Wall Street Crash of 1929

From New World Encyclopedia
Crowd gathering on Wall Street outside the New York Stock Exchange after the 1929 crash.

The Wall Street Crash of 1929, also called the Great Crash or the Crash of '29, is the stock-market crash that occurred in late October, 1929. It started on October 24 ("Black Thursday") and continued through October 29, 1929 ("Black Tuesday"), when share prices on the New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) collapsed. However, the days leading up to the 29th had also seen enormous stock-market upheaval, with panic selling and vast levels of trading interspersed with brief periods of recovery.


Prologue

At the time of the stock market crash in 1929, New York City had grown to be a major metropolis, and its Wall Street district was one of the world's leading financial centers. The Roaring Twenties, which was a precursor to the Crash, was a time of prosperity and excess in the city, and despite warnings against speculation, many believed that the market could sustain high price levels (Smith 2008). Shortly before the crash, Irving Fisher famously proclaimed, "Stock prices have reached what looks like a permanently high plateau" (Teach 2007).NOTE: Fisher’s huge leveraged position in Remington Rand stock was wiped out by the crash ( Skousen 1995.)

In 1929, so many people were buying on margin that they had run up a debt of six billion dollars (Allen 1986).This is how “buying on margin” was done. To start with, you borrowed the money for the stock at low, 3 1/2%, interest. Then you put up the stock as collateral for your loan and wait for the stock to go up to collect your dividends. In short, the bull market on Wall Street that began in 1923 led to an unprecedented period of share trading. However, by 1929 there were signs of instability. On September 3 the Dow Jones Industrial Average (DJIA) reached its peak, closing at 381.7 (The Guardian 2008).

The prosperity couldn't last forever, though. During the month of September, and despite Dow Jones peak on September 3, the market was dropping sharply only to be rising and then dropping again. It was like tremors before a big earthquake but nobody heeded the warning. The market had sagged temporarily before, but it always came back stronger( Allen 1986.)

In the days leading up to Black Tuesday, the market was severely unstable. Periods of selling and high volumes of trading were interspersed with brief periods of rising prices and recovery. After the crash, the Dow Jones Industrial Average recovered early in 1930, only to reverse and crash again, reaching a low point of the great bear market in 1932. The Dow did not return to pre-1929 levels until late 1954, and on July 8, 1932 reached its lowest level of the twentieth century:

Anyone who bought stocks in mid-1929 and held on to them saw most of his adult life pass by before getting back to even (Salsman 2004).

Predictions by prominent economists

On September 5 the economist Roger Babson gave a speech saying "Sooner or later, a crash is coming, and it may be terrific." Later that day the stock market declined by about three percent, a phenomenon that became known as the "Babson Break." He had predicted a crash for years but this time the market fell (Allen 1986). The Great Depression soon followed.

It is interesting that both protagonists of the Austrian School, Ludwig von Mises and Friedrich von Hayek predicted the crash much earlier than Babson.

In the summer of 1929, von Mises was offered a high position at the Kreditanstalt Bank. His future wife, Margit, was ecstatic, but von Mises decided against it. “Why not?” she asked. His response shocked her:

“A great crash is coming, and I don’t want my name in any way connected with it.” He preferred to write and teach. “If you want a rich man,” he said, “don’t marry me. I am not interested in earning money. I am writing about money, but will never have much of my own” (Margit von Mises 1984, Skousen 1993).

After Wall Street collapsed several months later, world trade suffered and in May 1931, Kreditanstalt went bankrupt. This, more than any other event, extended the depression throughout Europe.

Friedrich Hayek ventured, about the same time, similar dire predictions:

Up to 1927 I should have expected that the subsequent depression would be very mild. But in that year an entirely unprecedented action was taken by the American monetary authorities. ... [they] succeeded, by means of an easy-money policy, inaugurated as soon as the symptoms of an impending reaction were noticed, in prolonging the boom for two years beyond what would otherwise have been its natural end. ... And when the crises finally occurred, deliberate attempts were made to prevent, by all conceivable means, the normal process of liquidation (Skousen 1991).

I was one of the only ones to predict what was going to happen. In early 1929, when I made this forecast, I was living in Europe which was then going through a period of depression. I said that there [would be] no hope of a recovery in Europe until interest rates fell, and interest rates would not fall until the American boom collapses, which I said was likely to happen within the next few months (Hayek 1975).

