Difference between revisions of "Inheritance tax" - New World Encyclopedia

From New World Encyclopedia
 
(31 intermediate revisions by 3 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
 +
{{Images OK}}{{Approved}}{{copyedited}}
 
[[Category:Politics and social sciences]]
 
[[Category:Politics and social sciences]]
 
[[Category:Economics]]
 
[[Category:Economics]]
{{Public finance}}
+
{{Taxation}}
'''Inheritance tax''', '''estate tax''', and '''death duty''' are the names given to various [[tax]]es which arise on the death of an individual. Technically, "inheritance tax" and "estate tax" are different, in that inheritance tax may be payable by the [[heir]] while estate tax is levied prior to the receiving of the [[Inheritance (Sociology)|inheritance]]. In many cases, however, the distinction is of little import and the terms are used interchangeably; in the [[United Kingdom]], no distinction is made and inheritance tax is equivalent to estate tax.  
+
'''Inheritance tax,''' '''estate tax,''' and '''death duty''' are the names given to various [[tax]]es which arise on the death of an individual. Technically, "inheritance tax" and "estate tax" are different, in that inheritance tax may be payable by the [[heir]] while estate tax is levied prior to the receiving of the [[Inheritance (Sociology)|inheritance]]. In many cases, however, the distinction is of little importance and the terms are used interchangeably; in the [[United Kingdom]], no distinction is made and inheritance tax is equivalent to estate tax. In the U. S. an estate tax is paid out of the deceased’s estate before it is distributed. The same total tax is paid, therefore, whether there is one heir or more and the same tax is paid whether the heirs are rich or poor.
  
In the U.S. an estate tax is paid out of the deceased’s estate before it is distributed. The same total tax is paid, therefore, whether there is one heir or dozens and the same tax is paid whether the heirs are rich or poor.
+
Such death duties are controversial both in terms of [[economics]] and [[ethics]]. Although they have a long history, the imposition of contemporary inheritance and estate taxes has been relatively recent and debate has increased as the numbers of people affected has risen in the twenty-first century. The logic of disallowing those who earned their wealth to choose how to distribute it upon their death (except by [[philanthropy]]) is controversial and the economic impact on [[savings]] potentially problematic. Perhaps even more serious, once applied only to the affluent, generating substantial revenue for the government who justified this as it would be spent on programs that would benefit [[society]] as a whole rather than allowing a few to continue to amass excessive [[wealth]], the estates of an increasingly large proportion of middle-class people in many countries are now at a level that incurs such taxes.  
 +
{{toc}}
 +
The existence of such a tax underscores the problems inherent in all forms of taxation, issues that cannot be solved by legislation because they reflect weaknesses in human nature. It is only when human nature changes from selfishness to caring for others and society as a whole that these problems can be resolved, both by those designing the system and by those paying and collecting the taxes.
  
 
==Overview==  
 
==Overview==  
 
 
===Definitions===
 
===Definitions===
 +
In different [[jurisdiction]]s, the [[tax]] code may make reference to '''inheritance tax,''' '''estate tax,''' or even '''death duty.''' Generally, except in the [[United States]], the terms estate tax and inheritance tax are used interchangeably.
  
In different [[jurisdiction]]s, the [[tax]] code may make reference to '''inheritance tax''', '''estate tax''', or even '''death duty'''. Generally, except in the [[United States]], the terms estate tax and inheritance tax are used interchangeably.
+
In the United States, there is a difference between estate taxes and inheritance taxes. Estate taxes are levied on representatives of the deceased person, while inheritance taxes are levied on the beneficiaries of an estate. Inheritance taxes are generally levied by state authorities and estate taxes are imposed by the federal government.  
  
In the United States, there is a difference between estate taxes and inheritance taxes. Estate taxes are levied on representatives of the deceased person, while inheritance taxes are levied on the beneficiaries of an estate.
+
The '''estate tax''' is a tax on net worth, the value of all [[property]] owned minus debt and any estate expenses. Essentially the tax is an “everything tax.” It is a tax on cash and [[bank]] accounts, [[stock]]s, [[bond]]s, [[real estate]], [[business]]es, equipment, and machinery, [[automobile]]s, and other property, [[life insurance]] policies, [[art]]work, even personal belongings.  
  
An "inheritance tax" is paid by the [[heir]] and may vary according to the heir’s relation to the deceased, the heir’s income and [[wealth]], and the amount [[inheritance (sociology)|inherited]]. If an inheritance tax is, in any of the senses above, [[progressive tax|progressive]] then the total tax paid varies according to the number of heirs and their wealth.
+
'''Inheritance tax''' is paid by the [[heir]] and may vary according to the heir’s relation to the deceased, the heir’s income and [[wealth]], and the amount [[inheritance (sociology)|inherited]]. If an inheritance tax is [[progressive tax|progressive]] then the total tax paid varies according to the number of heirs and their wealth.
  
The “estate tax” is a tax on net worth, the value of all property owned minus debt and any estate expenses. Essentially the tax is an “everything tax.” It is a tax on cash and [[bank]] accounts, [[stock]]s, [[bond]]s, [[real estate]], [[business]]es, equipment, and machinery, [[automobile]]s and other [[property]], [[life insurance]] policies, artwork, even personal belongings.  
+
In both the U.S. and Great Britain, egalitarians tend to prefer an inheritance tax since this gives the deceased an incentive to spread wealth across many heirs ([[John Stuart Mill]] proposed an inheritance tax, for example) while pragmatists tend to support the estate tax because it is easier to administer and tends to raise more revenue than the inheritance tax (precisely because it cannot be avoided by increasing the number of heirs).  
  
In both the U. S. and Great Britain, egalitarians tend to prefer an inheritance tax since this gives the deceased an incentive to spread wealth across many heirs ([[John Stuart Mill]] proposed an inheritance tax, for example) while pragmatists tend to support the estate tax because it is easier to administer and tends to raise more revenue than the inheritance tax (precisely because it cannot be avoided by increasing the number of heirs).  
+
'''[[Gift tax]]''' is a related type of tax, applying to gratuitous transfers of money and property between living persons.
  
====Calculation of Inheritance Tax in the U.S.====
+
===History===
 +
Inheritance taxes have a long history dating back to the [[Roman Empire]], which levied taxes on inherited property to provide [[pension]]s for retired soldiers. Contemporary inheritance taxes are based on the [[feudal]] arrangement of the [[Middle Ages]] whereby the sovereign was the ultimate owner of all land and property, and permission was required to transfer property on the death of the immediate owner. In many [[Europe]]an countries property could be transferred by payment of a "relief" when no direct descendant laid claim. Contemporary estate taxes can be traced back to such payments.
  
