Hayek, Friedrich

From New World Encyclopedia
Line 3: Line 3:
 
[[Category:Biography]]
 
[[Category:Biography]]
 
[[Category:Politics]]
 
[[Category:Politics]]
{{epname}}
+
{{epname|Hayek, Friedrich}}
 
{{Contracted}}
 
{{Contracted}}
 
[[Image:FvonHayek.jpg|thumbnail|right|200px|Friedrich Hayek]]
 
[[Image:FvonHayek.jpg|thumbnail|right|200px|Friedrich Hayek]]
  
'''Friedrich August von Hayek''' (May 8, 1899 in Vienna – March 23, 1992 in Freiburg) was an [[Austria]]n [[economist]] and [[political philosophy|political philosopher]], noted for his defense of [[liberal democracy]] and [[free market|free-market capitalism]] against [[socialism|socialist]] and [[collectivism|collectivist]] thought in the mid-20th century. Widely regarded as one of the most influential members of the [[Austrian School]] of economics, he also made significant contributions in the fields of [[jurisprudence]] and [[cognitive science]]. He shared the 1974 [[Nobel Prize|Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics]] with ideological rival [[Gunnar Myrdal]] and in 1991 he received the [[Presidential Medal of Freedom]].
+
'''Friedrich August von Hayek''' (May 8, 1899 in Vienna – March 23, 1992 in Freiburg) was an [[Austria]]n [[economics|economist]] and [[political philosophy|political philosopher]], noted for his defense of [[liberal democracy]] and [[free market|free-market capitalism]] against [[socialism|socialist]] and [[collectivism|collectivist]] thought in the mid-twentieth century. Widely regarded as one of the most influential members of the [[Austrian School]] of economics, he also made significant contributions in the fields of [[jurisprudence]] and [[cognitive science]]. He shared the 1974 [[Nobel Prize|Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics]] with ideological rival [[Gunnar Myrdal]], and in 1991 he received the [[Presidential Medal of Freedom]].
  
 
== Biography ==
 
== Biography ==
'''Friedrich Hayek''' was born in Vienna to a Catholic family of prominent intellectuals. He was a distant cousin of the philosopher [[Ludwig Wittgenstein]]. At the [[University of Vienna]] he earned doctorates in law and political science in 1921 and 1923 respectively, and he also studied psychology and economics with keen interest. Initially sympathetic to socialism, Hayek's economic thinking was transformed during his student years in Vienna through attending [[Ludwig von Mises]]' private seminars along with [[Fritz Machlup]] and other young students.  He was a student of [[Friedrich von Wieser]].
+
'''Friedrich Hayek''' was born on May 8, 1899 in [[Vienna]], [[Austria]] to a Catholic family of prominent intellectuals. He was a distant cousin of the [[philosophy|philosopher]] [[Ludwig Wittgenstein]]. At the [[University of Vienna]] he earned doctorates in [[law]] and [[political science]] in 1921 and 1923 respectively, and also studied [[psychology]] and [[economics]] with keen interest. He was a student of [[Friedrich von Wieser]]. Initially sympathetic to [[socialism]], Hayek's economic thinking was transformed during his student years in Vienna through attending [[Ludwig von Mises]]' private seminars along with [[Fritz Machlup]] and other young students.  
  
Hayek worked as a research assistant to Prof. [[Jeremiah Jenks]] of [[New York University]] from 1923 to 1924. He then served as director of the newly formed Austrian Institute for Business Cycle Research before joining the faculty of the [[London School of Economics]] at the behest of [[Lionel Robbins]] in 1931. Unwilling to return to Austria after its annexation to Nazi Germany, Hayek became a British citizen in 1938, a status he held for the remainder of his life.
+
Hayek worked as a research assistant to [[Jeremiah Jenks]] of [[New York University]] from 1923 to 1924. He then served as director of the newly formed Austrian Institute for Business Cycle Research before joining the faculty of the [[London School of Economics]] (LSE) at the behest of [[Lionel Robbins]] in 1931. Unwilling to return to Austria after its annexation to [[Nazism|Nazi]] [[Germany]], Hayek became a British citizen in 1938, a status he held for the remainder of his life.
  
In the 1930s Hayek enjoyed a considerable reputation as a leading economic theorist but his models were challenged by followers of [[John Maynard Keynes]] who argued for more active government intervention in economic affairs. The debate between the two schools of thought remains unresolved today, with Hayek's position gaining currency since the late 1970s.  
+
In the 1930s Hayek enjoyed a considerable reputation as a leading economic theorist but his models were challenged by followers of [[John Maynard Keynes]] who argued for more active government intervention in economic affairs. The debate between the two schools of thought has continue, with Hayek's position gaining currency since the late 1970s.
 +
[[Image:Hayek and Oxford students 1985.jpg|thumb|250 px|right|Friedrich A. Hayek with Andrew Melnyk, Chandran Kukathas and Hannes Hólmsteinn Gissurarson in Jesus College, Oxford, in spring of 1985.]]
 +
By 1947, Hayek was an organizer of the [[Mont Pelerin Society]], a group of classical liberals who sought to oppose what they saw as "socialism" in various areas. In 1950, Hayek left the LSE for the [[University of Chicago]], becoming a professor in the [[Committee on Social Thought]] (NOTE: He was barred from entering the Economics department because of his Austrian economic views by one member whom he would not name but many have speculated was [[Frank Hyneman Knight]]). He found himself at Chicago amongst other prominent economists, such as [[Milton Friedman]], but by this time, Hayek had turned his interests towards political philosophy and psychology.  
  
In 1950 Hayek left the [[London School of Economics]] for the [[University of Chicago]], becoming a professor in the [[Committee on Social Thought]] (NOTE: He was barred from entering the Economics department because of his Austrian economic views by one member whom he would not name and many speculate was [[Frank Knight]]). He found himself at Chicago amongst other prominent economists, such as [[Milton Friedman]], but by this time, Hayek had turned his interests towards political philosophy and psychology.  
+
From 1962 until his retirement in 1968, he was a professor at the [[University of Freiburg]]. In 1974 he shared the [[Nobel Prize|Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics]], causing a revival of interest in the Austrian school of economics. In 1984 he was appointed as a member of the [[Order of the Companions of Honour]] by [[Queen Elizabeth II of the United Kingdom|Queen Elizabeth II]] on the advice of [[Prime Minister of the United Kingdom|British Prime Minister]] [[Margaret Thatcher]] for his "services to the study of economics." Later he was a visiting professor at the [[University of Salzburg]]. Hayek died in 1992 in Freiburg, Germany.
  
From 1962 until his retirement in 1968, he was a professor at the [[Albert Ludwigs University of Freiburg|University of Freiburg]].  In 1974 he shared the [[Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics]], causing a revival of interest in the Austrian school of economics. In 1984 he was appointed as a member of the [[Order of the Companions of Honour]] by [[Elizabeth II of the United Kingdom|Queen Elizabeth II of the United Kingdom]] on the advice of [[Prime Minister of the United Kingdom|British Prime Minister]] [[Margaret Thatcher]] for his 'services to the study of economics'. Later he was a visiting professor at the [[University of Salzburg]]. Hayek died in 1992 in Freiburg, Germany.
+
==Contributions to science ==
 +
Specialists in [[business cycle]] theory recognize his early work on industrial fluctuations and modern information theorists often acknowledge Hayek's work on [[price]]s as signals. Hayek's work is also known in political philosophy (Hayek 1960), legal theory (Hayek 1973-79), and psychology (Hayek 1952).  
  
==Contributions to Science ==
+
Famous  philosopher of science [[Karl Popper]], wrote in letter to Hayek in 1944:  "I think I have learnt more from you than from any other living thinker, except perhaps Alfred Tarski." (Hacohen 2000).
Specialists in business-cycle theory recognize his early work on industrial fluctuations and modern information theorists often acknowledge Hayek's work on prices as signals. Hayek's work is also known in political philosophy (Hayek 1960), legal theory (Hayek 1973-79), and psychology (Hayek 1952).  
 