Timeline of the Crash

Dow Jones Industrial, 1928-1930

Spring and Summer of 1929

In late March 1929, just after the inauguration of Herbert Hoover, the Federal Reserve Board was meeting every day behind closed doors. There was no doubt heavy discussion about the market and the national economy. However, the May issue of the National City Bank of New York Newsletter indicated the earnings statements for the first quarter of surveyed firms showed a 31 percent increase compared to the first quarter of 1928. The August issue showed that for 650 firms the increase for the first six months of 1929 compared to 1928 was 24.4 percent. In the first nine months of 1929, 1,436 firms announced increased dividends. In 1928, the number was only 955 and in 1927, it was 755.

September

The financial news from corporations was very positive in September 1929. The Dow Jones Industrial Average ("the DJIA" or "the Dow") reached a high of 381.17 on September 3. In September 1929 dividend increases were announced by 193 firms, compared with 135 the year before. Although it can be argued that the stock market was not overvalued, there is evidence that many feared that it was overvalued—including the Federal Reserve Board and the United States Senate.

By 1929, there were many who felt the market price of equity securities had increased too much, and this feeling was reinforced daily by the media and statements by influential government officials. The market value of one segment of the market, the public utility sector, should have been based on existing fundamentals, and fundamentals seem to have changed considerably in October 1929.

October

Thursday, October 3

Business activity news in October was generally good and there were very few hints of a coming depression. Although the start of the stock market crash is conventionally identified with Black Thursday, October 24, there were price declines on October 3, 4, and 16. The economic news after the price drops of October 3 and October 4 were mixed. But the deluge of bad news regarding public utility regulation seems to have truly upset the market. In view of public utilities’ stock upcoming crash, it is reasonable to conclude that the October 16 break was related to the news from Massachusetts and New York public utilities. Among the sensational and mostly negative “frantic stock selling news” news in, both, New York Times and Washington Post, there appeared the statement by Philip Snowden, British Chancellor of the Exchequer, that described America's stock market as "speculative orgy."

Black Thursday—Thursday, October 24
The trading floor of the New York Stock Exchange just after the crash of 1929.

"On October 21, an amendment to impose tariffs only on agricultural imports was defeated. ... Three days later the stock market suffered its first one-day crash" (Salsman 2004). On that day, forever called “Black Thursday,” 12,894,650 shares changed hands on the New York Stock Exchange (NYSE)—a record. To put this number in perspective, the previous record for trading activity was set on March 12, 1928. On that day, a total of 3,875,910 shares were traded.

The market was crashing and the floor of the NYSE was in a state of panic. By noon on Black Thursday, there had been eleven suicides of fairly prominent investors.

Battle to save the market

America's financial elite tried to rescue the market. At 1:00pm, several leading Wall Street bankers met to find a solution. The group included Thomas W. Lamont, acting head of Morgan Bank, Albert Wiggin head of the Chase National Bank, and Charles E. Mitchell, president of National City Bank. They chose Richard Whitney, vice president of the Exchange, to act on their behalf. With the bankers' financial resources behind him, Whitney placed a bid to purchase a large block of shares in U.S. Steel at a price well above the current market. As amazed traders watched, Whitney then placed similar bids on other "blue chip" stocks.

Although a similar such tactic had ended the Panic of 1907, this action halted the slide that day and returned stability to the market only temporarily. The move could not stem the tide this time. The market eventually hit new lows in November, but it was not until July 1932 that it reached the lowest point of the Great Depression, down 89 percent from its peak (The Guardian 2008.)

Monday, October 28

Over the weekend, the events were dramatized by the newspapers across the U.S. The Sunday, October 27 edition of The Times had a two-column article "Bay State Utilities Face Investigation." It implied that regulation in Massachusetts was going to be less friendly towards utilities. Stocks again went down on Monday, October 28. There were 9,212,800 shares traded (3,000,000 in the final hour). On Monday, October 28, 1929 the volume was huge-over 9,250,000 shares traded with a record 13 percent loss in the Dow for the day. But unlike Thursday, there was no dramatic recovery; it was the prelude to Black Tuesday, the most infamous day in Wall Street history.

Black Tuesday—Tuesday, October 29

The Times on Tuesday, October 29 again carried an article on the New York public utility investigating committee being critical of the rate making process. This time, the panic of selling made sure, once and for all, that there was to be no quick fix, that the recovery would be slow and painful. There was not the nearly the recovery of gains seen on Thursday. The market had crashed.