*Inheritance Tax Basis:
+
Although initially levied in the seventeenth century, estate taxes in the [[United Kingdom]] were established in their current form at the end of the nineteenth century. In the [[United States]], various estate taxes were imposed for short periods, on both the state and federal levels. [[Pennsylvania]] was the first state to impose inheritance tax in 1826, and many states continue to tax inheritance. In 1916, a federal estate tax was imposed to help finance [[World War I]], and it has remained in force since that time.  
The first step used to determine any inheritance tax that might be due is to calculate the fair market value of the entire estate.  This would include cash, bank accounts, stocks and bonds, real state, insurance and similar items of value.  The total fair market value of all these items is termed the Gross Estate.
+
   
 
+
===Calculation===
*Adjustments to Gross Estate:
+
For the purpose of illustrating how inheritance/estate tax is generally calculated, the United States is used as an example.  
The next step would be to calculate any adjustments to the gross estate. Typical adjustments include the remaining balance on a mortgage or the fees associated with settling the estate. This last item might include items such as estate administration fees or payments made to an attorney.  Finally, there is also a Marital Deduction that can be taken for property that is left to a surviving spouse.
 
 
 
*Net Value of Property:
 
Once all the deductions have been taken from the gross estate, the remaining balance is considered the net value of the property - or the inheritance tax basis. 
 
 
 
To calculate whether nor not any inheritance tax is due; the net value of the property must be subtracted from the inheritance tax credits appearing in the tables below.  If the net estate is larger than the tax exclusion, then the federal income taxes due can be found on the standard tax brackets or tax rate tables published by the IRS.
 
 
 
*Taxing of Life Insurance Proceeds:
 
Life insurance proceeds paid to you are used in the calculation of the gross estate.  The value of any insurance received is subject to the unified credits and inheritance tax exemptions explained later.  This last statement is true if you elect to receive the proceeds in the form of a single lump sum.
 
 
 
If you elect to receive life insurance proceeds in installments, then you need to separate the value of the insurance inherited from the total of all payments to determine your federal tax liability. 
 
 
 
For example, you may be able to elect to receive a lump sum of $100,000 or $10,000 per month for 12 months. The difference between the lump sum payment and the money received is due to interest you are earning on the policy by taking installments.
 
 
 
In this example, you are receiving a total of 12 x $10,000 or $120,000, which is $20,000 higher than the lump sum of $100,000.  This means that you would need to pay income tax on the $20,000 received in the form of interest income.
 
 
 
*Unified Credits, Gift Tax and Estate Tax:
 
The Unified Credit is used to eliminate or reduce your tax liability.  The credit applies to both gifts you may have received and estates that have been inherited.  The credit is termed a lifetime credit because as it is consumed by each gift or estate inherited the credit is reduced.  The lifetime credit applies to all inheritance or gifts received since 1977.
 
 
 
The lifetime gift tax exclusion you can take in 2006 is $1,000,000. Another way of looking at the same information is to state that you have a $345,000 tax credit that you can apply to any income taxes owed on gifts.
 
 
 
===Rising problems with Inheritance tax in OECD===  
 
 
 
"Inheritance tax" used to make the news only when it forced once super-rich dynasties to flog their heirlooms after the head of the family died. But suddenly, death is getting expensive for a much larger number of Europeans, and that's starting to attract the attention of politicians and headline writers across the Continent.
 
 
 
Animated discussions about whether to limit, amend or suppress inheritance taxes have been going on in earnest, in both, Britain and France since 2006.
 
 
 
In Italy, meanwhile, there's controversy and skepticism about plans by the new government ─ an error occurred while processing this directive ─  of Romano Prodi to reinstate the inheritance tax abolished by former Prime Minister Silvio Berlusconi in one of his first acts on taking office in 2001.
 
 
 
The debate is erupting now because death duties of up to 40%, once paid only by the affluent, are starting to affect a growing number of middle-class Europeans—and will likely hit millions more in the decade to come.  
 
  
"……'''''Inheritance tax used to be a problem for the rich. Now it's a problem for you and me'''''….." says Anne Young, a tax expert at the Edinburgh financial-services firm Scottish Widows, who calculates that about 1 in 3 of Britain's 24 million households now have estates that would fall within the taxman's reach. Young herself admits she has an inheritance-tax "problem."
+
The first step is to calculate the fair market value of the entire estate. This includes cash, [[bank]] accounts, [[stock]]s and [[bond]]s, real state, [[insurance]], and similar items of value. Included are [[life insurance]] and [[annuity]] proceeds payable to the estate or the [[heir]]s as well as the value of certain property transferred within a specified time period prior to the death. This last item involves a connection between [[gift tax]]es (and their exclusions) and inheritance tax.  
  
Blame the explosion of house prices. Unlike their parents, European baby boomers tend to own their homes. As prices have soared over the past few years in almost every country except Germany, these homeowners have enjoyed big increases in the value of their total assets. But in many cases, the rise has pushed their net worth over the national minimum thresholds for inheritance tax, which haven't been adjusted in step with the housing boom. The result: almost anyone owning a detached house in London or southeast England is already well over the U.K. tax-free limit on estates of £540,000.  
+
The total fair market value of all these items is termed the "gross estate." The next step involves the calculation of any adjustments to the gross estate. Typical adjustments include the remaining balance on a [[mortgage]], [[funeral]] expenses, the fees associated with settling the estate (which might include items such as estate administration fees or payments made to an [[attorney]]), and a "marital deduction" that can be taken for property that is left to a surviving spouse.
  
France is even tougher. There, inheritance tax is levied in theory from the first euro passed on, but a series of tax-free thresholds apply to family members, including a €50,000 one for children of the deceased. The value of even a modest two-bedroom apartment in central Paris is enough to push families into a 30% tax bracket (the top rate for them is 40%, for estates valued at over €1.7 million).  
+
Once all the deductions have been taken from the gross estate, the remaining balance is considered the net value of the property—or the inheritance tax basis. The final deduction prior to calculation of the tax is the lifetime tax exclusion (or unified credit), which was $1 million in 2002, rising in steps to $3.5 million in 2009, and which includes taxable [[gift]]s. The remainder of the estate is taxable, at a rate that ranges from around 40 to 60 percent.
  
For nonfamily members and unmarried partners, the situation is even more complicated, with inheritance tax rising as high as 60%. And unlike many other countries, where the tax is levied when assets are handed down a generation, husbands and wives in France are subject to death duties on what they inherit from their spouses.  
+
===Rising problems with inheritance tax===
 +
Inheritance tax used to impact only the very wealthy, but in the twenty-first century, the proportion of people affected has become much larger. This has led to animated discussions about whether to limit, amend, or suppress inheritance taxes in many countries, particularly in [[Europe]]. The debate erupted when death duties, once paid only by the affluent, began to affect middle-class Europeans in significant and increasing numbers.  
  