  
Famous  philosopher of science Karl Popper, wrote in letter to Hayek in 1944:  "…..''I think I have learnt more from you than from any other living thinker, except perhaps Alfred Tarski'' ......" (  Hacohen 2000).
+
Others have lauded his achievements:
 +
<blockquote>The first proponent of cortical memory networks on a major scale was neither a neuroscientist nor a computer scientist but ... a Viennese economist: Friedrich von Hayek. A man of exceptionally broad knowledge and profound insight into the operation of complex systems, Hayek applied such insight with remarkable success to economics (Nobel Prize, 1974), sociology, political science, jurisprudence, evolutionary theory, psychology, and brain science. (Fuster 1995, p. 87)</blockquote>
  
"…..''The first proponent of cortical memory networks on a major scale was neither a neuroscientist nor a computer scientist but .. a Viennes economist: Friedrich von Hayek …... A man of exceptionally broad knowledge and profound insight into the operation of complex systems, Hayek applied such insight with remarkable success to economics (Nobel Prize, 1974), sociology, political science, jurisprudence, evolutionary theory, psychology, and brain science (Hayek, 1952)''....” ( Fuster 1995, p. 87).
+
<blockquote>"Hayek posited spontaneous order in the brain arising out of distributed networks of simple units (neurons) exchanging local signals" says Harvard psychologist Steven Pinker: "Hayek was way ahead of his time in pushing this idea. It became popular in cognitive science, beginning in the mid-1980s, under the names `connectionism' and parallel distributed processing." (Postrel 2004).</blockquote>
  
 +
==The economic thinker==
  
"…...''Hayek posited spontaneous order in the brain arising out of distributed networks of simple units (neurons) exchanging local signals''..." says Harvard psychologist Steven Pinker: "……''Hayek was way ahead of his time in pushing this idea. It became popular in cognitive science, beginning in the mid-1980s, under the names `connectionism' and parallel distributed processing''….” ( Postrel 2004 ).
+
Hayek’s argument has always been that to fully control the [[economy]] meant to control all aspects of life. Economic decisions are not separate from individual values or purposes. They reflect those purposes:
  
===Hayek, the economic thinker===
+
<blockquote>We want money for many different things, and those things are not always, or even rarely, just to have money for its own sake. ... We want money for our spouses or our children or to do something in terms of the transformation of ourselves; for everything from plastic surgery to reading intellectual history or building a church. These are all non-economic goals that we express through the common means of money. (Muller 2002).</blockquote>
  
Hayek’s argument has always been that to fully control the economy meant to control all aspects of life. Economic decisions are not separate from individual values or purposes. They reflect those purposes.
+
Consequently, Hayek put the [[price]] mechanism on the same level as, for example, [[language]]. Such thinking led him to speculate on how the human [[brain]] could accommodate this evolved behavior. In ''The Sensory Order'' (1952), he proposed the hypothesis that forms the basis of the [[technology]] of [[neural network]]s  and of much of modern [[neurophysiology]]:
 +
<blockquote>
 +
When the definitive history of economic analysis during the 1930s comes to be written…….a leading character in the drama (it was quite a drama) will be Professor Hayek. ... It is hardly remembered that there was a time when the new theories of Hayek were the principal rival of the new theories of Keynes. (Hicks 1967, p. 203).</blockquote>
  
"..''We want money for many different things, and those things are not always, or even rarely, just to have money for its own sake....We want money for our spouses or our children or to do something in terms of the transformation of ourselves; for everything from plastic surgery to reading intellectual history or building a church. These are all non-economic goals that we express through the common means of money''....."( Muller 2002).
+
[[Margaret Thatcher]], the Conservative British prime minister from 1979 to 1990, was an outspoken devotée of Hayek's writings. Shortly after Thatcher became Leader of the party, she "reached into her briefcase and took out a book. It was Friedrich von Hayek's ''The Constitution of Liberty.'' Interrupting [the speaker], she held the book up for all of us to see. "This." she said sternly, "is what we believe," and banged Hayek down on the table."
  
 +
===The economic calculation problem===
  
Consequently, Hayek put the price mechanism on the same level as, for example, language. Such thinking led him to speculate on how the human brain could accommodate this evolved behavior. In ''[[The Sensory Order]]'' (1952), he proposed  hypothesis that forms the basis of the technology of neural networks  and of much of modern neurophysiology.
+
Hayek was one of the leading academic critics of [[collectivism]] in the twentieth century. Hayek believed that all forms of collectivism (even those theoretically based on voluntary cooperation) could only be maintained by a central authority of some kind. In his popular book, ''The Road to Serfdom'' (1944) and in subsequent works, Hayek claimed that [[socialism]] required central economic planning and that such planning in turn had a risk of leading towards [[totalitarianism]], because the central authority would have to be endowed with powers that would impact social life as well.  
  
 +
Building on the earlier work of [[Ludwig von Mises]] and others, Hayek also argued that in centrally-planned economies an individual or a select group of individuals must determine the distribution of resources, but that these planners will never have enough information to carry out this allocation reliably. Hayek maintained that:
  
"…….''When the definitive history of economic analysis during the 1930s comes to be written…….a leading character in the drama (it was quite a drama) will be Professor Hayek. . . It is hardly remembered that there was a time when the new theories of Hayek were the principal rival of the new theories of Keynes''….." (Hicks 1967, p. 203).
+
<blockquote>central to Mises’ thesis was that socialist economy is possible in theory but difficult (if not impossible) in practice because knowledge is decentralized and incentives are weak ... and thus it cannot achieve an efficient utilization of resources. (Hayek 1992, p. 127)</blockquote>
  
Margaret Thatcher, the Conservative British prime minister from 1979 to 1990, was an outspoken devotée of Hayek's writings. Shortly after Thatcher became Leader of the party, she "reached into her briefcase and took out a book. It was Friedrich von Hayek's ''[[The Constitution of Liberty]].'' Interrupting [the speaker], she held the book up for all of us to see."... ''This''.. ", she said sternly,".."...''is what we believe''..", and banged Hayek down on the table."
+
In Hayek's view, the central role of the state should be to maintain the [[rule of law]], with as little arbitrary intervention as possible. It was shocking enough for Britain, where his views were respectfully, though critically, received. But in the United States, where ''Reader's Digest'' published a condensed version, ''The Road to Serfdom'' was a bestseller and a political lightning rod. It rallied supporters of traditional free enterprise and enraged the intelligentsia to whom it was addressed. How dare this mustachioed Austrian suggest that the ambitions of the [[New Deal]] might have anything in common with [[Hitler]] or [[Stalin]]! (Postrel 2004).
  
====The economic calculation problem====
+
Hayek went eventually as far as to attribute the birth of [[civilization]] to private property in his book ''The Fatal Conceit'' (1988). According to him, price signals are the only possible way to let each economic decision maker communicate tacit knowledge or dispersed knowledge to each other, in order to solve the economic calculation problem.
  
Hayek was one of the leading academic critics of [[collectivism]] in the 20th century. Hayek believed that all forms of collectivism (even those theoretically based on voluntary cooperation) could only be maintained by a central authority of some kind. In his popular book, ''[[The Road to Serfdom]]'' (1944) and in subsequent works, Hayek claimed that socialism required central economic planning and that such planning in turn had a risk of leading towards [[totalitarianism]], because the central authority would have to be endowed with powers that would impact social life as well.
+
===The business cycle===
 
+
In ''Prices and Production'' (1931) and ''Monetary Theory and the Trade Cycle'' (1933) Hayek showed how monetary injections, by lowering the rate of [[interest]] below what [[Ludwig von Mises]] called its "natural rate," distort the economy's inter-temporal structure of production. Most theories of the effects of [[money]] on [[price]]s and output (then and since) consider only the effects of the total [[money supply]] on the price level and aggregate output or [[investment]]. Hayek, instead, focused on the way money enters the economy ("injection effects") and how this affects relative prices and investment in particular sectors.  
Building on the earlier work of Mises and others, Hayek also argued that in centrally-planned economies an individual or a select group of individuals must determine the distribution of resources, but that these planners will never have enough information to carry out this allocation reliably. Hayek maintained that:
 
 
 
 
 
"……''central Mises’ thesis was  that socialist economy is possible in theory but difficult ( if not impossible ) in practice because knowledge is decentralized and incentives are weak ….and thus  it cannot achieve an efficient utilization of resources''……." ( Hayek 1992, p. 127)
 
 
 
 
 
In Hayek's view, the central role of the state should be to maintain the [[rule of law]], with as little arbitrary intervention as possible. It was shocking enough for Britain, where his views were respectfully, though critically, received. But in the United States, where ''Reader's Digest'' published a condensed version, ''[[The Road to Serfdom]]'' was a bestseller and a political lightning rod. It rallied supporters of traditional free enterprise and enraged the intelligentsia to whom it was addressed. How dare this mustachioed Austrian suggest that the ambitions of the New Deal might have anything in common with Hitler or Stalin! ( Postrel 2004 ).
 
 
 
 
 
Hayek went eventually as far as to attribute the birth of civilization to private property  in his book ''[[The Fatal Conceit]]'' (1988). According to him, price signals are the only possible way to let each economic decision maker communicate tacit knowledge or dispersed knowledge  to each other, in order to solve the economic calculation problem .
 
