Quesnay, François

From New World Encyclopedia
(copied from Wikipedia)
 
 
(35 intermediate revisions by 8 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
[[Category:Politics and social sciences]]
+
[[Category:Economists]]
[[Category:Economics]]
+
[[Category:biography]]
[[Category:Biography]]
+
{{epname|Quesnay, François}}
{{epname}}
+
{{Copyedited}}{{Ebapproved}}{{Paid}}{{Approved}}{{Images OK}}{{Submitted}}
  
'''François Quesnay''' ([[June 4]], [[1694]] - [[December 16]], [[1774]]) was a [[France|French]] [[economist]] of the [[Physiocrats|Physiocratic]] school.  He also practiced [[surgery]].
+
[[Image:Quesnay Portrait.jpg|thumb|250px|right| François Quesnay]]  
  
==Life==
+
'''François Quesnay''' (June 4, 1694 – December 16, 1774) was a [[France|French]] [[economics|economist]], founder of the [[Physiocrats|Physiocratic]] school. He also practiced [[surgery]], serving as surgeon to [[King Louis XV]] and his mistress, [[Madame de Pompadour]]. Quesnay, in opposition to the then-dominant [[mercantilism|mercantilist]] position, advocated a ''[[laissez-faire]]'' policy against government interference with [[trade]]. As an attempt to support this position, Quesnay developed his famous ''Tableau Economique'', which purportedly showed that the only productive sector was [[agriculture]], and that industry was "sterile," i.e. unable to produce a surplus of output above costs. While Quesnay's model had many limitations, he recognized that his idealized "natural" system did not reflect reality, and thus he argued that the government should lift restrictions allowing the natural economic order to emerge.
 +
{{toc}}
 +
Quesnay envisioned this natural economic state as a balanced, circular flow of funds—a system he saw as similar to the flow of [[blood]] in the body, achieving an equilibrium which maximizes the net product, and therefore the health of the society, similar to [[homeostasis]] in living organisms. This may be his most enduring insight.
  
Quesnay was born at [[Merey]], in today's [[Eure]] ''[[département in France|département]]'', near [[Paris]], the son of an advocate and small [[landed proprietor]]. Apprenticed at the age of sixteen to a surgeon, he soon went to Paris, studied medicine and surgery there, and, having qualified as a master-surgeon, settled down to practice at [[Mantes]]. In [[1737]] he was appointed perpetual secretary of the academy of surgery founded by [[François la Peyronie]], and became surgeon in ordinary to the king. In [[1744]] he graduated as a doctor of medicine; he became physician in ordinary to the king, and afterwards his first consulting physician, and was installed in the [[Palace of Versailles]]. His apartments were on the [[entresol]], whence the ''Réunions de l'entresol'' received their name. [[Louis XV of France|Louis XV]] esteemed Quesnay much, and used to call him his thinker; when he ennobled him he gave him for arms three flowers of the [[pansy]] (''pensée'' in [[French language|French]], also meaning ''thought''), with the motto ''Propter excogitalionem mentis''.
+
==Biography==
 +
François Quesnay was born on June 4, 1694, near [[Paris]] [[France]], into a humble family. His father worked as a ploughman and merchant. In 1711, Quesnay entered into training for five years as a Parisian engraver.  
  
He now devoted himself principally to economic studies, taking no part in the court intrigues which were perpetually going on around him. About the year [[1750]] he became acquainted with [[Jean de Gournay|Jean C. M. V. de Gournay]] (1712-1759), who was also an earnest inquirer in the economic field; and round these two distinguished men was gradually formed the philosophic sect of the ''Économistes'', or, as for distinction's sake they were afterwards called, the ''Physiocrates''. The most remarkable men in this group of disciples were the elder [[Honoré Mirabeau|Mirabeau]] (author of ''L'Ami des hommes'', 1756-60, and ''Philosophie rurale'', 1763), [[Nicolas Baudeau]] (''Introduction a la philosophie économique'', 1771), [[G. F. Le Trosne]] (''De l'ordre social'', 1777), [[André Morellet]] (best known by his controversy with [[Ferdinando Galiani|Galiani]] on the freedom of the grain trade during the [[Flour War]]), [[Mercier Larivière]] and [[Dupont de Nemours]]. [[Adam Smith]], during his stay on the continent with the young [[Henry Scott, 3rd Duke of Buccleuch|Duke of Buccleuch]] in [[1764]]-[[1766]], spent some time in Paris, where he made the acquaintance of Quesnay and some of his followers; he paid a high tribute to their scientific services in his ''[[Wealth of Nations]]''.
+
Following this, he registered at the [[university]] in the college of [[surgery]], receiving his degree in 1717. In 1718, Quesnay was accepted into the community of surgeons of Paris. In 1723, he became royal surgeon, entering in the service of the Duke of Villeroy in 1734, and in 1744, was awarded the rank of doctor of medicine. Five years later he became physician to [[Madame de Pompadour]], influential mistress of [[King Louis XV]]. Elected to the Academy of Science in 1751, Quesnay became a member of Royal Society in 1752, and the same year he was made a noble by the king.
  