In the U.S., the subsequent administrations to Ronald Reagan's one have left the following legacy concerning the Inheritance Tax:
+
"Inheritance tax used to be a problem for the rich. Now it's a problem for you and me," said Anne Young, a tax expert at an Edinburgh financial-services firm. Young has estimated that as many as one third of British households have estates that could be subject to tax. She includes herself in this group (Gumbel 2006).
  
*The rate was scheduled to fall to 50 percent by 1993, however, ERTA (i.e. Economic Recovery Act of 1981)  had scheduled the rate to fall to 50 percent by 1985, but this reduction has been twice delayed and pushed off to the farther future; the general public may never see the 50 percent rate promised in ERTA.  
+
This increase in value of estates, with concomitant tax liability, has been blamed on the rise in house prices. Unlike their parents, European [[baby boomer]]s tend to own their homes. As prices have risen these homeowners have enjoyed increases in the value of their assets. However, in many cases, this has pushed their net worth over the national minimum thresholds for inheritance tax, which have not been adjusted to keep up with changes in house prices. The result is that almost anyone owning a detached house in [[London]] or southeast [[England]] has an estate valued over the U.K. tax-free limit (Gumbel 2006).
  
*Marginal rates begin at 37 percent after the first $600,000.
+
==Economic issues==
 +
Inheritance taxes have been controversial since their inception. A few excerpts from the writings of prominent [[economics|economists]] should precede the discussion:
  
*There is a peculiar non-linearity in the schedules so that the tax rises to 60 percent between $10,000,000 and $21,040,000 but then falls to 55 percent again. It’s unclear why this non-linearity exists.
+
<blockquote>This does not imply that once-earned wealth perpetuates itself forever. On the contrary, even if a fortune were completely immune from risk it would tend to quickly dissipate so long as there is more than one heir in each generation. In a free market wealth is continually changing hands… Increasing and even maintaining a fortune requires entrepreneurial skill. …Consider how much easier it is to waste a million dollars than it is to make a million dollars. Nevertheless, wealth will typically last more than one generation so it is reasonable to argue that at least two generations of heirs are significantly harmed by the estate tax (von Mises 1981, 338–40).</blockquote>
  
==Economics of minimal Inheritance Taxes==
+
<blockquote>In modern times the funds raised by the estate and gift tax have accounted for only a small proportion of government revenue…. In 1990 death and gift taxes raised just over $15 billion in revenue, approximately $11 billion of which was because of the Federal estate and gift tax the remainder because of state death and gift taxes (Tabarrok 1997).</blockquote>
  
Before we enter this domain, a few excerpts  should precede it:
+
Those in favor of taxes on a person's estate argue that the amount of the tax is small and occurs only once, that it reduces [[savings]] to a lesser degree than [[income tax]]es, and is useful for redistributing [[wealth]]. Opponents argue that such taxes have a negative effect on incentives, discouraging people to build up their estate since a large part will not be given to their [[heir]]s. Those against this form of taxation claim that this leads to reductions in savings and hurts [[business]] incentives. In such cases it can be argued that the limit to the usefulness of such taxes exists when the accumulation of wealth is discouraged to the extent that the [[economy]] of the nation is harmed.
  
“…..''This does not imply that once-earned wealth perpetuates itself forever. On the contrary, even if a fortune were completely immune from risk it would tend to quickly dissipate so long as there is more than one heir in each generation. In a free market wealth is continually changing hands…… .….Increasing and even maintaining a fortune requires entrepreneurial skill''……” ( von Mises 1981, pp. 338–40 ).  
+
===Inter-generation transfers===
 +
Bequest theory is an inter-generational transfer theory of saving. Hence, a tax on the transfer of property between the generations can affect savings by changing the behavior of the bequestor or the heir. The effect on the bequestor is composed of two parts: The price effect and the wealth effect.  
  
“…….''Consider how much easier it is to waste a million dollars than it is to make a million dollars. Nevertheless, wealth will typically last more than one generation so it is reasonable to argue that at least two generations of heirs are significantly harmed by the estate tax''……"( ibid.).
+
====Price effect====
 +
The tax raises the price of bequests and therefore reduces the desired bequest. The effect on savings, however, is ambiguous. The price effect can be summarized in terms of elasticities. If the demand to give bequests is inelastic the price effect works to increase savings. Little data exist on this elasticity but a [[demand curve]] must be elastic above some price, otherwise a consumer could be made to spend all of his income on the single taxed good (Wagner 1977, 19).  
  
“…''In modern times the funds raised by the estate and gift tax have accounted for only a small proportion of government revenue…In 1990 death and gift taxes raised just over $15 billion in revenue, approximately $11 billion of which  was because of the Federal estate and gift tax the remainder because of state death and gift taxes; as seen in Statistical Abstract of the United States, 1990''…” ( Tabarrok, 1997).
+
For example, in order to bequeath an estate of $1 million to his daughter an individual must save $1 million if there is no tax, but if there is a tax of 50 percent and he still wishes to bequeath $1 million he must increase his savings to $2 million. In most circumstances the bequestor may reduce the amount of bequest, but so long as the reduction in final bequest is less than 50 percent the price effect works to increase saving. At rates around 50 percent the demand for bequests is probably elastic, but if the rates were raised by any significant degree the amount of savings would be reduced.
  
===Inter-generation transfers and “working” capital accumulation===
+
====Wealth effect====
In spite of the best efforts of social engineers, the estate tax has not had a revolutionary effect on aggregate  income inequality, although some families have been devastated by the tax. In fact, both, [[Adam Smith]] and [[David Ricardo]] ( Smith, 1904 ; Ricardo, 1917)   argued that the inheritance tax reduced savings, and, in causal relation,  future capital investments.
+
Reinforcing the reduced savings because of the price effect is the wealth effect. For a given size of bequest, an increase in the estate tax is equivalent to a reduction in wealth. The desire to give bequests decreases (increases) as wealth decreases (increases). In other words, bequests are a “normal” good.  
  
However,since the 1950s,the above classics notwithstanding, the dominant opinion among economists has been that the bequest motive has little to do with saving and capital accumulation. So, even if true, the slight sapping of savings by estate taxation was not to be worried about.  
+
An inheritance is a large, one-time, increase in wealth. Income smoothing requires that the bulk of this wealth be saved. A decrease in the heir’s inheritance is therefore ''ipso facto'', a large decrease in savings. Indeed, if the bequestor and heir have similar wealth and value scales, the heir will want to save the principal portion of the estate so that it can be passed on to his own heirs. This is what accounts for the fact that family fortunes are typically the accumulated savings of more than one generation.  
  
As a matter of fact, however,  the modern bequest theory is an inter-generational transfer theory of saving.  Hence, a tax on the transfer of property between the generations can affect savings by changing the behavior of the bequestor or the heir. The effect on the bequestor is composed of two parts:
+
Bequest-saving tends to be long-term and continuous and therefore allows for what [[F. W. Taussig]] called "sustained accumulation and permanent investment" (Taussig 1920, 249). This is especially true when savings are passed along in the form of family businesses.
  