 
 
====The business cycle====
 
In '''<<are these titles? do they need to be bolded or italicized?>>Prices and Production (1931) and Monetary Theory and the Trade Cycle (1933)''' Hayek showed how monetary injections, by lowering the rate of interest below what Mises called its "natural rate," distort the economy's inter temporal structure of production. Most theories of the effects of money on prices and output (then and since) consider only the effects of the total money supply on the price level and aggregate output or investment. Hayek, instead, focuses on the way money enters the economy ("injection effects") and how this affects relative prices and investment in particular sectors.  
 
  
 
In Hayek's framework, investments in some stages of production are "malinvestments" if they do not help to align the structure of production to consumers' inter temporal preferences. The reduction in interest rates caused by credit expansion directs resources toward capital-intensive processes and early stages of production (whose investment demands are more interest-rate elastic), thus "lengthening" the period of production. If interest rates had fallen because consumers had changed their preferences to favor future over present consumption, then the longer time structure of production would have been an appropriate, coordinating response.  
 
In Hayek's framework, investments in some stages of production are "malinvestments" if they do not help to align the structure of production to consumers' inter temporal preferences. The reduction in interest rates caused by credit expansion directs resources toward capital-intensive processes and early stages of production (whose investment demands are more interest-rate elastic), thus "lengthening" the period of production. If interest rates had fallen because consumers had changed their preferences to favor future over present consumption, then the longer time structure of production would have been an appropriate, coordinating response.  
Line 68: Line 63:
 
Every artificial boom induced by credit expansion, then, is self-reversing. Recovery consists of liquidating the malinvestments induced by the lowering of interest rates below their natural levels, thus restoring the time structure of production so that it accords with consumers' inter temporal preferences.
 
Every artificial boom induced by credit expansion, then, is self-reversing. Recovery consists of liquidating the malinvestments induced by the lowering of interest rates below their natural levels, thus restoring the time structure of production so that it accords with consumers' inter temporal preferences.
  
====Spontaneous order====
+
===Spontaneous order===
In ''[[Economics and Knowledge]]''(1937) and ''[[The Use of Knowledge in Society]]'' (1945) Hayek argued that the central economic problem facing society is not, as is commonly expressed in textbooks, the allocation of given resources among competing ends.
+
In ''Economics and Knowledge''(1937) and ''The Use of Knowledge in Society'' (1945) Hayek argued that the central economic problem facing society is not, as is commonly expressed in textbooks, the allocation of given resources among competing ends:
 
+
<blockquote>It is rather a problem of how to secure the best use of resources known to any of the members of society, for ends whose relative importance only those individuals know. Or, to put it briefly, it is a problem of the utilization of knowledge not given to anyone in its totality. (Hayek 1945, p. 78).</blockquote>
".....''It is rather a problem of how to secure the best use of resources known to any of the members of society, for ends whose relative importance only those individuals know. Or, to put it briefly, it is a problem of the utilization of knowledge not given to anyone in its totality''....." (Hayek 1945, p. 78).
 
 
   
 
   
 +
The efficient exchange and use of resources, Hayek claimed, can be maintained only through the price mechanism in free markets. He argued that the price mechanism serves to share and synchronize local and personal knowledge, allowing society's members to achieve diverse, complicated ends through a principle of spontaneous self-organization. He coined the term "[[catallaxy]]" to describe a "self-organizing system of voluntary co-operation." (Hayek 1945)
  
The efficient exchange and use of resources, Hayek claimed, can be maintained only through the price mechanism in free markets (see [[economic calculation problem]]). He argued that the price mechanism serves to share and synchronize local and personal knowledge, allowing society's members to achieve diverse, complicated ends through a principle of spontaneous self-organization. He coined the term [[catallaxy]] to describe a "self-organizing system of voluntary co-operation"( Hayek 1945 ).
+
Much of the knowledge necessary for running the economic system, Hayek contended, is in the form not of  
 
+
<blockquote>"scientific" or technical knowledge—the conscious awareness of the rules governing natural and social phenomena—but of ... knowledge, the idiosyncratic, dispersed bits of understanding of "circumstances of time and place" (Hayek 1968).</blockquote>
 
 
Much of the knowledge necessary for running the economic system, Hayek contended, is in the form not of "…..''scientific" or technical knowledge—the conscious awareness of the rules governing natural and social phenomena—but of .. knowledge, the idiosyncratic, dispersed bits of understanding of ‘circumstances of time and place’''…..." (Hayek 1968).  
 
  
 
This tacit knowledge is often not consciously known even to those who possess it and can never be communicated to a central authority. The market tends to use this tacit knowledge through a type of [[discovery procedure]] (Hayek 1968), by which this information is unknowingly transmitted throughout the economy as an unintended consequence of individuals' pursuing their own ends.
 
This tacit knowledge is often not consciously known even to those who possess it and can never be communicated to a central authority. The market tends to use this tacit knowledge through a type of [[discovery procedure]] (Hayek 1968), by which this information is unknowingly transmitted throughout the economy as an unintended consequence of individuals' pursuing their own ends.
  
 +
Indeed, Hayek's (1948) distinction between the neoclassical notion of "[[competition]]," identified as a set of equilibrium conditions (number of market participants, characteristics of the product, and so on), and the older notion of notion of competition as a rivalrous process, has been widely influential in Austrian economics.
  
Indeed, Hayek's (1948) distinction between the neoclassical notion of "competition," identified as a set of equilibrium conditions (number of market participants, characteristics of the product, and so on), and the older notion of notion of competition as a rivalrous process, has been widely influential in Austrian economics .
+
Hayek went eventually as far as to attribute the birth of civilization to private property in his book ''The Fatal Conceit'' (1988). According to him, price signals are the only possible way to let each economic decision maker communicate tacit knowledge or dispersed knowledge to each other, in order to solve the economic calculation problem.  
  
Hayek went eventually as far as to attribute the birth of civilization to private property  in his book ''[[The Fatal Conceit]]'' (1988). According to him, price signals are the only possible way to let each economic decision maker communicate tacit knowledge or dispersed knowledge  to each other, in order to solve the economic calculation problem .
+
On the other side, the key to a functioning economy—or society—is decentralized competition. In a market economy, prices act as a "system of telecommunications," coordinating information far beyond the scope of a single mind. They permit ever-evolving order to emerge from dispersed knowledge. In any complex operation, there is too much relevant information for a single person or small group to absorb and act on.
 
 
 
 
On the other side, the key to a functioning economy — or society —is decentralized competition. In a market economy, prices act as a "system of telecommunications," coordinating information far beyond the scope of a single mind. They permit ever-evolving order to emerge from dispersed knowledge. In any complex operation, there is too much relevant information for a single person or small group to absorb and act on.
 
 
 
 
 
For Hayek, market competition generates a particular kind of order—an order that is the product "of human action but not human design" (a phrase Hayek borrowed from Adam Smith's mentor Adam Ferguson).  
 
  
 +
For Hayek, market competition generates a particular kind of order—an order that is the product "of human action but not human design" (a phrase Hayek borrowed from [[Adam Smith]]'s mentor [[Adam Ferguson]]).
  
 
This "spontaneous order" is a system that comes about through the independent actions of many individuals, and produces overall benefits unintended and mostly unforeseen by those whose actions bring it about. To distinguish between this kind of order and that of a deliberate, planned system, Hayek (1968b, pp. 72-76) used the Greek terms ''cosmos'' for a spontaneous order and ''taxis'' for a consciously planned one.  
 
This "spontaneous order" is a system that comes about through the independent actions of many individuals, and produces overall benefits unintended and mostly unforeseen by those whose actions bring it about. To distinguish between this kind of order and that of a deliberate, planned system, Hayek (1968b, pp. 72-76) used the Greek terms ''cosmos'' for a spontaneous order and ''taxis'' for a consciously planned one.  
  
Examples of a cosmos include the market system as a whole, money, the common law, and even language. A taxis, by contrast, is a designed or constructed organization, like a firm or bureau; these are the "islands of conscious power in [the] ocean of unconscious cooperation like “…''lumps of butter coagulating in a pail of buttermilk''…”
+
Examples of a "cosmos" include the market system as a whole, money, the [[common law]], and even language. A "taxis," by contrast, is a designed or constructed organization, like a [[corporation]] or bureau; these are the "islands of conscious power in [the] ocean of unconscious cooperation like 'lumps of butter coagulating in a pail of buttermilk'”
 
 
 
 
Most importantly, however, Hayek always stressed that his moral philosophy has to be backed by “….''a complex system of moral codes, rules of fairness, as well as an articulated system of punishment for the violators……system under which bad man can do a least harm''….” ( Hayek 1945 ).
 