Quesnay died on December 16, 1774, having lived long enough to see his great pupil, [[Anne Robert Jacques Turgot, Baron de Laune|Turgot]], in office as [[List of Finance Ministers of France|minister of finance]]. He had married in [[1718]], and had a son and a daughter; his grandson by the former was a member of the [[Legislative Assembly (France)|first Legislative Assembly]].
+
François Quesnay's interest in [[economics]] arose in 1756, when, hoping to draw on his country background, he was asked to contribute several articles on farming to the ''Encyclopédie'' of [[Denis Diderot]] and [[Jean Le Rond d'Alembert]]. Quesnay delved into the works of the Maréchal de Vauban, Pierre de Boisguilbert, and [[Richard Cantillon]]. Mixing all these ingredients together, he came up with his famous economic theory.
  
==Works==
+
In 1758, Quesnay wrote his ''Tableau Économique''—renowned for its "zigzag" depiction of income flows between economic sectors—to explain his doctrine. This became the founding document of the [[Physiocrats]] and the ancestor of the multisectoral input-output systems of [[Wassily Leontief]]. While the accepted founder of the [[classical economics|classical school]] of economics was [[Adam Smith]], he acknowledged his indebtedness to the French Physiocrats, and so in turn to their founder, François Quesnay.
  
In [[1758]] he published the ''Tableau économique'' (Economic Table), which provided the foundations of the ideas of the Physiocrats. This was perhaps the first work to attempt to describe the workings of the economy in an analytical way, and as such can be viewed as one of the first important contributions to economic thought.
+
Quesnay died on December 16, 1774, in Versailles, France.
  
The publications in which Quesnay expounded his system were the following: two articles, on "Fermiers" and on "Grains", in the ''[[Encyclopédie]]'' of [[Denis Diderot|Diderot]] and [[Jean le Rond d'Alembert|D'Alembert]] ([[1756]], [[1757]]); a discourse on the law of nature in the ''Physiocratie'' of Dupont de Nemours ([[1768]]); ''Maximes générales de gouvernement economique d'un royaume agricole'' ([[1758]]), and the simultaneously published ''Tableau économique avec son explication, ou extrait des économies royales de [[Maximilien de Bethune, duc de Sully|Sully]]'' (with the celebrated motto, ''Pauvres paysans, pauvre royaume; pauvre royaume, pauvre roi''); ''Dialogue sur le commerce et les travaux des artisans''; and other minor pieces.
+
==Work==
  
The ''Tableau économique'', though on account of its dryness and abstract form it met with little general favor, may be considered the principal manifesto of the school. It was regarded by the followers of Quesnay as entitled to a place amongst the foremost products of human wisdom, and is named by the elder Mirabeau, in a passage quoted by Adam Smith, as one of the three great inventions which have contributed most to the stability of political societies, the other two being those of writing and of money. Its object was to exhibit by means of certain formulas the way in which the products of [[agriculture]], which is the only source of wealth, would in a state of perfect liberty be distributed among the several classes of the community (namely, the productive classes of the proprietors and cultivators of land, and the unproductive class composed of manufacturers and merchants), and to represent by other formulas the modes of distribution which take place under systems of Governmental restraint and regulation, with the evil results arising to the whole society from different degrees of such violations of the natural order. It follows from Quesnay's theoretic views that the one thing deserving the solicitude of the practical economist and the statesman is the increase of the net product; and he infers also what Smith afterwards affirmed, on not quite the same ground, that the interest of the landowner is strictly and indissolubly connected with the general interest of the society. A small edition de luxe of this work, with other pieces, was printed in [[1758]] in the Palace of Versailles under the king's immediate supervision, some of the sheets, it is said, having been pulled by the royal hand. Already in [[1767]] the book had disappeared from circulation, and no copy of it is now procurable; but, the substance of it has been preserved in the ''Ami des hommes'' of Mirabeau, and the ''Physiocratie'' of Dupont de Nemours.
+
François Quesnay began with the axiom that [[agriculture]] is the only source of ''produit net'' (net product, or surplus of output above cost). The wealth of a nation, Quesnay argued, lies in the size of its net product. He believed that [[manufacturing]] and [[commerce]] were "sterile" as (in his view) the value of their output was equal to the value of their inputs. Only land, Quesnay reasoned, produced more than went into it.  
  