*the price effect and  
+
===Inheritance as foundational to capitalism===
*the wealth effect.  
+
Traditionally, many economists believed that the most important reason people saved was to give bequests. [[Alfred Marshall]] (1949, 227), however, held that "family affection is the main motive for saving." Similarly, [[Joseph Schumpeter]] (1942, 160) called the "family motive the 'mainspring' of savings," and [[F. W. Taussig]] (1920, 249) argued that for long-term savings "the main motives are domestic affection and family ambition."
  
'''The tax raises the price of bequests and therefore reduces the desired be'''quest. The effect on savings, however, is ambiguous.
+
Elsewhere Taussig (1920, 509) called inheritance "the great engine for the maintenance of capital" and, in his highly regarded principles text, [[Frank A. Fetter]] (1913, 371) argued that "much of the existing wealth probably never would have been created if men did not have [the] right of gift." In fact, the entire capitalist order for Schumpeter is founded on the "family motive:"
  
Imagine, for instance, that a man wishes to bequeath an estate of $1 million to his daughter. If there is no tax he must save $1 million, but if there is a tax of 50 percent and he still wishes to bequeath $1 million he must increase his savings to $2 million.
+
<blockquote>When the capitalist-entrepreneur-bourgeois is sundered from longterm family ties he becomes, to borrow a phrase, a wage slave or bureaucrat-cog easily crushed by the state and its philosophical apparatus (Schumpeter 1942, 160).</blockquote>
  
In most circumstances the bequestor will want to reduce the amount of bequest, but so long as the
+
Those who are able to bequeath a material [[inheritance (sociology)|inheritance]] are also often able to bequeath a sound moral and educational inheritance. Along with pecuniary and physical capital the founding generation bequeaths human capital. In a [[capitalism|capitalist]] society, therefore, the institution of inheritance is more than a moral institution, it is part of the process whereby wealth is transferred to those who can best use it to serve the wishes of consumers
reduction in final bequest is less than 50 percent the price effect works to increase saving. The price effect can be summarized in terms of elasticities. If the demand to give bequests is inelastic the price effect works to increase savings.
 
  
Little data exist on this elasticity but a demand curve must be elastic above some price, otherwise a consumer could be made to spend all of his income on the single taxed good (Wagner 1977, 19). At today’s rates of 55 percent the demand for bequests is probably elastic and there is little doubt that if the rates were raised by any significant degree the amount of savings would be reduced.
+
===Problems in government "investing" of the inheritance tax===
 +
One reason most neo-classical economists ignore the effect of the estate tax on the heir’s saving is the argument that the government can also “save” the estate tax by investing it in capital projects. Generally, however, there are several flaws with this argument:
  
Reinforcing the reduced savings because of the price effect is the wealth effect. For a '''given size of bequest, an increase in the estate tax is equivalent to a reduction in wealth'''. The desire to give bequests decreases (increases) as wealth decreases (increases). In other words, bequests are a “normal” good.  
+
First, the wealthy tend to have low rates of time preference, which allows family fortunes to be invested in long-term projects, as seen in Taussig’s "sustained accumulation and permanent investment" (Lawrence 1991).  
  
The effect of estate taxation on the heir’s savings decision is important although rarely discussed
+
Second, and more fundamentally, there is a crucial difference between government investment and private sector investment. "Only the private sector investment can be defined as welfare-enhancing" (Rothbard 1956). Private sector savings are necessarily allocated to maximize consumer and producer well-being. Rothbard (1970) has made a strong case that so called government investment is better understood as consumption by government officials rather than savings.  
even though it formed the focus of Ricardo’s comments ( Ricardo, 1917 ).  
 
  
An inheritance is a large, one-time, increase in wealth. Income smoothing requires that the bulk of this wealth be saved. A decrease in the heir’s inheritance is therefore ''ipso facto'', a large decrease in savings.  
+
[[Adam Smith]]’s distinction between unproductive and productive labor was never more apt than when he wrote:
 +
<blockquote>All taxes upon the transference of property … are all more or less unthrifty taxes that increase the  revenue of the sovereign, which seldom maintains any but unproductive laborers; at the expense of the capital of the people, which maintains none but productive (Smith 1904).</blockquote>
  
Indeed, if the bequestor and heir have similar wealth and value scales, the heir will want to save the principal portion of the estate so that it can be passed on to his own heirs. This is what accounts for the fact that family fortunes are typically the accumulated savings of more than one generation.  
+
To evaluate the effect of higher estate (or inheritance) taxes, it is therefore necessary to examine the "life cycle theory."
  
'''Bequest-saving tends to be long-term and continuous and therefore allows for what [[F.W. Taussig]] called''' “…''sustained accumulation and permanent investment''…..” ( Taussig, 1920, p. 249) .This is especially true when savings are passed along in the form of family businesses.
+
===Cycle theory of saving===
 +
The theory of saving was the central component of post World War II [[Keynesian economics|Keynesian macroeconomics]] but the bequest theory was completely abandoned during this period. In its place was put the life cycle theory of saving by the main protagonists: [[Franco Modigliani]] and [[Richard Brumberg]] (1954).  
  
====Questions of morality and efficiency of inheritance====
+
The life cycle theory places the main motivation for saving on the desire to provide for retirement. The theory implies that savings should follow a “hump” pattern. Young adults begin the saving process by borrowing; as their career stabilizes they pay off old debts and begin to save; then, when retirement begins, they draw upon their savings until they die. In the simple model, everyone wishes to consume up to the moment of death and then die penniless. In more complicated models a bequest motive is tacked on as an afterthought.
  
Those who are able to bequeath a material inheritance are also often able to bequeath a sound moral and educational inheritance. Along with pecuniary and physical capital the founding generation bequeaths human capital.  
+
Yet, far before the life cycle theory was born, [[Alfred Marshall]] recognized an important fact which casts doubt on the theory:
 +
<blockquote>Men seldom spend, after they have retired from work, more than the income that comes in from their savings, preferring to leave their stored up wealth intact for their families (Marshall 1949, 228).</blockquote>
  
In a capitalist society, therefore, the institution of '''inheritance''' is more than a moral institution, it is '''part of the process whereby wealth is transferred to those who can best use it to serve the wishes of consumers'''.
+
In other words, the elderly do not dissave as the life cycle theory predicts. Marshall’s observation has been verified by a number of studies. Far from dying penniless, the elderly often die richer than at any other point in their life. In addition, [[econometrics|econometric]] work by Kotlikoff and Summers (1981) indicates that "the stock of wealth is far too large to be accounted for by life cycle reasons."
  
Consider the following three proposals and try to assess  which will cause the most efficient distribution of wealth according to the wishes of consumers:
+
Hence, the theoretical and empirical shortcomings of the life cycle theory indicate that the bequest motive is an important determinant of savings. This means that far from being negligible increases in the estate tax and gift tax could significantly reduce total savings.
  