 
 
Only then, the role played by his ''spontaneous order'' in a society  organized around a market order (in which the apparatus of state is employed solely to secure the peace necessary for a market of free individuals to function), the system works ( Hayek 1949).
 
 
 
====Theorem on transitional and developing countries====
 
 
 
Let us start with a quote that logically follows the last paragraph of “ '''Spontaneous Order'''” in this text:
 
 
 
"….. ''I think that permanence and stability are the cardinal virtues of the legal rules that make private innovation and public progress possible. To my mind there is no doubt that a legal regime that embraced private property and freedom of contract is the only one that in practice can offer that permanence and stability .. In reaching this conclusion, I have been heavily influenced by the work of Friedrich Hayek''….." (Epstein, Chicago School of Law).
 
 
 
 
 
When we combine Hayek’s key theorems, it emerges that it takes: (a) the “'''learning process'''” of how to play the social roles of which market relations is based on and keeping within the implicit rules and (b) the moral codes of co-operative society ( which punishes violators ), to form a system marginalizing the opportunities and other element harmful to the society while forming the ultimate criterion of success.
 
 
 
Such a “learning process” - in which the moral codes are spontaneously achieved - is, however, a function of time usually measured in terms of generations ( Dallago 1996, pp.82, 116-117).
 
 
 
 
 
The time-element of “'''learning process'''” is obviously non-existent in developing and transitional societies. Hence, we see there quick "privatizations" ( usually by the old oligarchy transformed into "democratic" leadership that had the money to buy the bulk of industrial infrastructure )  and “quasi-market” relations without any moral scruples, codes of conduct, and, above all, without any functioning legal system that would punish the violators.
 
 
 
  
So far, most of the methods trying to substitute the generations-long “learning process” - of how to achieve at least minimum functioning legal , moral, and co-operative notion in the society -  in these new “free market” societies were based on exogenous inputs. They consisted either of the transfer of the whole constitution ( or major substantive and civil laws ) with short courses for upper echelons of the indigenous law profession or just amendments some of the old “communist-era” laws with or without help from the legal experts from historical democracies.  
+
Most importantly, however, Hayek always stressed that his [[moral philosophy]] has to be backed by “a complex system of moral codes, rules of fairness, as well as an articulated system of punishment for the violators ... system under which bad man can do a least harm.” (Hayek 1945).
  
In any case, these exogenous tries only helped to jump-start the self-perpetuating and opportunism-strengthening  loop between the old-oligarchy-cum-new-“democratic”-leaders and lawlessness, because the "new leadership" still “owns” the whole legal and police apparatus anyway and the two judicial measures ( combined with their "we-are-above-the-law" behavior ) only contributed to further moral and, in many cases,  economic decay of these societies.
+
Only then, the role played by his "spontaneous order" in a society organized around a market order (in which the apparatus of state is employed solely to secure the peace necessary for a market of free individuals to function), the system works (Hayek 1949).
  
There, Hayek’s Theorem of  generations-long learning process on the road to full-fledged democracy showed to be one of his most prophetic.
+
===Theorem on transitional and developing countries===
  
====Hayek vs. Maynard Keynes====
+
Let us start with a quote that logically follows the last paragraph of “Spontaneous Order” in this text:
As one of Keynes's leading professional adversaries, Hayek was well situated to provide a full refutation of the General Theory. But he never did. Part of the explanation for this no doubt lies with Keynes's personal charm and legendary rhetorical skill, along with Hayek's general reluctance to engage in direct confrontation with his colleagues. Hayek also considered Keynes an ally in the fight against wartime inflation and did not want to detract from that issue (Hayek, 1994, p. 91).  
+
<blockquote>I think that permanence and stability are the cardinal virtues of the legal rules that make private innovation and public progress possible. To my mind there is no doubt that a legal regime that embraced private property and freedom of contract is the only one that in practice can offer that permanence and stability .. In reaching this conclusion, I have been heavily influenced by the work of Friedrich Hayek. (Epstein, Chicago School of Law).</blockquote>
  
Caldwell (1988) suggests another reason: it was during this time that Hayek was losing faith in equilibrium theory and moving toward a "market process" view of economic activity, making it difficult for him to engage Keynes on the same terms in which they had debated earlier. Furthermore, as Hayek later explained, Keynes was constantly changing his theoretical framework, and Hayek saw no point in working out a detailed critique of the ''[[General Theory]]'', if Keynes might change his mind again (Hayek, 1963, p. 60; Hayek, 1966, pp. 240-41).  
+
When we combine Hayek’s key theorems, it emerges that it takes: (a) the “learning process” of how to play the social roles of which market relations is based on and keeping within the implicit rules and (b) the moral codes of co-operative society (which punishes violators), to form a system marginalizing the opportunities and other element harmful to the society while forming the ultimate criterion of success.  
  
Hayek thought a better course would be to produce a fuller elaboration of [[Böhm-Bawerk]]'s capital theory, and he began to devote his energies to this project.
+
Such a “learning process” - in which the moral codes are spontaneously achieved - is, however, a function of time usually measured in terms of generations (Dallago 1996, pp.82, 116-117).
  
 +
The time-element of “learning process” is obviously non-existent in developing and transitional societies. Hence, we see there quick "privatizations" (usually by the old [[oligarchy]] transformed into "democratic" leadership that had the money to buy the bulk of industrial infrastructure) and “quasi-market” relations without any moral scruples, codes of conduct, and, above all, without any functioning legal system that would punish the violators.
  
The following quote puts Hayek’s “side” into a proper perspective. ".. .''Underlying all this has been a fundamental shift in ideas …. The dramatic redefinition of state and marketplace over the last two decades demonstrates anew the truth of Keynes' axiom about the overwhelming power of ideas. For concepts and notions that were decidedly outside the mainstream have now moved, with some rapidity, to center stage and are reshaping economies in every corner of the world. Even [[Keynes]] himself has been done in by his own dictum. During the bombing of London in World War II, he arranged for a transplanted Austrian economist, Friedrich von Hayek, to be temporarily housed in a college at Cambridge University. It was a generous gesture; after all, Keynes was the leading economist of his time, and Hayek, his rather obscure critic. In the postwar years, Keynes' theories of government management of the economy appeared unassailable. But a half century later, it is Keynes who has been toppled and Hayek, the fierce advocate of free markets, who is preeminent'' .." (Yergin &Stanislaw  1998. pp. 14-15)
+
So far, most of the methods trying to substitute the generations-long “learning process” - of how to achieve at least minimum functioning legal, moral, and co-operative notion in the society - in these new “free market” societies were based on exogenous inputs. They consisted either of the transfer of the whole constitution (or major substantive and civil laws) with short courses for upper echelons of the indigenous law profession or just amendments some of the old “communist-era” laws with or without help from the legal experts from historical democracies.  
  
 +
In any case, these exogenous tries only helped to jump-start the self-perpetuating and opportunism-strengthening loop between the old-oligarchy-cum-new-“democratic”-leaders and lawlessness, because the "new leadership" still “owns” the whole legal and police apparatus anyway and the two judicial measures (combined with their "we-are-above-the-law" behavior) only contributed to further moral and,in many cases,  economic decay of these societies.
  
===Contribution to social and political philosophy===
+
There, Hayek’s Theorem of generations-long learning process on the road to full-fledged democracy showed to be one of his most prophetic.
  
Hayek's most significant contribution, he explains, "…..''was to make clear how our present complex social structure is not the result of the intended actions of individuals but of the unintended consequences of individual interactions over a long period of time, the product of social evolution, not of deliberate planning''…."(Postrel 2004).
+
===Hayek vs. Keynes===
 +
As one of [[John Maynard Keynes|Keynes]]' leading professional adversaries, Hayek was well situated to provide a full refutation of Keynes' ''General Theory''. But he never did. Part of the explanation for this no doubt lies with Keynes's personal charm and legendary [[rhetoric]]al skill, along with Hayek's general reluctance to engage in direct confrontation with his colleagues. Hayek also considered Keynes an ally in the fight against [[war]]time [[inflation]] and did not want to detract from that issue (Hayek, 1994, p. 91).  
  
 +
Caldwell (1988) suggests another reason: it was during this time that Hayek was losing faith in equilibrium theory and moving toward a "market process" view of economic activity, making it difficult for him to engage Keynes on the same terms in which they had debated earlier. Furthermore, as Hayek later explained, Keynes was constantly changing his theoretical framework, and Hayek saw no point in working out a detailed critique of the ''General Theory'', if Keynes might change his mind again (Hayek, 1963, p. 60; Hayek, 1966, pp. 240-41). Hayek thought a better course would be to produce a fuller elaboration of [[Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk]]'s [[capital]] theory, and he began to devote his energies to this project.
  