The consequences

The Crash led to higher trade tariffs as governments tried to shore up their economies, and higher interest rates in the US after a worldwide run on US gold deposits. In America unemployment went from 1.5 million in 1929 to 12.8 million—or 24.75 percent of the workforce—by 1933, a pattern replicated around the world. It took 23 years for the US market to recover (The Guardian 2008).

Causes

Some economists such as Joseph Schumpeter and Nikolai Kondratiev (also written Kondratieff) have claimed that the crash of 1929 was merely a historical event in the continuing process known as economic cycles. The Kondratiev long-wave cycle is a theory based on study of nineteenth century price behavior. The theory predicts 50-60 year-long cycles of economic booms and depressions (Kondratiev 1984). However, the stock market crash in 1929 was as monumental as it was unexpected. Thus, it falls far beyond the standard Kondratiev’s long-term economic cycles theory (Kondratiev 1984), which itself has been subject to serious criticism. According to Murray Rothbard, Kondratiev long "depressions" were really booms in everything except for prices. However, falling prices have been found to be compatible with economic growth and prosperity. Also Kondratiev long "booms" were really short booms fueled by devastating wars (Rothbard 1984).

Thus, although the K-cycle theory has economic merit, the 1929 Stock Market crash was a result of various other economic imbalances and structural failings. Thus the Crash is treated as a singularity (a unique event). These are some of the most significant economic factors behind the stock market crash of 1929:

Boom and Bust: The disagreement between Monetarists and the Austrian School

Monetarists

Complete inability to analyze the real monetary situation leading to the Crash typifies Milton Friedman’s claim: "I have no reason to suppose there was any over-investment boom … during the 1920s" (Friedman 1963).

Friedman claimed, as he and Anna Schwartz concluded in A Monetary History of the United States, that the 1920s was the "high tide" of Federal Reserve policy, inflation was virtually non-existent, and economic growth was reasonably rapid. Monetarists even deny that the stock market was overvalued in 1929! In short, "everything going on in the 1920s was fine" (Friedman 1963: 240-298).

The problem, according to Friedman was not the 1920s, but the 1930s, when the Federal Reserve permitted the "Great Contraction" of the money supply and drove the economy into the worst depression in U.S. history.

Austrian School

In contrast to Friedman and the Monetarists, the Austrians argued that the Federal Reserve artificially cheapened credit during most of the 1920s and orchestrated an unsustainable inflationary boom. The stock market crash of 1929 and subsequent economic cataclysm were therefore inevitable.

An interesting historical sidelight is the fact that Irving Fisher, the principal Monetarist of the 1920s, completely failed to anticipate the crash, while Austrian economists Ludwig von Mises and Friedrich Hayek predicted the economic crisis, as mentioned in the above section.

Was there an overinvestment boom in the 1920s? The answer depends on which statistics you examine. The "macro" data favors the Monetarists’ thesis, while the "micro" data supports the Austrians’ view (Skousen 1995).

In support of the Monetarists, the broad-based price indices show little if any inflation. Average wholesale and consumer prices hardly budged between 1921 and 1929. Most commodity prices actually fell. Friedman and Schwartz conclude, "Far from being an inflationary decade, the twenties were the reverse" (Friedman and Schwartz 196: 298).

However, other data support the Austrian view that the decade was aptly named the "Roaring Twenties." The 1920s may not have been characterized by a "price" inflation, but there was, in the words of John Maynard Keynes, a "profit" inflation. After the 1920-1921 depression, national output (GNP) grew rapidly at a 5.2 percent pace, substantially exceeding the national norm (3.0 percent). The Index of Manufacturing Production grew much more rapidly and virtually doubled between 1921 and 1929. So did capital investment and corporate profits.

Like the 1980s, there was also an "asset" inflation in the U.S. A nationwide real estate boom occurred in the mid-1920s, including a speculative bubble in Florida that collapsed in 1927. Manhattan, the world’s financial center, also experienced a boom.

The asset bubble was most pronounced on Wall Street, both in stocks and bonds. The Dow Jones Industrial Average began its monstrous bull market in late 1921 at a cyclical low of 66, mounting a drive that carried it to a high of 300 by mid-1929, more than tripling in value. The Standard & Poor’s Index of Common Stocks was just as dramatic-Industrials, up 321 percent, Railroads, up 129 percent, and Utilities, up an incredible 318 percent (Skousen 1995).

Astonishingly, the Monetarists go so far as to deny any stock market orgy. Anna Schwartz suggests, "Had high employment and economic growth continued, prices in the stock market could have been maintained" (Schwartz 1997). It is as if they want to exonerate Irving Fisher’s infamous blunder of declaring a week before the 1929 crash, "stock prices have reached what looks like a permanently high plateau." (NOTE: Fisher’s huge leveraged position in Remington Rand stock was wiped out by the crash.)

