 259-89, Libertarian Press, South Holland, Illinois 1959
  • Fusfeld, Daniel R. 1994. The Age of the Economist. Harper Collins.
  • Hayek, F. A. ,The Road to Serfdom, University of Chicago Press, Chicago, 1944
  • Hayek, F. A. editor, Capitalism and the Historians, University of Chicago Press, Chicago, 1954, pp. 15f.
  • Hollander, J. 1910. "The Development of the Theory of Money From Adam Smith to David Ricardo," Quarterly J. of Economics.
  • Lagueux, M. 1997. The Rationality Principle and Classical Economics congrès de History of Economics Society tenu à Charleston, S.C., du 20 au 23 juin, University of Montreal.
  • Laidler, D.,The Golden Age of the Quantity Theory, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, 1991
  • Mill, John S.,Principles of Political Economy, Bk. III, Chaps. III – VI, Ashley Edition (reprint, Fairfield, New Jersey) Augustus M. Kelley 1976
  • Mises, Ludwig von, Human Action, Third Revised Edition, Henry Regnery Company, Chicago, 1966, p. 142.
  • Newcomb, S.,Principles of Political Economy, Harper, NY, 1885
  • Ormazabal, Kepa M. 2005. “Neo-Classical Economics Is Not ‘Neo’, But ‘Anti’-Classical”, Post-Autistic Economics Review, Issue no. 30, article 5, 21 March 2005
  • Pressman, Steven. 2006. Fifty Major Economists. Routledge. ISBN 0415366496
  • Reisman, George. 1985. Classical Economics vs. The Exploitation Theory The Political Economy of Freedom Essays in Honor of F. A. Hayek, Kurt R. Leube and Albert H. Zlabinger (eds.) München and Wien: Philosophia Verlag. Retrieved August 27, 2008.
  • Reisman, G., Capitalism: A Treatise on Economics, Jameson Books, Ottawa, IL, 1996, pp.172-180, 200-201, 206-209, 414-441
  • Ricardo, D. [1817, 1821] 2004. Principles of Political Economy and Taxation. Dover Publications. ISBN 0486434613
  • Ricardo, David,”On the Protectionism of Agriculture”, in: The Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo; ( ed. Piere Sraffa) , vol IV, Cambridge U. Press, Cambridge, 1951
  • Say, Jean-Baptiste, [ orig.1803], A Treatise on Political Economy: or the Production, Distribution and Consumption of Wealth, (translated by C.R. Prinsep and Clement C. Biddle) Augustus M. Kelley, New York 1971
  • Smith, Adam, The Wealth of Nations, Cannan Edition, Bk. I, Chap. VIII,X, Methuen,London, 1904
  • Stigler, George J. 1965. The Nature and Role of Originality in Scientific Progress in Essays in the History of Economics, 1-15. University of Chicago Press.

Credits

New World Encyclopedia writers and editors rewrote and completed the Wikipedia article in accordance with New World Encyclopedia standards. This article abides by terms of the Creative Commons CC-by-sa 3.0 License (CC-by-sa), which may be used and disseminated with proper attribution. Credit is due under the terms of this license that can reference both the New World Encyclopedia contributors and the selfless volunteer contributors of the Wikimedia Foundation. To cite this article click here for a list of acceptable citing formats.The history of earlier contributions by wikipedians is accessible to researchers here:

The history of this article since it was imported to New World Encyclopedia:

Note: Some restrictions may apply to use of individual images which are separately licensed.