Hayek's major insight, which he referred to as his "one discovery" in the social sciences, was to define the central economic and social problem as one of organizing dispersed knowledge. Different people have different purposes. They know different things about the world. Much important information is local and transitory, known only to the man on the spot.
+
The following quote puts Hayek’s “side” into a proper perspective.
 +
<blockquote>
 +
Underlying all this has been a fundamental shift in ideas ... The dramatic redefinition of state and marketplace over the last two decades demonstrates anew the truth of Keynes' axiom about the overwhelming power of ideas. For concepts and notions that were decidedly outside the mainstream have now moved, with some rapidity, to center stage and are reshaping economies in every corner of the world. Even [[Keynes]] himself has been done in by his own dictum. During the bombing of London in World War II, he arranged for a transplanted Austrian economist, Friedrich von Hayek, to be temporarily housed in a college at Cambridge University. It was a generous gesture; after all, Keynes was the leading economist of his time, and Hayek, his rather obscure critic. In the postwar years, Keynes' theories of government management of the economy appeared unassailable. But a half century later, it is Keynes who has been toppled and Hayek, the fierce advocate of free markets, who is preeminent. (Yergin & Stanislaw 1998. pp. 14-15)</blockquote>
  
 +
==Contribution to social and political philosophy==
  
"…… ''Some of that knowledge is objective and quantifiable, but much is tacit and unarticulated…. Often we only discover what we truly want as we actually make trade-offs between competing goods ……The economic problem of society'' ………", Hayek wrote in his 1945 article, "….''is thus not merely a problem of how to allocate `given' resources …. if `given' is taken to mean given to a single mind which deliberately solves the problem set by these `data….. It is rather a problem of how to secure the best use of resources known to any of the members of society, for ends whose relative importance only these individuals know….. Or, to put it briefly, it is a problem of the utilization of knowledge which is not given to anyone in totality''….." ( Hayek 1945).
+
Hayek's most significant contribution,  
 +
<blockquote>was to make clear how our present complex social structure is not the result of the intended actions of individuals but of the unintended consequences of individual interactions over a long period of time, the product of social evolution, not of deliberate planning. (Postrel 2004).</blockquote> 
  
 +
Hayek's major insight, which he referred to as his "one discovery" in the [[social sciences]], was to define the central economic and social problem as one of organizing dispersed knowledge. Different people have different purposes. They know different things about the world. Much important information is local and transitory, known only to the man on the spot.
  
"..''Hayek made a quite fruitful suggestion, made contemporaneously by the psychologist Donald Hebb, that whatever kind of encounter the sensory system has with the world, a corresponding event between a particular cell in the brain and some other cell carrying the information from the outside word must result in reinforcement of the connection between those cells. These day, this is known as a Hebbian synapse, but von Hayek quite independently came upon the idea. I think the essence of his analysis still remains with us'' . . ".    ( Edelman 1987, p. 25).
+
<blockquote>"Some of that knowledge is objective and quantifiable, but much is tacit and unarticulated. Often we only discover what we truly want as we actually make trade-offs between competing goods ... The economic problem of society," Hayek wrote in his 1945 article, "is thus not merely a problem of how to allocate `given' resources ... if `given' is taken to mean given to a single mind which deliberately solves the problem set by these data. ... It is rather a problem of how to secure the best use of resources known to any of the members of society, for ends whose relative importance only these individuals know ... Or, to put it briefly, it is a problem of the utilization of knowledge which is not given to anyone in totality." (Hayek 1945).</blockquote>
  
== Influence, recognition and legacy of Hayek’s work ==
+
<blockquote>Hayek made a quite fruitful suggestion, made contemporaneously by the psychologist Donald Hebb, that whatever kind of encounter the sensory system has with the world, a corresponding event between a particular cell in the brain and some other cell carrying the information from the outside word must result in reinforcement of the connection between those cells. These day, this is known as a Hebbian synapse, but von Hayek quite independently came upon the idea. I think the essence of his analysis still remains with us. (Edelman 1987, p. 25).</blockquote>
  
By 1947, Hayek was an organizer of the [[Mont Pelerin Society]], a group of classical liberals who sought to oppose what they saw as "socialism" in various areas. 
+
== Influence, recognition, and legacy ==
  
Having heavily influenced Margaret Thatcher's economic approach, and some of Ronald Reagan's economic advisors, in the 1990's Hayek became one of the most-respected economists in Eastern Europe. There is a general consensus that his analyses of socialist as well as non-socialist societies were proven prescient by the breakup of communist Eastern Europe.
+
Hayek's intellectual foundation was based on the ideas of [[David Hume]], [[Adam Smith]], and other Scottish thinkers of the 1700s. He had a wide-reaching influence on contemporary [[economics]], [[politics]], [[philosophy]], [[sociology]], [[psychology]], and [[anthropology]]. For example, Hayek's discussion in ''The Road to Serfdom'' (1944) about truth and falsehood in [[totalitarian]] systems influenced some later opponents of [[postmodernism]]. (Wolin 2004).  
  
Hayek's intellectual foundation was based on the ideas of David Hume, Adam Smith and other Scottish thinkers of the 1700s. He had a wide-reaching influence on contemporary economics, politics, philosophy, sociology, psychology and anthropology.  For example, Hayek's discussion in ''[[The Road to Serfdom]]'' (1944) about truth and falsehood in [[totalitarian]] systems influenced some later opponents of [[postmodernism]] (e.g., Wolin 2004).  
+
Having heavily influenced [[Margaret Thatcher]]'s economic approach, and some of [[Ronald Reagan]]'s economic advisors, in the 1990s Hayek became one of the most-respected economists in Europe. There is a general consensus that his analyses of socialist as well as non-socialist societies were proven prescient by the breakup of [[communism|communist]] Eastern Europe.
  
 
He shared the 1974 [[Nobel Prize|Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics]] with ideological rival [[Gunnar Myrdal]] and in 1991 he received the [[Presidential Medal of Freedom]], one of the two highest civilian awards in the United States, “for a lifetime of looking beyond the horizon.”<ref>[http://bushlibrary.tamu.edu/research/papers/1991/91111800.html Remarks on Presenting the Presidential Medal of Freedom Awards] November 18, 1991. Retrieved February 9, 2007.</ref>
 
He shared the 1974 [[Nobel Prize|Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics]] with ideological rival [[Gunnar Myrdal]] and in 1991 he received the [[Presidential Medal of Freedom]], one of the two highest civilian awards in the United States, “for a lifetime of looking beyond the horizon.”<ref>[http://bushlibrary.tamu.edu/research/papers/1991/91111800.html Remarks on Presenting the Presidential Medal of Freedom Awards] November 18, 1991. Retrieved February 9, 2007.</ref>
  
 +
==Notes==
 +
<references/>
  
 
==Publications==
 
==Publications==
Line 171: Line 151:
 
*Hayek, F. A.,The Sensory Order, University of Chicago Press,  Chicago  1952  
 
*Hayek, F. A.,The Sensory Order, University of Chicago Press,  Chicago  1952  
 
*Hayek, F. A.. The Constitution of Liberty, University of Chicago Press, Chicago 1960
 
*Hayek, F. A.. The Constitution of Liberty, University of Chicago Press, Chicago 1960
*Hayek, F. A. "The Economics of the 1930s as Seen from London”, 1963; in: Hayek, 1995, pp. 49-73.  
+
*Hayek, F. A. "The Economics of the 1930s as Seen from London,1963; in: Hayek, 1995, pp. 49-73.  
*Hayek, F. A.. "Personal Recollections of Keynes and the 'Keynesian Revolution.'", 1966 ; in Hayek, 1995, pp. 240-46. :
+
*Hayek, F. A.. "Personal Recollections of Keynes and the 'Keynesian Revolution.'," 1966 ; in Hayek, 1995, pp. 240-46. :
 
*Hayek, F. A. 1968a. "Competition as a Discovery Procedure." In Hayek, 1978, pp. 179-90.  
 
*Hayek, F. A. 1968a. "Competition as a Discovery Procedure." In Hayek, 1978, pp. 179-90.  
 
*Hayek, F. A. 1968b. "The Confusion of Language in Political Thought." In Hayek, 1978, pp. 71-97.  
 