# Inheritance according to the will of the owner,  
+
==Ethical issues==
# Inheritance to a randomly picked individual, or
+
In addition to various economic impacts of estate and inheritance taxes, there are also [[ethics|ethical]] considerations. Basically, this issue involves justifying the imposition of large taxes on the estate of the wealthy, people who earned or inherited their wealth and wish to transfer it to their descendants or other beneficiaries of their choice. This issue strikes at the heart of the rights of [[ownership]].
# The state takes the inheritance as tax revenue (see [[Rothbard]], 1970 in the below note ?
 
  
In the long run only the market can reveal who possesses the entrepreneurial spark. But when wealth must be passed from one generation to another the institution of inheritance seems to be both moral and efficient (see [[von Mises]]' comment at the beginning of this chapter).
+
===Equality of opportunity=== 
 +
Economists and other writers have attempted to rationalize the imposition of estate and inheritance taxes by appealing to ''the principle of equality of opportunity''. Economist and [[Nobel Prize]] winner [[James Buchanan]], for example, argued that:
 +
<blockquote>A guarantee of “some” equality of opportunity is inherent in the political philosophy of the free society (Buchanan 1975, 303).</blockquote>
  
====Problems in government "investing" of the inheritance tax ====
+
[[Harold Groves]] (1939, 248) noted that equality of opportunity is often accepted as desirable “by the most ‘rugged’ of individualists.
One reason most neo-classical economists ignore the effect of the estate tax on the heir’s saving
 
is the argument that the government can also “save” the estate tax by investing it in capital
 
projects.  
 
  
From that does not immediately follows that if the bequestor reduces his savings in the face of the estate tax, savings must decline regardless of what the government does with the tax revenue.  
+
However, there are problems in the justification of inheritance taxes in terms of equality of opportunity. To increase opportunities for individuals to excel is a worthy goal but to restrict the opportunities of some in order to create “equality” among all is impossible, not to say "monstrous." In fact, among the opportunities it is desirable to increase is the opportunity to inherit wealth.  
  
At best, this objection, even if accepted, blunts but does not overturn the negative effect on savings derived from the behavior of bequestors.
+
Inheritance taxes on the rich do not significantly improve the lot of the poor. Even if the taxes raised from the rich were redistributed to the poor, instead of spent on consumption by the state, the wealth of the poor would increase only trivially. Thus, in practical terms, equality of opportunity is a poor justification for the negative impact of such taxes on the wealthy.
  
But, generally, there are several flaws with this argument:
+
===Principle of desert===
 +
Closely linked with the idea of equality of opportunity is the principle of "desert." Many who reject as morally repugnant confiscatory income taxes accept the inheritance tax because the individual does not “earn” his inheritance and is therefore undeserving. [[Harlan Read]] stated the thesis boldly in his ''Abolition of Inheritance:''
 +
<blockquote>All estates are unearned by the heirs and should therefore, be taken by taxation (Read 1918, 279).</blockquote>
 +
However, this argument in [[logic]]ally weak since the (correct) idea that a man deserves what he earns does not necessitate the conclusion that a man does not deserve what he does not earn.
  
*First, '''the wealthy tend to have low rates of time preference, which allows family fortunes to be invested in long-term projects''', as seen in the above Taussig’s “..''sustained accumulation and permanent investment''..” (Lawrence 1991).
+
The difficulties of defining “deserve” and “earn” and their relationship notwithstanding, if one accepts the assumption that in some sense the [[heir]] does not deserve his [[inheritance (sociology)|inheritance]] because he has not earned it, the question now becomes: How does it follow from this that the state deserves the inheritance? It is the owner of the estate who earned it and not the government. Furthermore, if the owner of the estate earned it and, thus, deserves it, he must also deserve the right to allocate the estate as he wishes. Thus, even accepting that a man does not deserve what he does not earn, this is no justification for inheritance taxes.
 
 
Even assuming that governments were to “invest” the proceeds of the tax rather than spend it on redistribution and pork barrel projects, '''governments are dominated by politicians whose time horizons are measured in years to the next election rather than in decades and generations'''.
 
 
 
*Second, and more fundamentally, there is a crucial difference between government investment and private sector investment.
 
 
 
'''Only the private sector investment can be defined as welfare-enhancing''' (Rothbard 1956 ). Private sector savings are necessarily allocated to maximize consumer and producer  well-being.
 
 
 
'''Government savings are allocated according to arbitrary political fiat'''. Rothbard (1970) has made a strong case that so called government investment is '''better understood as consumption''' by government officials '''rather than savings'''.
 
 
 
Adam Smith’s distinction between unproductive and productive labor was never more apt than when he wrote:
 
 
 
“…..''All taxes upon the transference of property . . . are all more or less unthrifty taxes that increase the  revenue of the sovereign, which seldom maintains any but unproductive laborers; at the expense of the capital of the people, which maintains none but productive''….” (Smith 1904).
 
 
 
 
 
To evaluate the effect of higher estate (or inheritance) taxes, it is therefore necessary to examine the "life cycle theory" (see the next paragraph).
 
 
 
Traditionally, many economists believed that the most important reason people saved was to give bequests. [[Alfred Marshall]] (1949 227), however, held that:
 
 
 
“….''family affection is the main motive for saving…''..”
 
 
 
Similarly, [[Schumpeter]] (1942, 160) called the “….''family motive” the “mainspring” of savings…''..,” and [[F.W. Taussig]] (1920, 249) argued that for long-term savings “…..''the main motives are domestic affection and family ambition''…….”
 
 
 
 
 
Elsewhere Taussig (1920, 509) called inheritance “……''the great engine for the maintenance of capital…''…” and, in his highly regarded principles text, [[Frank A. Fetter]] (1913, 371) argued that:
 
 
 
“…….''Much of the existing wealth probably never would have been created if men did not have [the] right of gift''…...”
 
 
 
'''In fact, the entire capitalist order for [[Schumpeter]]  is founded on the family motive''':
 
 
 
''“…….When the capitalist-entrepreneur-bourgeois is sundered from longterm family ties he becomes, to borrow a phrase, a wage slave or bureaucrat-cog easily crushed by the state and its philosophical apparatus''……..” (Schumpeter 1942, 160 and passim).
 
 
 
====Cycle Theory of Saving====
 
The theory of saving was the central component of post World War II Keynesian macroeconomics
 
but the bequest theory was completely abandoned during this period. In its place was put the life cycle theory of saving by the main protagonists: [[Modigliani]] and Brumberg (1954).
 
 
 
The '''life cycle theory places the main motivation for saving on the desire to provide for retirement'''. The theory implies that savings should follow a “hump” pattern.
 
 
 
Young adults begin the saving process by borrowing; as their career stabilizes they pay off old debts and begin to save, then, when retirement begins, they draw down their savings until they die.
 