His economic writings are collected in the 2nd vol. of the ''Principaux économistes'', published by Guillaumin, Paris, with preface and notes by [[Eugène Daire]]; also his ''OEuvres économiques et philosophiques'' were collected with an introduction and note by [[August Oncken]] (Frankfort, 1888); a facsimile reprint of the ''Tableau économique'', from the original MS., was published by the British Economic Association (London, 1895). His other writings were the article "Évidence" in the ''Encyclopédie'', and ''Recherches sur l'évidence des vérites geometriques'', with a ''Projet de nouveaux éléments de géometrie'', 1773. Quesnay's Eloge was pronounced in the [[French Academy of Sciences|Academy of Sciences]] by [[Grandjean de Fouchy]] (see the Recueil of that Academy, 1774, p. 134). See also [[Jean-François Marmontel|F.J. Marmontel]], ''Mémoires''; ''Mémoires de [[Mme. du Hausset]]''; [[H. Higgs]], ''The Physiocrats'' (London, 1897).
+
He claimed that the only "productive" person is the farmer, the only one that generated a net product. The landlord, the farmhand, the foreign merchant, and, most notably, the artisan, were all part of the "sterile class" because none of them generated a net product. In this, Quesnay opposed the [[mercantilism|mercantilist]] doctrines of Colbert, believing that they concentrated too much on propping up [[industry]] and commerce rather than supporting agriculture.  
  
The influence of [[China|Chinese]] ideas and concepts on Quesnay should not be forgotten: in his lifetime he was known as the French [[Confucius]]. [http://www.lse.ac.uk/collections/economicHistory/GEHN/GEHNPDF/WorkingPaper12CG.pdf 1]
+
Quesnay's system of [[political economy]] was summed up in ''Tableau économique'' (1758), which diagrammed the relationship between the different economic sectors and the flow of payments between them. In his ''Tableau'', Quesnay developed the notion of economic equilibrium, a concept frequently used as a point of departure for subsequent economic analyses.  
  
 +
He conceived of the natural state of the economy as the balanced circular flow of income between economic sectors, and thus [[social class]]es, maximizing the net product. In these concepts, Quesnay saw analogies to the circulation of human [[blood]] and the [[homeostasis]] of a body.
  
{{1911}}
+
===''Laissez-faire''===
 +
{{Main|Laissez-faire}}
  
 +
The term ''laissez-faire, laissez-passer''—“let it be, let it pass” (although the phrase is not readily translatable), was widely used by the [[Physiocrats]] in urging freedom from government interference, and was later adopted by [[Adam Smith]]. Quesnay believed, in opposition to the then-dominant French [[mercantilism|mercantilists]], that high [[taxation|taxes]] and high barriers to imported goods were the cause of French [[poverty]]. Thus, he wanted [[King Louis XV|Louis XV]] to deregulate [[trade]] and cut taxes so that France could begin to emulate wealthier [[Britain]].
  
 +
Influenced by Vincent de Gournay, an advocate of ''laissez-faire'', Quesnay wished to see many of the [[Medieval]] rules governing agricultural production lifted, permitting the economy to find its "natural state." Thus, François Quesnay was largely responsible for the distinction between the ''ordre naturel'' (nature's order) and the ''ordre positif'' (positive, i.e. human-idealized, order). A good [[government]], Quesnay argued, should follow a ''laissez-faire'' policy so that the ''ordre naturel'' could emerge.
  