Schwartz’s thesis is based on what appears to be reasonable price-earnings ratios for most stocks in 1929 (15.6 versus a norm of 13.6). However, P/E ratios can be a notoriously misleading indicator of speculative activity. While they do tend to rise during a bull market, they severely underestimate the degree of speculation because both prices and earnings tend to rise during a boom. However, when annual national output averages 5.2 percent during the 1920s, and the S&P Index of Common Stocks increases an average 18.6 percent a year, something has to give. In fact, during 1927-1929, the economy grew only 6.3 percent, while common stocks gained an incredible 82.2 percent! As the old Wall Street saying goes, "Trees don’t grow to the sky." A crash was inevitable (Skousen 1995).

The Austrians argue ‘that the Federal Reserve’s "cheap-credit" policy was to blame for the structural imbalances of the Twenties, while the Monetarists dispute any significant inflationary intent. The money stock (M2) grew 46 percent between 1921-29, less than 5 percent per annum, which Monetarists do not consider excessive. Austrians, on the other hand, point to the deliberate efforts by the Fed to lower interest rates, especially in 1924 and 1927, thus generating an unjustifiable boom in assets and manufacturing. More importantly, the credit expansion in the United States far exceeded the increase in gold reserves, which would eventually spell disaster under the gold exchange standard.

In sum, was there an inflationary imbalance during the 1920s, sufficient to cause an economic crisis? The evidence is mixed, but on net balance, the Austrians have a case. In the minds of the Monetarists, the "easy credit" stimulus may not have been large, but given the fragile nature of the financial system under the international gold standard, small changes by the newly established central bank triggered a global earthquake of monstrous proportions (Skousen 1995).

Mismatch between production and consumption

Overproduction was one of the main reasons for the Wall Street crash. During the boom businesses were overproducing which meant that they were making more than they were selling. This was because also due to the new way of manufacturing. Production lines were most commonly used which meant that they factories could make more product in a shorter amount of time and during the boom this was a good thing as the demand for products was great but as early as 1926 the demand for goods was decreasing but business kept producing as they had been as they thought that the demand would rise again but it didn’t as many people that could afford the goods had bought them earlier on and they didn’t need any more. Not everyone had benefitted from the boom and the groups that were poor could not afford the luxuries. Even farmers had been overproducing which meant that even food prices went down and so even farmer couldn’t make a profit. A drop in sales and product values meant that businesses had to fire many workers and many farmers lost their which mean that many people had less money to spend (www.termpaperwarehouse.com )

Agricultural Recession

Even before 1929, the American agricultural sector was struggling to maintain profitability. Many small farmers were driven out of business because they could not compete in the new economic climate. Not everyone had benefitted from the boom and the groups that were poor could not afford the luxuries. Then, better technology in agriculture was increasing supply and even farmers had been overproducing. But, demand for food was not increasing at same rate. Therefore, prices fell and farmers incomes dropped so even they couldn’t make a profit. A drop in sales and product values meant that businesses had to fire many workers and many farmers lost their jobs which mean that many people had less money to spend. There was occupational and geographical immobilities in this sector. It was difficult for unemployed famers to get jobs elsewhere in the economy (www.economicshelp.org).

Weaknesses in the banking system

Before the Great Depression, the American banking system was characterized by having many small to medium sized firms. America had over 30,000 banks. The effect of this was that they were prone to going bankrupt if there was a run on deposits. In particular, many banks in rural areas went bankrupt due to the agricultural recession. This had a negative impact on the rest of the financial industry. Between 1923 and 1930 5,000 banks collapsed. However the inflation factor exogenously brought into the system from the Feds is clearly prevailing.

For Ludwig von Mises of the Austrian School, inflation is defined as money creation, the act of which tends to manifest itself through the fall in the purchasing power of money (PPM). Thus for a given demand for money, an increase in its supply lowers the PPM.

Whenever monetary authorities allow the rate of monetary pumping to proceed at an accelerating pace, the purchasing power of money tends to fall by a much larger percentage than the rate of increase in money supply. Mises attributed this to increases in inflationary expectations. Peoples' expectation that the future PPM is likely to fall causes them to lower the present demand for money. This sets in motion a mechanism that, if allowed to continue unabated, can ultimately break the monetary system (Shostak 2006).