 
 
In the simple model, everyone wishes to consume up to the moment of death and then die penniless. In more complicated models a bequest motive is tacked on as an afterthought.
 
 
 
Yet, far before the life cycle theory was born, [[Alfred Marshall]] recognized an important fact which casts doubt on the theory. He noted that:
 
 
 
“…. ''men seldom spend, after they have retired from work, more than the income that comes in from their savings, preferring to leave their stored up wealth intact for their families''……..” ( Marshall, 1949, p.228).
 
 
 
In other words, the elderly do not dissave as the life cycle theory predicts. Marshall’s observation has been verified by a number of studies in recent years. Far from dying penniless, '''the elderly often die richer than at any other point in their life'''.
 
 
 
A related point is the '''low demand among the elderly for annuities and reverse mortgages'''. Some economists have claimed that "uncertainty about time of death" explains why the elderly do not dissave.
 
 
 
But if this were the motivation for maintaining income in old age we would expect the elderly to invest in annuities and reverse mortgages.
 
 
 
An annuity is like life insurance in reverse. A large and certain payment is made today in return for an income stream which lasts until death. Similarly, in a reverse mortgage the buyer promises to will his house to a firm in return for an income stream which is paid until death.
 
 
 
If they wanted to do so, the elderly could use these devices to consume their wealth without fear of being destitute in the event that they live longer than expected. '''The fact that these markets are relatively small suggests that the main reason the elderly do not dissave is to make bequests'''.
 
 
 
Instead of buying annuities, which the life cycle theory predicts, many elderly persons are trying to get rid of annuities the government has forced them to buy.
 
 
 
One of those annuities is Social Security that taxes income in early periods and then returns that income in later periods in annuitized form. Social Security changes not only the amount of saving but the type of saving which occurs—it favors annuity saving rather than saving in the form of bequestable wealth.
 
 
 
Imagine, for instance, that a man has paid $100,000 into Social Security. After he retires, this money begins to return to him in periodic payments. If he lives long enough he may even see the entire $100,000 again, but if he dies after consuming only half of his $100,000 payment he cannot bequest the remaining $50,000.
 
 
 
In addition to these theoretical arguments, recent econometric work by Kotlikoff and Summers (1981) indicates that '''the stock of wealth is far too large to be accounted for by life cycle reasons'''. Although hotly debated and challenged, the bequest wealth is now recognized to be much more important than previously thought.
 
 
 
Hence, the theoretical and empirical shortcomings of the life cycle theory indicate that the '''bequest motive is an important determinant of savings'''. This means that far from being negligible the estate tax and gift tax could significantly reduce total savings. If the current exemption were to be lowered the increase in the estate tax base would be considerable and savings could be even more adversely affected.
 
 
 
===Ethical Justifications of Inheritance Tax===
 
 
 
====Equality of Opportunity====     
 
Economists and other writers often ethically rationalize the estate and inheritance taxes by appealing to '''''the principle of equality of opportunity'''''. Economist  and Nobel Prize winner [[James Buchanan]],  for example, argue that:
 
 
 
”…… ''a guarantee of  “some” equality of opportunity is inherent in the political philosophy of the free society''…….” ( Buchanan, 1975, p. 303 ).
 
 
 
And Groves (1939, p. 248) correctly notes that "...''equality of opportunity is often accepted as desirable “by the most ‘rugged’ of individualists.''...”
 
 
 
Closely linked with the idea of equality of opportunity is the principle of desert. Many who reject as morally repugnant confiscatory income taxes accept the inheritance tax because the individual does not “earn” his inheritance and is therefore undeserving. [[Harlan Read]] (1918, p. 279) stated the thesis boldly in his ''Abolition of Inheritance'':
 
 
 
“…….''All estates are unearned by the heirs and should therefore, be taken by taxation''……..”
 
 
 
From the correct idea that a man deserves what he earns he draws the incorrect conclusion that a man does not deserve what he does not earn.
 
 
 
The principle of equality of opportunity and the principle of desert are both inimical to the free society. There are, however, at least two uncertainties in these moral principles:
 
 
 
*1)  Stated in a certain fashion it appears inherently just and when contrasted with equality of condition or outcome it appears manifestly superior. Equality of opportunity is often presented in the context of lack of opportunity.
 
 
 
'''Typical argument''': The intelligent child of the inner city who is unable to excel because he lacks a good education is contrasted with the luckier child of the suburb. Why should forces for which the child is not responsible and does not control be such a large factor in his life? Why are otherwise identical individuals placed in such differing circumstances?
 
 
 
In this context equality of opportunity seems compelling. An argument can be made, however, that what is compelling about these anecdotes is the lack of opportunity of the inner-city child and not the notion of equality of opportunity.
 
 
 
'''Counter-argument''': Let us establish equality of opportunity by ruining the schools for all. ( NOTE: Mind you only the spiteful and envious could prefer such a situation to happen when the children were unequal.)
 
 
 
'''Yet, such must be the argument behind inheritance taxes because taxing the rich does not improve the lot of the poor'''.
 
 
 
Even if the taxes raised from the rich were redistributed to the poor, instead of wasted or spent on consumption by the state, the wealth of the poor would not increase but trivially.
 
 
 
The issue of opportunity must be separated from that of equality of opportunity. '''To increase
 
opportunities for individuals to excel is a worthy goal but to restrict the opportunities of some in order to create “equality” among all is impossible, not to say "monstrous"'''. Among the opportunities it is desirable to increase is the opportunity to inherit wealth.
 
 
 
*2)  The second reason equality of opportunity is highly regarded is that it is often favorably contrasted with equality of condition or outcome.
 
 
 
'''Equality of opportunity, it is said, allows men to rise as far and as fast as their talents''' allow so long as each generation begins the race on an equal footing.
 
 
 
'''Equality of outcome, by contrast, is inefficient, coercive, and totalitarian'''. In actuality, equality of opportunity is nothing but equality of outcome applied at the beginning of life rather than throughout life.
 
 
 
Both forms of equality are coercive and totalitarian. '''Taken seriously, equality of opportunity requires that all inheritance—monetary, genetic, and experiential—be abolished'''.
 
 
 
Of the three forms, monetary inheritance is the most obvious but probably the least important creator of inequality.
 
 
 
Genetic inheritance is the least obvious but is likely of the greatest importance with experiential
 
inheritance (the informal education and training given by one’s parents) falling close to that of genetic inheritance. (NOTE: It is difficult to separate these influences because they are positively correlated.)
 
 
As a mere beginning, to create equality of opportunity would require a massive program of eugenics and the raising of children communally. Although eugenics is still a subject of taboo, some public schools, which make the communal raising of children a partial reality, are often justified on the grounds of equality of  opportunity.
 