 +
The methodology of Quesnay's physiocratic system and his principles of policy sprang from an extreme form of the doctrine of [[natural law]], which he believed represented the divinely appointed economic order. He was, therefore, one of the originators of the nineteenth-century doctrine of the harmony of class interests, and of the related doctrine that maximum social satisfaction occurs under free [[monopoly and competition|competition]].
 +
 +
===The ''Tableau Économique''===
 +
 +
Quesnay identified three distinct classes:
 +
#the ''proprietary'' class (landlords)
 +
#the ''productive'' class (farmers and agricultural farmhands)
 +
#the ''sterile'' class (artisans and merchants),
 +
 +
and the following five protagonists were involved:
 +
#''Farmer'': produces grain, owns livestock and seed, hires [[labor]], pays [[rent]] to landlord.
 +
#''Artisan'': produces crafts, uses local grains and foreign goods as raw materials.
 +
#''Farmhand'': works for farmer, receives [[wages]].
 +
#''Merchant'': sells foreign goods he has imported and buys local grain for export.
 +
#''Landlord'': owns land, receives rent from farmer.
 +
 +
A view of Quesnay's original [http://www.taieb.net/auteurs/Quesnay/Qimages/1759.jpg ''Tableau Economique''] shows a zigzag flow. The left side of the ''Tableau'' represents the "productive" class (farmer) and the right side represents the "sterile" class (artisan). At the top in the center is the landlord. The landlord begins the flow by buying goods from both the farmer and the artisan; hence the income flows from the landlord to both the left (productive) and right (sterile) columns.
 +
 +
Quesnay claimed that the most "productive" sector is [[agriculture]], the only one that can generate a net product. He was well aware, though, that he created an idealized "natural" system and he repeatedly noted that "real" conditions are never as smooth as the example in the ''Tableau''. He wanted to bring to the King's attention the real [[market]] distortions: inequitable [[taxation]], insufficient compensation due to excessive taxes, underdeveloped markets, protectionist [[trade]] distortions, etc., which the [[government]] could help to mitigate. In other words, he said that under the present conditions only the agricultural sector could produce a surplus that could then be used to produce more the next year and, therefore, help growth. [[Industry]] and manufacturing were, under those existing circumstances (that he wanted to change), sterile.
 +
 +
Quesnay (1959) used the term ''avances'' ("advances") to denote [[capital]], i.e. expenditures during a production process that are drawn from a previously accumulated fund. He identified four types of capital, according to the type of expenditure:
 +
#''avances foncières'' (fundamental/landed advances): one-time capital expenditures undertaken by landlords on their land, e.g. land-clearing, drainage, fence-building, etc.
 +
#''avances souveraines'' (sovereign advances): one-time capital expenditures undertaken by government, e.g. [[road]]s, [[bridge]]s, etc.
 +
#''avances primitives'' (primitive advances): expenditures on durable producers' goods, e.g. [[horse]]s, [[cattle]], [[plow]]s, etc. In the ''Tableau'', these are also referred to as ''avances originelles'' (original advances).
 +
#''avances annuelles'' (annual advances): expenditures on the [[wages]] of [[labor]] and non-durable producers' goods, e.g. cattle-feed, seed, etc.
 +
 +
Of these categories of advances, types (three) (original) and (four) (annual) are the most important and the ones which Quesnay analyzed most deeply. His distinction between original advances and annual advances was imported by [[Adam Smith]] as "fixed" and "circulating" capital respectively.
 +
 +
====Zigzag Analysis====
 +
This simplified form of the ''Tableau'' illustrates the zigzag flow of funds. Down on the right side of the Tableau is the productive class (Farmer) and on the upper left side there is the Artisan. On the lower left side is the Landlord.
 +
 +
For the sake of simplicity, we have two production processes—[[grain]] and crafts—and both of them use previously accumulated stocks of grain as raw materials. Only the Farmer and the Artisan produce. Some of their products they retain internally, the rest they supply to [[market]]. What is supplied to market is exchanged for cash; what is retained internally does not command cash. At the market, their goods are bought by different people.
 +
 +