Inflationary expectations lead the suppliers of goods to ask for prices that are above what the holders of money can pay. Potential buyers don't have the money to purchase the goods. The emerging shortage of money, according to Mises, is an indication that the inflationary process has gained pace and cannot be "fixed" by raising the supply of money. On the contrary, policies that accommodate this shortage can only make things much worse. Ultimately, the sellers demand astronomical prices, transactions with inflated money become impossible, and the monetary system falls apart (Shostak 2006).

Lessons learned

All stock market crashes are unforeseen for most people, economists notwithstanding. This is the first lesson of history.

Irwing Fisher’s “New Era”

Well after the fact, Irving Fisher identified most precisely and perceptively what he meant by a “New Era.” In trying to identify the cause of the stock market crash and depression he found most explanations lacking. What he did find was that new eras occurred when technology allowed for higher productivity, lower costs, more profits, and higher stock prices:

In such a period, the commodity market and the stock market are apt to diverge; commodity prices falling by reason of the lowered cost, and stock prices rising by reason of the increased profits. In a word, this was an exceptional period – really a “New Era” (Fisher 1932, 75).

"In a few months I expect to see the stock market much higher than today." Those words were pronounced by Irving Fisher, America's distinguished and famous economist, Professor of Economics at Yale University, 14 days before Wall Street crashed on Black Tuesday, October 29, 1929.

The key development of the 1920s was that monetary inflation did not show up in price inflation as measured by price indexes. As Fisher noted: “One warning, however, failed to put in an appearance – the commodity price level did not rise.” He suggested that price inflation would have normally kept economic excesses in check, but that price indexes have “theoretical imperfections” (Fisher 1932, 74).

During and after the World War, it (wholesale commodity price level) responded very exactly to both inflation and deflation. If it did not do so during the inflationary period from 1923–1929, this was partly because trade had grown with the inflation, and partly because technological improvements had reduced the cost, so that many producers were able to get higher profits without charging higher prices (Fisher 1932, 75).

Fisher had therefore stumbled near a correct understanding of the problem of new-era thinking. Technology can drive down costs and increase profits, creating periods of economic euphoria, where economic signals would otherwise inject greater caution and clearer thinking (Thornton 2004).

Was the Great Crash predictable or preventable?

The failure of the market economy to “right itself” in the wake of the Great Crash is the most pivotal development in modern economic history and its impact has continued to shape mass ideology and to determine public institutions and policy. Unfortunately, few saw the development of the stock market bubble, its cause, or predicted the bust and the resulting depression.

Mises showed that the central bank’s attempt to keep interest rates low and to maintain the boom only makes the crisis worse. Despite the tremendous odds against the adoption of his solution, he ended his analysis with a prescription for preventing future cycles (Thornton 2004):

The only way to do away with, or even to alleviate, the periodic return of the trade cycle – with its denouement, the crisis – is to reject the fallacy that prosperity can be produced by using banking procedures to make credit cheap (Mises 1928, 93, 95, 128–129, 143, 147, 171).

And finally, a big problem - not mentioned so far in all this - was communication. It is said that Henry Ford was taking the elevator to his penthouse one day in 1929, and the operator said, "Mr. Ford, a friend of mine who knows a lot about stocks recommended that I buy shares in X, Y, and Z. You are a person with a lot of money. You should seize this opportunity." Ford thanked him, and as soon as he got into his penthouse, he called his broker, and told him to sell everything. He explained afterwards: "If the elevator operator recommends buying, you should have sold long ago." (Friedberg Mercantile group 1997).

Even at telegraphic speed, the volume was having an effect on time. Issues were behind as much as one hour to an hour and a half on the tape. Telephone calls were just busy signals. Crowds gathered outside the New York Stock Exchange trying to obtain information. Police had to be called to control the strangest of riots; the investors of business. Panic prevailed.

Now we switch “fast forward” to the depression of 2008, where the, well documented, greedy monetary institutions used “falsifications” or “enhancing” of basic data (by those such as Enron, Fannie Mae, and others) and, sure enough, very soon afterwards started to go completely haywire in 2002. However, there were no “red flags” (extreme inflation, for one) that would bring the K-cycle “trough” to the surface. But, the 2008-2009 watershed kept - thanks to the on-line virtual information gadgets (TV, e-mail, cell-phone, blackberries etc.) - the general public (inclusive of all professional and “lay” investors) well informed (as opposed to the situation Henry Ford encountered in 1929) of what the current situation is and what the Federal Reserve was going to do, with the result that no panic or “run on banks” took place in developed countries. Thus, the danger of completely bringing down the global markets as occurred in September 1929 is, and will be, virtually nonexistent.