 
 
====Principle of Desert====
 
Consider first the issue of inheritance taxes. Let us pass over the difficulties of defining “deserve” and “earn” and assume that in some sense the heir does not deserve his inheritance because he has not earned it.
 
 
 
'''How does it follow from this that the state deserves the inheritance?''' It is the owner of the estate who earned it and not the government. Furthermore, if the owner of the estate earned it and thus deserves it he must also deserve the right to allocate the estate as he wishes. Who else could deserve this  right?  Thus, even accepting that a man does not deserve what he does not earn, this is no justification for inheritance taxes.
 
 
 
The argument that desert justifies ownership is entirely misplaced. It is not a man’s duty to “justify” his claims to the state or to other men.
 
 
 
'''It is the state which must justify its takings.''' The notion of desert as justification implicitly regards ownership as a gift granted by the state and given only so long as a man can “justify” such ownership to the state’s inquisitors.
 
 
 
However, it is the inquisitors who must be questioned. '''The state justifies its existence only to the extent that it protects the rights of individuals.''' This is the meaning of the “'''Declaration of Independence'''” when it declares that:
 
 
 
”…… ''every man has, certain unalienable Rights, that among these are Life, Liberty, and the Pursuit of Happiness….That, to secure these Rights, Governments are instituted among Men, deriving their just Powers from the Consent of the Governed, that whenever any Form of Government becomes destructive of these Ends, it is the Right of the People to alter or to abolish it''……”
 
  
 
==Conclusion==
 
==Conclusion==
So long as men are mortal, wealth should be—for several reasons; among them: long-term capital projects, efficiency of capital investment and all the above reasons coming from: [[Smith]], [[Ricardo]], [[Marshall]], [[Taussig]] and others—transferred between the generations and so long as parents care for their children the dominant means of doing so will be through family inheritance.
+
In many ways, both practical—for long-term capital projects and efficiency of capital investment—and as noted by prominent economists including [[Adam Smith]], [[David Ricardo]], [[Alfred Marshall]], [[F. W. Taussig]], and others, the transfer of [[wealth]] between generations is beneficial. As as long as [[parent]]s care for their children the dominant means of doing so will be through [[family]] [[Inheritance (Sociology)|inheritance]].  
 
 
The transference of wealth through the family benefits bequestor and heir, strengthens family ties, and increases long-term savings. When the state intervenes in this process it increase its coffers at the expense of the smooth operation of family, society, and economy.
 
  
Even if a given amount of taxes must be raised  it is probably preferable to tax consumption rather
+
The transference of wealth through the family benefits bequestor and [[heir]], strengthens family ties, and increases long-term savings, which are the basis of economic growth. When the state intervenes significantly in this process it does so at the expense of the smooth operation of family, [[society]], and [[economy]]. The estate tax has the greatest impact on these grounds, as [[Murray Rothbard]] has noted:
than to tax capital accumulation because private savings are the basis of economic growth. The estate tax is among the worst taxes on these grounds, as Rothbard (1970, p. 113) notes:
+
<blockquote>The inheritance tax is perhaps the most devastating example of a tax on pure capital (Rothbard 1970, 113).</blockquote>
  
“……'''''The inheritance tax is perhaps the most devastating example of a tax on pure capital'''''…...
+
However, until those who accumulate significant wealth in their lifetime show themselves able to use it to benefit society as a whole, in ways that reduce the need for government efforts, the imposition of these types of death duties continue to be seen as necessary and justifiable, provided the taxes are sufficiently [[progressive tax|progressive]] to ensure that only those with the greatest wealth are significantly impacted.
  
 
==References==
 
==References==
*Buchanan, J., Cost and Choice, Markham, Chicago, 1969
+
*Buchanan, James. [1969] 1999. ''Cost and Choice''. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. ISBN 0865972249.
*Fetter, Frank A., The Principles of Economics, Century New York,  1913
+
*Fetter, Frank A. 1913. ''The Principles of Economics''. New York: Century.
*Groves, Harold. M., Financing Government, Henry Holt, New York: 1939
+
*Groves, Harold. M. 1939. ''Financing Government''. New York: Henry Holt.
*Kotlikoff, L., and L. Summers, “The Role of Intergenerational Transfers in Aggregate Capital Accumulation,“ Journal of Political Economy , vol. 89, 1981, pp. 706-732  
+
*Gumbel, Peter. 2006. [http://www.time.com/time/magazine/article/0,9171,1376184,00.html Death's Other Sting.] ''Time.'' August 27, 2006. Retrieved August 23, 2008.
*Lawrence, M. and Carl Davidson,. "Tax incidence in a simple general equilibrium model with collusion and entry," Journal of Public Economics, vol. 45(2), Elsevier, 1991, pp. 161-190
+
*Harwood, Sterling. 2001. "Is Inheritance Immoral?" In Louis P. Pojman, ''Political Philosophy''. McGraw Hill. ISBN 978-0071131445.
*Read, H.E., The Abolition of Inheritance, MacMillan, New York, 1918
+
*Kotlikoff, L., and L. Summers. “The Role of Intergenerational Transfers in Aggregate Capital Accumulation." ''Journal of Political Economy'' 89 (1981): 706-732.
*Ricardo, D.Principles of Political Economy and Taxation,  Dent, London, 1817, chap. 8 (for his comments on transfer taxes and savings)
+
*Lawrence, M., and Carl Davidson. 1991. "Tax Incidence in a Simple General Equilibrium Model with Collusion and Entry" ''Journal of Public Economics'' 45(2): 161-190.
*Rothbard, M., “ Towards the Reconstruction of Utility and Welfare Economics”; in: On Friedom and Free Enterprises (ed. Mary Sonnholtz) , Van Nostrand, Princeton, 1956
+
*Modigliani, Franco, and Richard Brumberg. [1954] 2003. Utility analysis and the consumption function: An interpretation of cross-section data. In Kenneth K. Kurihara (ed.) ''Post-Keynesian Economics.'' Routledge. ISBN 978-0415313766.
*Rothbard, M., Nan, Economy and State, vols, 1 and 2. , Nash Publ. , Los Angeles, 1970
+
*Read, Harlan. E. 1918. ''The Abolition of Inheritance''. New York: MacMillan.
*Schumpeter, Joseph A.. Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy, Harper and Row, New York, 1942
+
*Ricardo, David. [1817] 2006. ''Principles of Political Economy and Taxation''. Cosimo Classics. ISBN 978-1596059276.
*Smith AdamThe Wealth of Nations, Methuen and Co., Ltd., ed. Edwin Cannan, 1904. Fifth edition, Book 5, chap. 2, pt. i, appendix to articles 1 and 2
+
*Rothbard, Murray. 1956. "Towards the Reconstruction of Utility and Welfare Economics” in ''On Freedom and Free Enterprises.'' Mary Sennholtz (ed.). Princeton, NJ: Van Nostrand.
*Tabarrok, A.” Death Taxes: Theory, History, and Ethics” in: Essays in Political Economy, Ludwig von Mises Institute (Auburn University, Auburn, AL ) USA, 1997;  translated into Spanish as Impuestos a la herencia: teoría, historia y ética (Eseade, 2002)
+
*Rothbard, Murray. [1970] 1993. ''Man, Economy and State''. Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute. ISBN 978-0945466321.  
*Taussig, F.W., Principles of Economics, Vol, 2, Macmillan, New York, 1920
+
*Schumpeter, Joseph A. [1942] 2005. ''Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy''. New York: Taylor & Francis. ISBN 0415107628.
*von Mises, L., Socialism, Indianopolis 1934; Liberty Classics 1981
+
*Smith Adam. [1904] 2003. ''The Wealth of Nations''. Bantam Classics. ISBN 978-0553585971.
*Wagner, R., Inheritance and State, American Enterprise Institute, Washington, 1977
+
*Tabarrok, A. 1997. ”Death Taxes: Theory, History, and Ethics.” In ''Essays in Political Economy.'' Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.
*Sterling Harwood, "Is Inheritance Immoral?" in Louis P. Pojman, Political Philosophy (McGraw Hill, 2002).
+
*Taussig, Frank W. [1920] 2007. ''Principles of Economics, Vol. 2''. Cosimo Classics. ISBN 978-1602063433.
 +
*von Mises, Ludwig. [1934] 1981. ''Socialism''. Indianapolis: Liberty Classics. ISBN 978-0913966631.
 +
*Wagner, R. 1977. ''Inheritance and the State: Tax Principles for a Free and Prosperous Commonwealth''. Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research. ISBN 0844732524.
  