In the following account, we trace the movement of grains and crafts. Note that that the numbers are not payments, but merely quantities reflecting the output flows.
 +
 +
'''Agricultural Sector''': (output owned by Farmer)
 +
*Produces 1500 grain = 600 internal + 900 to market, of which:
 +
:*Internal = 600 = 300 to Livestock + 150 to Laborer + 150 to Farmer
 +
:*To Market = 900 = 300 to Landlord + 450 to Artisan + 150 to Merchant
 +
 +
'''Manufacturing Sector''': (output owned by Artisan)
 +
*Produces 750 crafts = 150 internal + 600 to market, of which:
 +
:*Internal = 150 for Artisan
 +
:*To Market = 600 = 150 to Farmer + 150 to Laborer + 300 to Landlord
 +
 +
'''Notes''': In the agricultural sector the Farmer has to use part of his output to feed his livestock, a new category. Also the Merchant does not buy any of the Artisan's goods, but only the Farmer's grain. The Laborer is to receive 150 of the Farmer's output. This is only part of his [[wage]] (paid in kind). Another part will be paid in cash (using annual advances denoted in items (three) and (four) above). The 300 units of grain going to the Landlord are not [[rent]] payments—the Landlord just happens to buy the Farmer's grain at the market place. The Landlord's initial expenditure is in fact equal to his total rent income of 600. So, rent "initiates" the process. As the zigzag diagram shows, from his 600 rent income, the landlord spends 300 on agricultural products and 300 on manufactured products.
 +
 +
The total net product of the economy is identical (in this oversimplified example) to the Landlord’s “initial” expenditure from rent. Thus, the “rent on land” and the “net product” created are the same (Quesnay 1758, 1759).
 +
 +
==Critique==
 +
Although Quesnay was wrong about the sterility of the manufacturing sector, he was right in ascribing [[France]]'s [[poverty]] to [[mercantilism]], which he called Colbertisme (after Louis XV's finance minister, Colbert). The French government had protected French manufacturers from foreign competition, thus raising the cost of machinery for farmers, and had also sold to wealthy citizens the power to tax farmers.
 +
 +
Quesnay advocated reforming these laws by consolidating and reducing [[taxation|taxes]], getting rid of tolls and other regulations that prevented [[trade]] within France, and generally freeing the economy from the government's stifling controls. These reforms were much more sensible than his theorizing about the sterility of [[industry]]. Thus, it seems that it was Quesnay's efforts to provide these reforms with a watertight theoretical argument that were behind the forced reasoning and slightly absurd conclusions of the “Tableau.”
 +
 +
==Legacy==
 +
In Quesnay's ''Tableau Économique'' we see perhaps the first attempt to describe the workings of the economy in an analytical way, and as such this can be viewed as one of the first important contributions to [[economics|economic]] thought. Also, it was the ancestor of the multisectoral input-output systems of [[Wassily Leontief]].
 +
 +
While the accepted founder of the [[Classical economics|classical school of economics]] is [[Adam Smith]], he, in turn, acknowledged his indebtedness to the French [[Physiocrats]], the pioneer school of economic thought which advocated a single land [[tax]] and [[free trade]]. And the founder of the Physiocratic movement was François Quesnay, the King’s physician.
 +
 +
==References==
 +
*Quesnay, F. 1756-1757. "Évidence," "Fermiers," and "Grains" in ''Encyclopèdie'' of Diderot and d'Alembert.
 +
*Quesnay, F. 1758. "Questions intéréssantes sur la population, l'agriculture et le commerce" with de Marivelt in ''Mirabeau, l'Ami des Hommes''. Pt.IV.
 +
*Quesnay, F. ''Le Tableau Économique'' "First" 1758 Edition (Tableau with base of 400l., accompanied by Remarques sur les variations de la distribution des revenus annuels d'une nation; manuscript) "Second" 1759 Edition (the Tableau with base of 600l. accompanied by Extrait des oeconomies royales de M. de Sully) "Third" 1759 Edition (the Tableau with base of 600l. accompanied by Explication du tableau ecoomique and an expanded and footnoted Extrait des économies -royales de M. de Sully) A facsimile reprint of the “Tableau Économique” was published by the British Economic Association, London 1895
 +
*Quesnay, F. 1759. ''Essai sur l'administration des terres''.
 +
*Quesnay, F. 1768. ''La physiocratie''. 2 vols.
 +
*Quesnay, F. 1888. ''Oeuvres économiques et philosophiques''. Sientia Verlag, Aalen.
 +
 +
*{{1911}}
 +
 +
{{Physiocrats}}
 