*Hayek, F. A. 1968b. "The Confusion of Language in Political Thought." In Hayek, 1978, pp. 71-97.  
Line 206: Line 186:
 
* [http://www.econ-pol.unisi.it/pubdocenti/HEI99.pdf The economics of information, market socialism and Hayek's legacy] Retrieved August 7, 2007.
 
* [http://www.econ-pol.unisi.it/pubdocenti/HEI99.pdf The economics of information, market socialism and Hayek's legacy] Retrieved August 7, 2007.
 
* Caldwell, Bruce [http://cob.jmu.edu/rossermv/Caldwell.pdf Hayek and Socialism] ''Journal of Economic Literature'' Vol. XXXV (December 1997), pp. 1856-1890 Retrieved August 7, 2007.
 
* Caldwell, Bruce [http://cob.jmu.edu/rossermv/Caldwell.pdf Hayek and Socialism] ''Journal of Economic Literature'' Vol. XXXV (December 1997), pp. 1856-1890 Retrieved August 7, 2007.
* [http://reason.com/hayekint.shtml "The Road from Serfdom"], interview in ''[[Reason (magazine)|Reason]]'' by Thomas W. Hazlett Retrieved August 7, 2007.
+
* [http://reason.com/hayekint.shtml "The Road from Serfdom"], interview in ''Reason'' by Thomas W. Hazlett Retrieved August 7, 2007.
  
  
 
{{Credit1|Friedrich_Hayek|63612927|}}
 
{{Credit1|Friedrich_Hayek|63612927|}}

Revision as of 20:49, 30 August 2007

Friedrich Hayek

Friedrich August von Hayek (May 8, 1899 in Vienna – March 23, 1992 in Freiburg) was an Austrian economist and political philosopher, noted for his defense of liberal democracy and free-market capitalism against socialist and collectivist thought in the mid-twentieth century. Widely regarded as one of the most influential members of the Austrian School of economics, he also made significant contributions in the fields of jurisprudence and cognitive science. He shared the 1974 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics with ideological rival Gunnar Myrdal, and in 1991 he received the Presidential Medal of Freedom.

Biography

Friedrich Hayek was born on May 8, 1899 in Vienna, Austria to a Catholic family of prominent intellectuals. He was a distant cousin of the philosopher Ludwig Wittgenstein. At the University of Vienna he earned doctorates in law and political science in 1921 and 1923 respectively, and also studied psychology and economics with keen interest. He was a student of Friedrich von Wieser. Initially sympathetic to socialism, Hayek's economic thinking was transformed during his student years in Vienna through attending Ludwig von Mises' private seminars along with Fritz Machlup and other young students.

Hayek worked as a research assistant to Jeremiah Jenks of New York University from 1923 to 1924. He then served as director of the newly formed Austrian Institute for Business Cycle Research before joining the faculty of the London School of Economics (LSE) at the behest of Lionel Robbins in 1931. Unwilling to return to Austria after its annexation to Nazi Germany, Hayek became a British citizen in 1938, a status he held for the remainder of his life.

In the 1930s Hayek enjoyed a considerable reputation as a leading economic theorist but his models were challenged by followers of John Maynard Keynes who argued for more active government intervention in economic affairs. The debate between the two schools of thought has continue, with Hayek's position gaining currency since the late 1970s.

File:Hayek and Oxford students 1985.jpg
Friedrich A. Hayek with Andrew Melnyk, Chandran Kukathas and Hannes Hólmsteinn Gissurarson in Jesus College, Oxford, in spring of 1985.

By 1947, Hayek was an organizer of the Mont Pelerin Society, a group of classical liberals who sought to oppose what they saw as "socialism" in various areas. In 1950, Hayek left the LSE for the University of Chicago, becoming a professor in the Committee on Social Thought (NOTE: He was barred from entering the Economics department because of his Austrian economic views by one member whom he would not name but many have speculated was Frank Hyneman Knight). He found himself at Chicago amongst other prominent economists, such as Milton Friedman, but by this time, Hayek had turned his interests towards political philosophy and psychology.

From 1962 until his retirement in 1968, he was a professor at the University of Freiburg. In 1974 he shared the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics, causing a revival of interest in the Austrian school of economics. In 1984 he was appointed as a member of the Order of the Companions of Honour by Queen Elizabeth II on the advice of British Prime Minister Margaret Thatcher for his "services to the study of economics." Later he was a visiting professor at the University of Salzburg. Hayek died in 1992 in Freiburg, Germany.

Contributions to science

Specialists in business cycle theory recognize his early work on industrial fluctuations and modern information theorists often acknowledge Hayek's work on prices as signals. Hayek's work is also known in political philosophy (Hayek 1960), legal theory (Hayek 1973-79), and psychology (Hayek 1952).

Famous philosopher of science Karl Popper, wrote in letter to Hayek in 1944: "I think I have learnt more from you than from any other living thinker, except perhaps Alfred Tarski." (Hacohen 2000).

Others have lauded his achievements:

The first proponent of cortical memory networks on a major scale was neither a neuroscientist nor a computer scientist but ... a Viennese economist: Friedrich von Hayek. A man of exceptionally broad knowledge and profound insight into the operation of complex systems, Hayek applied such insight with remarkable success to economics (Nobel Prize, 1974), sociology, political science, jurisprudence, evolutionary theory, psychology, and brain science. (Fuster 1995, p. 87)

"Hayek posited spontaneous order in the brain arising out of distributed networks of simple units (neurons) exchanging local signals" says Harvard psychologist Steven Pinker: "Hayek was way ahead of his time in pushing this idea. It became popular in cognitive science, beginning in the mid-1980s, under the names `connectionism' and parallel distributed processing." (Postrel 2004).

The economic thinker

Hayek’s argument has always been that to fully control the economy meant to control all aspects of life. Economic decisions are not separate from individual values or purposes. They reflect those purposes:

We want money for many different things, and those things are not always, or even rarely, just to have money for its own sake. ... We want money for our spouses or our children or to do something in terms of the transformation of ourselves; for everything from plastic surgery to reading intellectual history or building a church. These are all non-economic goals that we express through the common means of money. (Muller 2002).

Consequently, Hayek put the price mechanism on the same level as, for example, language. Such thinking led him to speculate on how the human brain could accommodate this evolved behavior. In The Sensory Order (1952), he proposed the hypothesis that forms the basis of the technology of neural networks and of much of modern neurophysiology:

When the definitive history of economic analysis during the 1930s comes to be written…….a leading character in the drama (it was quite a drama) will be Professor Hayek. ... It is hardly remembered that there was a time when the new theories of Hayek were the principal rival of the new theories of Keynes. (Hicks 1967, p. 203).

Margaret Thatcher, the Conservative British prime minister from 1979 to 1990, was an outspoken devotée of Hayek's writings. Shortly after Thatcher became Leader of the party, she "reached into her briefcase and took out a book. It was Friedrich von Hayek's The Constitution of Liberty. Interrupting [the speaker], she held the book up for all of us to see. "This." she said sternly, "is what we believe," and banged Hayek down on the table."

The economic calculation problem

Hayek was one of the leading academic critics of collectivism in the twentieth century. Hayek believed that all forms of collectivism (even those theoretically based on voluntary cooperation) could only be maintained by a central authority of some kind. In his popular book, The Road to Serfdom (1944) and in subsequent works, Hayek claimed that socialism required central economic planning and that such planning in turn had a risk of leading towards totalitarianism, because the central authority would have to be endowed with powers that would impact social life as well.

Building on the earlier work of Ludwig von Mises and others, Hayek also argued that in centrally-planned economies an individual or a select group of individuals must determine the distribution of resources, but that these planners will never have enough information to carry out this allocation reliably. Hayek maintained that:

central to Mises’ thesis was that socialist economy is possible in theory but difficult (if not impossible) in practice because knowledge is decentralized and incentives are weak ... and thus it cannot achieve an efficient utilization of resources. (Hayek 1992, p. 127)

In Hayek's view, the central role of the state should be to maintain the rule of law, with as little arbitrary intervention as possible. It was shocking enough for Britain, where his views were respectfully, though critically, received. But in the United States, where Reader's Digest published a condensed version, The Road to Serfdom was a bestseller and a political lightning rod. It rallied supporters of traditional free enterprise and enraged the intelligentsia to whom it was addressed. How dare this mustachioed Austrian suggest that the ambitions of the New Deal might have anything in common with Hitler or Stalin! (Postrel 2004).

Hayek went eventually as far as to attribute the birth of civilization to private property in his book The Fatal Conceit (1988). According to him, price signals are the only possible way to let each economic decision maker communicate tacit knowledge or dispersed knowledge to each other, in order to solve the economic calculation problem.