References
ISBN links support NWE through referral fees

  • Allen, Frederick Lewis. 1986. Since Yesterday: The 1930's in America, September 3, 1929 to September 3, 1939. HarperCollins. ISBN 0060913223
  • Bierman, Harold, Jr. 1991. The Great Myths of 1929 and the Lessons to be Learned. Westport, CT: Greenwood Press. ISBN 0313273650
  • Bierman, Harold, Jr. 1998. The Causes of the 1929 Stock Market Crash. Westport, CT, Greenwood Press. ISBN 031330629X
  • Bierman, Harold, Jr. 2001. Bad Market Days. World Economics 177-191.
  • Fisher, Irving. 1932. Booms and Depressions: Some First Principles. New York, NY: Adelphi Company.
  • Friedman, Milton, and Anna J. Schwartz. 1963. A Monetary History of the United States, 1867-1960. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. ISBN 0691003548
  • Hayek, Friedrich A. 1975. Interview. Gold and Silver Newsletter. Newport Beach, CA: Monex International (June).
  • Galbraith, John Kenneth. [1954] 1997. The Great Crash, 1929. Boston, MA: Houghton Mifflin. ISBN 0395859999
  • Mises, Ludwig von. 1928. Geldwertstabilisierung und Konjunkturpolitik [Monetary Stabilization and Cyclical Policy]. Jena: Gustav Fischer.
  • Salsman, Richard M. 2004. The Cause and Consequences of the Great Depression, Part 1: What Made the Roaring '20s Roar. The Intellectual Activist (June): 16.
  • Salsman, Richard M. 2004. The Cause and Consequences of the Great Depression, Part 2: Hoover's Progressive Assault on Business. The Intellectual Activist (July): 15.
  • Schwartz, Anna J. 1987. Money in Historical Perspective. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. ISBN 0226742288
  • Shostak, Frank. 2006. The Prophet of the Great Depression. Mises Daily, Ludwig von Mises Institute, October 4, 2006. Retrieved February 22, 2009.
  • Skousen, Mark. 1991. Economics on Trial: Lies, Myths, and Realities. Homewood, IL: Business One Irvin. ISBN 1556239238
  • Skousen, Mark. 1993. Who Predicted the 1929 Crash? in Jeffrey M. Herbener (ed.). The Meaning of Ludwig von Mises. Norwell, MA: Kluwer Publishers. ISBN 0792392906
  • Skousen, Mark. 1995. Friedman vs. The Austrians, Part II: Was There an Inflationary Boom in the 1920s? The Freeman. Retrieved February 24, 2009.
  • Thornton, Mark. 2004. Uncomfortable Parallels. LewRockwell.com. Retrieved February 24, 2009.
  • The Guardian. 2008. How the 1929 Wall Street Crash unfolded. The Guardian, Saturday 4 October 2008. Retrieved February 22, 2009.
  • Friedberg Mercantile Group, “The Collapse of the Wall Street,”, Toronto, Canada , March 16, 1997
  • Smith, David. 2008. America gets depressed by thoughts of 1929 revisited. The Sunday Times. Retrieved February 20, 2009.
  • Teach, Edward. 2007. The Bright Side of Bubbles. CFO Magazine. Retrieved February 20, 2009.
  • Kondratiev, Nikolai D. [1925] 1984. The Long Wave Cycle. New York, NY: Richardson & Snyder. ISBN 0943940079
  • Rothbard, Murray. 1984. The Kondratieff Cycle: Real or Fabricated? Investment Insights (August): 5-7, (September): 2-7. Retrieved February 22, 2009.
  • Geisst, Charles R. 2004. Wall Street: A History: From Its Beginnings to the Fall of Enron. New York, NY: Oxford University Press. ISBN 0195170601

External links

Credits

New World Encyclopedia writers and editors rewrote and completed the Wikipedia article in accordance with New World Encyclopedia standards. This article abides by terms of the Creative Commons CC-by-sa 3.0 License (CC-by-sa), which may be used and disseminated with proper attribution. Credit is due under the terms of this license that can reference both the New World Encyclopedia contributors and the selfless volunteer contributors of the Wikimedia Foundation. To cite this article click here for a list of acceptable citing formats.The history of earlier contributions by wikipedians is accessible to researchers here:

The history of this article since it was imported to New World Encyclopedia:

Note: Some restrictions may apply to use of individual images which are separately licensed.