{{Credit1|François_Quesnay|62242485|}}
 
{{Credit1|François_Quesnay|62242485|}}

Latest revision as of 03:39, 4 June 2021


François Quesnay

François Quesnay (June 4, 1694 – December 16, 1774) was a French economist, founder of the Physiocratic school. He also practiced surgery, serving as surgeon to King Louis XV and his mistress, Madame de Pompadour. Quesnay, in opposition to the then-dominant mercantilist position, advocated a laissez-faire policy against government interference with trade. As an attempt to support this position, Quesnay developed his famous Tableau Economique, which purportedly showed that the only productive sector was agriculture, and that industry was "sterile," i.e. unable to produce a surplus of output above costs. While Quesnay's model had many limitations, he recognized that his idealized "natural" system did not reflect reality, and thus he argued that the government should lift restrictions allowing the natural economic order to emerge.

Quesnay envisioned this natural economic state as a balanced, circular flow of funds—a system he saw as similar to the flow of blood in the body, achieving an equilibrium which maximizes the net product, and therefore the health of the society, similar to homeostasis in living organisms. This may be his most enduring insight.

Biography

François Quesnay was born on June 4, 1694, near Paris France, into a humble family. His father worked as a ploughman and merchant. In 1711, Quesnay entered into training for five years as a Parisian engraver.

Following this, he registered at the university in the college of surgery, receiving his degree in 1717. In 1718, Quesnay was accepted into the community of surgeons of Paris. In 1723, he became royal surgeon, entering in the service of the Duke of Villeroy in 1734, and in 1744, was awarded the rank of doctor of medicine. Five years later he became physician to Madame de Pompadour, influential mistress of King Louis XV. Elected to the Academy of Science in 1751, Quesnay became a member of Royal Society in 1752, and the same year he was made a noble by the king.

François Quesnay's interest in economics arose in 1756, when, hoping to draw on his country background, he was asked to contribute several articles on farming to the Encyclopédie of Denis Diderot and Jean Le Rond d'Alembert. Quesnay delved into the works of the Maréchal de Vauban, Pierre de Boisguilbert, and Richard Cantillon. Mixing all these ingredients together, he came up with his famous economic theory.

In 1758, Quesnay wrote his Tableau Économique—renowned for its "zigzag" depiction of income flows between economic sectors—to explain his doctrine. This became the founding document of the Physiocrats and the ancestor of the multisectoral input-output systems of Wassily Leontief. While the accepted founder of the classical school of economics was Adam Smith, he acknowledged his indebtedness to the French Physiocrats, and so in turn to their founder, François Quesnay.

Quesnay died on December 16, 1774, in Versailles, France.

Work

François Quesnay began with the axiom that agriculture is the only source of produit net (net product, or surplus of output above cost). The wealth of a nation, Quesnay argued, lies in the size of its net product. He believed that manufacturing and commerce were "sterile" as (in his view) the value of their output was equal to the value of their inputs. Only land, Quesnay reasoned, produced more than went into it.

He claimed that the only "productive" person is the farmer, the only one that generated a net product. The landlord, the farmhand, the foreign merchant, and, most notably, the artisan, were all part of the "sterile class" because none of them generated a net product. In this, Quesnay opposed the mercantilist doctrines of Colbert, believing that they concentrated too much on propping up industry and commerce rather than supporting agriculture.

Quesnay's system of political economy was summed up in Tableau économique (1758), which diagrammed the relationship between the different economic sectors and the flow of payments between them. In his Tableau, Quesnay developed the notion of economic equilibrium, a concept frequently used as a point of departure for subsequent economic analyses.

He conceived of the natural state of the economy as the balanced circular flow of income between economic sectors, and thus social classes, maximizing the net product. In these concepts, Quesnay saw analogies to the circulation of human blood and the homeostasis of a body.

Laissez-faire

Main article: Laissez-faire

The term laissez-faire, laissez-passer—“let it be, let it pass” (although the phrase is not readily translatable), was widely used by the Physiocrats in urging freedom from government interference, and was later adopted by Adam Smith. Quesnay believed, in opposition to the then-dominant French mercantilists, that high taxes and high barriers to imported goods were the cause of French poverty. Thus, he wanted Louis XV to deregulate trade and cut taxes so that France could begin to emulate wealthier Britain.