The business cycle

In Prices and Production (1931) and Monetary Theory and the Trade Cycle (1933) Hayek showed how monetary injections, by lowering the rate of interest below what Ludwig von Mises called its "natural rate," distort the economy's inter-temporal structure of production. Most theories of the effects of money on prices and output (then and since) consider only the effects of the total money supply on the price level and aggregate output or investment. Hayek, instead, focused on the way money enters the economy ("injection effects") and how this affects relative prices and investment in particular sectors.

In Hayek's framework, investments in some stages of production are "malinvestments" if they do not help to align the structure of production to consumers' inter temporal preferences. The reduction in interest rates caused by credit expansion directs resources toward capital-intensive processes and early stages of production (whose investment demands are more interest-rate elastic), thus "lengthening" the period of production. If interest rates had fallen because consumers had changed their preferences to favor future over present consumption, then the longer time structure of production would have been an appropriate, coordinating response.

A fall in interest rates caused by credit expansion, however, would have been a "false signal," causing changes in the structure of production that do not accord with consumers' inter temporal preferences. The boom generated by the increase in investment is artificial. Eventually, market participants come to realize that there are not enough savings to complete all the new projects; the boom becomes a bust as these malinvestments are discovered and liquidated.

Every artificial boom induced by credit expansion, then, is self-reversing. Recovery consists of liquidating the malinvestments induced by the lowering of interest rates below their natural levels, thus restoring the time structure of production so that it accords with consumers' inter temporal preferences.

Spontaneous order

In Economics and Knowledge(1937) and The Use of Knowledge in Society (1945) Hayek argued that the central economic problem facing society is not, as is commonly expressed in textbooks, the allocation of given resources among competing ends:

It is rather a problem of how to secure the best use of resources known to any of the members of society, for ends whose relative importance only those individuals know. Or, to put it briefly, it is a problem of the utilization of knowledge not given to anyone in its totality. (Hayek 1945, p. 78).

The efficient exchange and use of resources, Hayek claimed, can be maintained only through the price mechanism in free markets. He argued that the price mechanism serves to share and synchronize local and personal knowledge, allowing society's members to achieve diverse, complicated ends through a principle of spontaneous self-organization. He coined the term "catallaxy" to describe a "self-organizing system of voluntary co-operation." (Hayek 1945)

Much of the knowledge necessary for running the economic system, Hayek contended, is in the form not of

"scientific" or technical knowledge—the conscious awareness of the rules governing natural and social phenomena—but of ... knowledge, the idiosyncratic, dispersed bits of understanding of "circumstances of time and place" (Hayek 1968).

This tacit knowledge is often not consciously known even to those who possess it and can never be communicated to a central authority. The market tends to use this tacit knowledge through a type of discovery procedure (Hayek 1968), by which this information is unknowingly transmitted throughout the economy as an unintended consequence of individuals' pursuing their own ends.

Indeed, Hayek's (1948) distinction between the neoclassical notion of "competition," identified as a set of equilibrium conditions (number of market participants, characteristics of the product, and so on), and the older notion of notion of competition as a rivalrous process, has been widely influential in Austrian economics.

Hayek went eventually as far as to attribute the birth of civilization to private property in his book The Fatal Conceit (1988). According to him, price signals are the only possible way to let each economic decision maker communicate tacit knowledge or dispersed knowledge to each other, in order to solve the economic calculation problem.

On the other side, the key to a functioning economy—or society—is decentralized competition. In a market economy, prices act as a "system of telecommunications," coordinating information far beyond the scope of a single mind. They permit ever-evolving order to emerge from dispersed knowledge. In any complex operation, there is too much relevant information for a single person or small group to absorb and act on.

For Hayek, market competition generates a particular kind of order—an order that is the product "of human action but not human design" (a phrase Hayek borrowed from Adam Smith's mentor Adam Ferguson).

This "spontaneous order" is a system that comes about through the independent actions of many individuals, and produces overall benefits unintended and mostly unforeseen by those whose actions bring it about. To distinguish between this kind of order and that of a deliberate, planned system, Hayek (1968b, pp. 72-76) used the Greek terms cosmos for a spontaneous order and taxis for a consciously planned one.

Examples of a "cosmos" include the market system as a whole, money, the common law, and even language. A "taxis," by contrast, is a designed or constructed organization, like a corporation or bureau; these are the "islands of conscious power in [the] ocean of unconscious cooperation like 'lumps of butter coagulating in a pail of buttermilk'”

Most importantly, however, Hayek always stressed that his moral philosophy has to be backed by “a complex system of moral codes, rules of fairness, as well as an articulated system of punishment for the violators ... system under which bad man can do a least harm.” (Hayek 1945).

Only then, the role played by his "spontaneous order" in a society organized around a market order (in which the apparatus of state is employed solely to secure the peace necessary for a market of free individuals to function), the system works (Hayek 1949).

Theorem on transitional and developing countries

Let us start with a quote that logically follows the last paragraph of “Spontaneous Order” in this text:

I think that permanence and stability are the cardinal virtues of the legal rules that make private innovation and public progress possible. To my mind there is no doubt that a legal regime that embraced private property and freedom of contract is the only one that in practice can offer that permanence and stability .. In reaching this conclusion, I have been heavily influenced by the work of Friedrich Hayek. (Epstein, Chicago School of Law).

When we combine Hayek’s key theorems, it emerges that it takes: (a) the “learning process” of how to play the social roles of which market relations is based on and keeping within the implicit rules and (b) the moral codes of co-operative society (which punishes violators), to form a system marginalizing the opportunities and other element harmful to the society while forming the ultimate criterion of success.

Such a “learning process” - in which the moral codes are spontaneously achieved - is, however, a function of time usually measured in terms of generations (Dallago 1996, pp.82, 116-117).

The time-element of “learning process” is obviously non-existent in developing and transitional societies. Hence, we see there quick "privatizations" (usually by the old oligarchy transformed into "democratic" leadership that had the money to buy the bulk of industrial infrastructure) and “quasi-market” relations without any moral scruples, codes of conduct, and, above all, without any functioning legal system that would punish the violators.

So far, most of the methods trying to substitute the generations-long “learning process” - of how to achieve at least minimum functioning legal, moral, and co-operative notion in the society - in these new “free market” societies were based on exogenous inputs. They consisted either of the transfer of the whole constitution (or major substantive and civil laws) with short courses for upper echelons of the indigenous law profession or just amendments some of the old “communist-era” laws with or without help from the legal experts from historical democracies.

In any case, these exogenous tries only helped to jump-start the self-perpetuating and opportunism-strengthening loop between the old-oligarchy-cum-new-“democratic”-leaders and lawlessness, because the "new leadership" still “owns” the whole legal and police apparatus anyway and the two judicial measures (combined with their "we-are-above-the-law" behavior) only contributed to further moral and,in many cases, economic decay of these societies.

There, Hayek’s Theorem of generations-long learning process on the road to full-fledged democracy showed to be one of his most prophetic.

Hayek vs. Keynes

As one of Keynes' leading professional adversaries, Hayek was well situated to provide a full refutation of Keynes' General Theory. But he never did. Part of the explanation for this no doubt lies with Keynes's personal charm and legendary rhetorical skill, along with Hayek's general reluctance to engage in direct confrontation with his colleagues. Hayek also considered Keynes an ally in the fight against wartime inflation and did not want to detract from that issue (Hayek, 1994, p. 91).

Caldwell (1988) suggests another reason: it was during this time that Hayek was losing faith in equilibrium theory and moving toward a "market process" view of economic activity, making it difficult for him to engage Keynes on the same terms in which they had debated earlier. Furthermore, as Hayek later explained, Keynes was constantly changing his theoretical framework, and Hayek saw no point in working out a detailed critique of the General Theory, if Keynes might change his mind again (Hayek, 1963, p. 60; Hayek, 1966, pp. 240-41). Hayek thought a better course would be to produce a fuller elaboration of Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk's capital theory, and he began to devote his energies to this project.

The following quote puts Hayek’s “side” into a proper perspective.

Underlying all this has been a fundamental shift in ideas ... The dramatic redefinition of state and marketplace over the last two decades demonstrates anew the truth of Keynes' axiom about the overwhelming power of ideas. For concepts and notions that were decidedly outside the mainstream have now moved, with some rapidity, to center stage and are reshaping economies in every corner of the world. Even Keynes himself has been done in by his own dictum. During the bombing of London in World War II, he arranged for a transplanted Austrian economist, Friedrich von Hayek, to be temporarily housed in a college at Cambridge University. It was a generous gesture; after all, Keynes was the leading economist of his time, and Hayek, his rather obscure critic. In the postwar years, Keynes' theories of government management of the economy appeared unassailable. But a half century later, it is Keynes who has been toppled and Hayek, the fierce advocate of free markets, who is preeminent. (Yergin & Stanislaw 1998. pp. 14-15)

Contribution to social and political philosophy

Hayek's most significant contribution,

was to make clear how our present complex social structure is not the result of the intended actions of individuals but of the unintended consequences of individual interactions over a long period of time, the product of social evolution, not of deliberate planning. (Postrel 2004).