Influenced by Vincent de Gournay, an advocate of laissez-faire, Quesnay wished to see many of the Medieval rules governing agricultural production lifted, permitting the economy to find its "natural state." Thus, François Quesnay was largely responsible for the distinction between the ordre naturel (nature's order) and the ordre positif (positive, i.e. human-idealized, order). A good government, Quesnay argued, should follow a laissez-faire policy so that the ordre naturel could emerge.

The methodology of Quesnay's physiocratic system and his principles of policy sprang from an extreme form of the doctrine of natural law, which he believed represented the divinely appointed economic order. He was, therefore, one of the originators of the nineteenth-century doctrine of the harmony of class interests, and of the related doctrine that maximum social satisfaction occurs under free competition.

The Tableau Économique

Quesnay identified three distinct classes:

  1. the proprietary class (landlords)
  2. the productive class (farmers and agricultural farmhands)
  3. the sterile class (artisans and merchants),

and the following five protagonists were involved:

  1. Farmer: produces grain, owns livestock and seed, hires labor, pays rent to landlord.
  2. Artisan: produces crafts, uses local grains and foreign goods as raw materials.
  3. Farmhand: works for farmer, receives wages.
  4. Merchant: sells foreign goods he has imported and buys local grain for export.
  5. Landlord: owns land, receives rent from farmer.

A view of Quesnay's original Tableau Economique shows a zigzag flow. The left side of the Tableau represents the "productive" class (farmer) and the right side represents the "sterile" class (artisan). At the top in the center is the landlord. The landlord begins the flow by buying goods from both the farmer and the artisan; hence the income flows from the landlord to both the left (productive) and right (sterile) columns.

Quesnay claimed that the most "productive" sector is agriculture, the only one that can generate a net product. He was well aware, though, that he created an idealized "natural" system and he repeatedly noted that "real" conditions are never as smooth as the example in the Tableau. He wanted to bring to the King's attention the real market distortions: inequitable taxation, insufficient compensation due to excessive taxes, underdeveloped markets, protectionist trade distortions, etc., which the government could help to mitigate. In other words, he said that under the present conditions only the agricultural sector could produce a surplus that could then be used to produce more the next year and, therefore, help growth. Industry and manufacturing were, under those existing circumstances (that he wanted to change), sterile.

Quesnay (1959) used the term avances ("advances") to denote capital, i.e. expenditures during a production process that are drawn from a previously accumulated fund. He identified four types of capital, according to the type of expenditure:

  1. avances foncières (fundamental/landed advances): one-time capital expenditures undertaken by landlords on their land, e.g. land-clearing, drainage, fence-building, etc.
  2. avances souveraines (sovereign advances): one-time capital expenditures undertaken by government, e.g. roads, bridges, etc.
  3. avances primitives (primitive advances): expenditures on durable producers' goods, e.g. horses, cattle, plows, etc. In the Tableau, these are also referred to as avances originelles (original advances).
  4. avances annuelles (annual advances): expenditures on the wages of labor and non-durable producers' goods, e.g. cattle-feed, seed, etc.

Of these categories of advances, types (three) (original) and (four) (annual) are the most important and the ones which Quesnay analyzed most deeply. His distinction between original advances and annual advances was imported by Adam Smith as "fixed" and "circulating" capital respectively.

Zigzag Analysis

This simplified form of the Tableau illustrates the zigzag flow of funds. Down on the right side of the Tableau is the productive class (Farmer) and on the upper left side there is the Artisan. On the lower left side is the Landlord.

For the sake of simplicity, we have two production processes—grain and crafts—and both of them use previously accumulated stocks of grain as raw materials. Only the Farmer and the Artisan produce. Some of their products they retain internally, the rest they supply to market. What is supplied to market is exchanged for cash; what is retained internally does not command cash. At the market, their goods are bought by different people.

In the following account, we trace the movement of grains and crafts. Note that that the numbers are not payments, but merely quantities reflecting the output flows.