Hayek's major insight, which he referred to as his "one discovery" in the social sciences, was to define the central economic and social problem as one of organizing dispersed knowledge. Different people have different purposes. They know different things about the world. Much important information is local and transitory, known only to the man on the spot.

"Some of that knowledge is objective and quantifiable, but much is tacit and unarticulated. Often we only discover what we truly want as we actually make trade-offs between competing goods ... The economic problem of society," Hayek wrote in his 1945 article, "is thus not merely a problem of how to allocate `given' resources ... if `given' is taken to mean given to a single mind which deliberately solves the problem set by these data. ... It is rather a problem of how to secure the best use of resources known to any of the members of society, for ends whose relative importance only these individuals know ... Or, to put it briefly, it is a problem of the utilization of knowledge which is not given to anyone in totality." (Hayek 1945).

Hayek made a quite fruitful suggestion, made contemporaneously by the psychologist Donald Hebb, that whatever kind of encounter the sensory system has with the world, a corresponding event between a particular cell in the brain and some other cell carrying the information from the outside word must result in reinforcement of the connection between those cells. These day, this is known as a Hebbian synapse, but von Hayek quite independently came upon the idea. I think the essence of his analysis still remains with us. (Edelman 1987, p. 25).

Influence, recognition, and legacy

Hayek's intellectual foundation was based on the ideas of David Hume, Adam Smith, and other Scottish thinkers of the 1700s. He had a wide-reaching influence on contemporary economics, politics, philosophy, sociology, psychology, and anthropology. For example, Hayek's discussion in The Road to Serfdom (1944) about truth and falsehood in totalitarian systems influenced some later opponents of postmodernism. (Wolin 2004).

Having heavily influenced Margaret Thatcher's economic approach, and some of Ronald Reagan's economic advisors, in the 1990s Hayek became one of the most-respected economists in Europe. There is a general consensus that his analyses of socialist as well as non-socialist societies were proven prescient by the breakup of communist Eastern Europe.

He shared the 1974 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics with ideological rival Gunnar Myrdal and in 1991 he received the Presidential Medal of Freedom, one of the two highest civilian awards in the United States, “for a lifetime of looking beyond the horizon.”[1]

Notes

  1. Remarks on Presenting the Presidential Medal of Freedom Awards November 18, 1991. Retrieved February 9, 2007.

Publications

  • Hayek, F. A. Prices and Production., Routledge & Sons London, 1931.. Second revised edition: Routledge & Kegan Paul, London 1935
  • Hayek, F. A., Monetary Theory and the Trade Cycl, Jonathan Cape, London 1933
  • Hayek, F. A. ,. "The Trend of Economic Thinking." Economica 13, 1933, 121-37. Reprinted in Hayek, 1991, pp. 17-34
  • Hayek, F. A.. "Economics and Knowledge." Economica N.S. 4, 1937, 33-54. Reprinted in Hayek, 1948, pp. 33-56
  • Hayek, F. A.. "Price Expectations, Monetary Disturbances, and Malinvestments." In Hayek, Profits, Interest, and Investment, Routledge and Kegan Paul, London 1939, pp. 135-56.
  • Hayek, F. A. ,The Pure Theory of Capital, University of Chicago Press, Chicago 1941
  • Hayek, F. A., The Road to Serfdom, University of Chicago Press, Chicago, 1944
  • Hayek, F. A. 1945. "The Use of Knowledge in Society." American Economic Review 35 (September): 519-30. Reprinted in Hayek, 1948, pp. 77-91.
  • Hayek, F. A., "The Meaning of Competition"; in: Hayek, 1948, pp. 92-106.
  • Hayek, F.A., “Individualism, True and False, 1945,pp.10-11; in: Individualism and Economic Order , Routledge & Kegan Paul , London 1949
  • Hayek, F. A.,The Sensory Order, University of Chicago Press, Chicago 1952
  • Hayek, F. A.. The Constitution of Liberty, University of Chicago Press, Chicago 1960
  • Hayek, F. A. "The Economics of the 1930s as Seen from London,” 1963; in: Hayek, 1995, pp. 49-73.
  • Hayek, F. A.. "Personal Recollections of Keynes and the 'Keynesian Revolution.'," 1966 ; in Hayek, 1995, pp. 240-46. :
  • Hayek, F. A. 1968a. "Competition as a Discovery Procedure." In Hayek, 1978, pp. 179-90.
  • Hayek, F. A. 1968b. "The Confusion of Language in Political Thought." In Hayek, 1978, pp. 71-97.
  • Hayek, F. A. Law, Legislation, and Liberty. Three volumes ;University of Chicago Press, Chicago 1973-79.
  • Hayek, F. A., New Studies in Philosophy, Politics and Economics, University of Chicago Press, Chicago 1978
  • Hayek, F. A. The Fatal Conceit: The Errors of Socialis,. Ed.by W. W. Bartley III., vol. 1 of The Collected Works of F. A. Hayek, Routledge, London:and University of Chicago Press, Chicago 1989.
  • Hayek, F. A. The Trend of Economic Thinking: Essays on Political Economists and Economic History, Ed. W. W. Bartley III and Stephen KresgeUniversity of Chicago Press, Chicago, and Routledge, London 1991
  • Hayek, F. A.. The Fortunes of Liberalism. Edited by Peter G. Klein. Vol. 4 of The Collected Works of F. A. *Hayek, University of Chicago Press, Chicago and Routledge London 1992
  • Hayek, F. A., Contra Keynes and Cambridge: Essays, Correspondence. Ed. Bruce Caldwell. Vol. 9 of The Collected Works of F. A. Hayek: University of Chicago Press,. Chicago and Routledge, London 1995

References
ISBN links support NWE through referral fees

  • Birner, Jack, 2001, "The mind-body problem and social evolution," CEEL Working Paper 1-02. “Politics, economics and the history of ideas (1994)
  • Caldwell, Bruce J.. "Hayek's Transformation." History of Political Economy 20, 1988 (Winter): 513-41.
  • Caldwell, Bruce J. 1995. "Introduction." In Hayek, 1995, pp. 1-48,
  • Caldwell, Bruce J. "Hayek and Socialism." Journal of Economic Literature 35, 1997,no. 4 (December): 1856-90
  • Caldwell, BruceHayek's Challenge : An Intellectual Biography of F.A. Hayek , 2005
  • Dallago , B. & L. Mintone ( eds.) , Economic Institutions , Markets and Competition , Edward Elgar , 1996
  • Edelman, G., Neural Darwinism, 1987, p. 25
  • Epstein, R. , Simple Rules for a Complex World, Harvard U. Press, Cambridge
  • Fuster, J., Memory in the Cerebral Cortex: An Empirical Approach to Neural Networks in the Human and Nonhuman Primate, MIT Press, Cambridge, MS 1995, p. 87
  • Hicks, Sir John, Critical Essays in Monetary Theory, Clarendon Press, Oxford, 1967
  • Muller, Jerry Z., The Mind and the Market: Capitalism in Western Thought, Anchor Books, 2002
  • Postrel, Virginia. 2004. “Friedrich the Great” The Boston Globe January 11, 2004. Retrieved February 9, 2007.
  • Wolin, R. , The Seduction of Unreason: The Intellectual Romance with Fascism from Nietzsche to Postmodernism, Princeton University Press, Princeton2004
  • Yergin , D. & J. Stanislaw, The Commanding Heights: The Battle Between Government and the Marketplace that Is Remaking the Modern World, Simon & Schuster , New York 1998, pp. 14-15

External links


Credits

New World Encyclopedia writers and editors rewrote and completed the Wikipedia article in accordance with New World Encyclopedia standards. This article abides by terms of the Creative Commons CC-by-sa 3.0 License (CC-by-sa), which may be used and disseminated with proper attribution. Credit is due under the terms of this license that can reference both the New World Encyclopedia contributors and the selfless volunteer contributors of the Wikimedia Foundation. To cite this article click here for a list of acceptable citing formats.The history of earlier contributions by wikipedians is accessible to researchers here:

The history of this article since it was imported to New World Encyclopedia:

Note: Some restrictions may apply to use of individual images which are separately licensed.