Agricultural Sector: (output owned by Farmer)

  • Produces 1500 grain = 600 internal + 900 to market, of which:
  • Internal = 600 = 300 to Livestock + 150 to Laborer + 150 to Farmer
  • To Market = 900 = 300 to Landlord + 450 to Artisan + 150 to Merchant

Manufacturing Sector: (output owned by Artisan)

  • Produces 750 crafts = 150 internal + 600 to market, of which:
  • Internal = 150 for Artisan
  • To Market = 600 = 150 to Farmer + 150 to Laborer + 300 to Landlord

Notes: In the agricultural sector the Farmer has to use part of his output to feed his livestock, a new category. Also the Merchant does not buy any of the Artisan's goods, but only the Farmer's grain. The Laborer is to receive 150 of the Farmer's output. This is only part of his wage (paid in kind). Another part will be paid in cash (using annual advances denoted in items (three) and (four) above). The 300 units of grain going to the Landlord are not rent payments—the Landlord just happens to buy the Farmer's grain at the market place. The Landlord's initial expenditure is in fact equal to his total rent income of 600. So, rent "initiates" the process. As the zigzag diagram shows, from his 600 rent income, the landlord spends 300 on agricultural products and 300 on manufactured products.

The total net product of the economy is identical (in this oversimplified example) to the Landlord’s “initial” expenditure from rent. Thus, the “rent on land” and the “net product” created are the same (Quesnay 1758, 1759).

Critique

Although Quesnay was wrong about the sterility of the manufacturing sector, he was right in ascribing France's poverty to mercantilism, which he called Colbertisme (after Louis XV's finance minister, Colbert). The French government had protected French manufacturers from foreign competition, thus raising the cost of machinery for farmers, and had also sold to wealthy citizens the power to tax farmers.

Quesnay advocated reforming these laws by consolidating and reducing taxes, getting rid of tolls and other regulations that prevented trade within France, and generally freeing the economy from the government's stifling controls. These reforms were much more sensible than his theorizing about the sterility of industry. Thus, it seems that it was Quesnay's efforts to provide these reforms with a watertight theoretical argument that were behind the forced reasoning and slightly absurd conclusions of the “Tableau.”

Legacy

In Quesnay's Tableau Économique we see perhaps the first attempt to describe the workings of the economy in an analytical way, and as such this can be viewed as one of the first important contributions to economic thought. Also, it was the ancestor of the multisectoral input-output systems of Wassily Leontief.

While the accepted founder of the classical school of economics is Adam Smith, he, in turn, acknowledged his indebtedness to the French Physiocrats, the pioneer school of economic thought which advocated a single land tax and free trade. And the founder of the Physiocratic movement was François Quesnay, the King’s physician.

References
ISBN links support NWE through referral fees

  • Quesnay, F. 1756-1757. "Évidence," "Fermiers," and "Grains" in Encyclopèdie of Diderot and d'Alembert.
  • Quesnay, F. 1758. "Questions intéréssantes sur la population, l'agriculture et le commerce" with de Marivelt in Mirabeau, l'Ami des Hommes. Pt.IV.
  • Quesnay, F. Le Tableau Économique "First" 1758 Edition (Tableau with base of 400l., accompanied by Remarques sur les variations de la distribution des revenus annuels d'une nation; manuscript) "Second" 1759 Edition (the Tableau with base of 600l. accompanied by Extrait des oeconomies royales de M. de Sully) "Third" 1759 Edition (the Tableau with base of 600l. accompanied by Explication du tableau ecoomique and an expanded and footnoted Extrait des économies -royales de M. de Sully) A facsimile reprint of the “Tableau Économique” was published by the British Economic Association, London 1895
  • Quesnay, F. 1759. Essai sur l'administration des terres.
  • Quesnay, F. 1768. La physiocratie. 2 vols.
  • Quesnay, F. 1888. Oeuvres économiques et philosophiques. Sientia Verlag, Aalen.
  • This article incorporates text from the Encyclopædia Britannica Eleventh Edition, a publication now in the public domain.

Credits

New World Encyclopedia writers and editors rewrote and completed the Wikipedia article in accordance with New World Encyclopedia standards. This article abides by terms of the Creative Commons CC-by-sa 3.0 License (CC-by-sa), which may be used and disseminated with proper attribution. Credit is due under the terms of this license that can reference both the New World Encyclopedia contributors and the selfless volunteer contributors of the Wikimedia Foundation. To cite this article click here for a list of acceptable citing formats.The history of earlier contributions by wikipedians is accessible to researchers here:

The history of this article since it was imported to New World Encyclopedia:

Note: Some restrictions may apply to use of individual images which are separately licensed.