 
==External links==
 
==External links==
All Links Retrieved August 23, 2008.
+
All links retrieved March 3, 2018.
* [http://www.irs.gov/pub/irs-pdf/p950.pdf IRS publication 950], Introduction to Estate and Gift Taxes
+
* [http://www.irs.gov/Businesses/Small-Businesses-&-Self-Employed/Estate-and-Gift-Taxes Estate and Gift Taxes] IRS website.  
* Reich, Robert B. 2006 [http://www.tompaine.com/articles/2006/06/06/estate_tax_pyramid_scheme.php Estate Tax Pyramid Scheme] TomPaine.com
 
* [http://www.deathtax.com/ The "Death" Tax is killing family business]
 
* [http://www.taxpolicycenter.org/TaxModel/tmdb/TMTemplate.cfm?DocID=734&topic2ID=40&topic3ID=41&DocTypeID= Gross Estate and Net Estate Tax on Farms and Businesses in 2004] Tax Policy Center
 
*[http://www.myheritage.org/Issues/MythBusters/DeathTax.asp Myth: Death tax repeal only benefits the wealthy] The Heritage Foundation
 
 
* Hunter, Rosie, and Chuck Collins [http://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/2003/0103hunter.html Death tax deception] ''Dollars & Sense''
 
* Hunter, Rosie, and Chuck Collins [http://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/2003/0103hunter.html Death tax deception] ''Dollars & Sense''
 
*Runciman, David. 2005. [http://www.lrb.co.uk/v27/n11/runc01_.html Tax Breaks for Rich Murderers] ''London Review of Books''
 
*Runciman, David. 2005. [http://www.lrb.co.uk/v27/n11/runc01_.html Tax Breaks for Rich Murderers] ''London Review of Books''
*[http://www.hmrc.gov.uk/cto/iht.htm HMRC Inheritance Tax (IHT)] HM Revenue & Customs
+
*[https://www.gov.uk/inheritance-tax HMRC Inheritance Tax (IHT)] HM Revenue & Customs
  
 
{{credits|Inheritance_tax|146427614|Inheritance_tax_(United_Kingdom)|146153690|Estate_tax_in_the_United_States|148069300}}
 
{{credits|Inheritance_tax|146427614|Inheritance_tax_(United_Kingdom)|146153690|Estate_tax_in_the_United_States|148069300}}

Latest revision as of 17:54, 3 March 2018

Taxation
Assorted United States coins.jpg

Types of Tax
Ad valorem tax ·  Consumption tax
Corporate tax ·  Excise
Gift tax ·  Income tax
Inheritance tax ·  Land value tax
Luxury tax ·  Poll tax
Property tax ·  Sales tax
Tariff ·  Value added tax

Tax incidence
Flat tax ·  Progressive tax
Regressive tax ·  Tax haven
Tax rate

Inheritance tax, estate tax, and death duty are the names given to various taxes which arise on the death of an individual. Technically, "inheritance tax" and "estate tax" are different, in that inheritance tax may be payable by the heir while estate tax is levied prior to the receiving of the inheritance. In many cases, however, the distinction is of little importance and the terms are used interchangeably; in the United Kingdom, no distinction is made and inheritance tax is equivalent to estate tax. In the U. S. an estate tax is paid out of the deceased’s estate before it is distributed. The same total tax is paid, therefore, whether there is one heir or more and the same tax is paid whether the heirs are rich or poor.

Such death duties are controversial both in terms of economics and ethics. Although they have a long history, the imposition of contemporary inheritance and estate taxes has been relatively recent and debate has increased as the numbers of people affected has risen in the twenty-first century. The logic of disallowing those who earned their wealth to choose how to distribute it upon their death (except by philanthropy) is controversial and the economic impact on savings potentially problematic. Perhaps even more serious, once applied only to the affluent, generating substantial revenue for the government who justified this as it would be spent on programs that would benefit society as a whole rather than allowing a few to continue to amass excessive wealth, the estates of an increasingly large proportion of middle-class people in many countries are now at a level that incurs such taxes.

The existence of such a tax underscores the problems inherent in all forms of taxation, issues that cannot be solved by legislation because they reflect weaknesses in human nature. It is only when human nature changes from selfishness to caring for others and society as a whole that these problems can be resolved, both by those designing the system and by those paying and collecting the taxes.

Overview

Definitions

In different jurisdictions, the tax code may make reference to inheritance tax, estate tax, or even death duty. Generally, except in the United States, the terms estate tax and inheritance tax are used interchangeably.

In the United States, there is a difference between estate taxes and inheritance taxes. Estate taxes are levied on representatives of the deceased person, while inheritance taxes are levied on the beneficiaries of an estate. Inheritance taxes are generally levied by state authorities and estate taxes are imposed by the federal government.

The estate tax is a tax on net worth, the value of all property owned minus debt and any estate expenses. Essentially the tax is an “everything tax.” It is a tax on cash and bank accounts, stocks, bonds, real estate, businesses, equipment, and machinery, automobiles, and other property, life insurance policies, artwork, even personal belongings.

Inheritance tax is paid by the heir and may vary according to the heir’s relation to the deceased, the heir’s income and wealth, and the amount inherited. If an inheritance tax is progressive then the total tax paid varies according to the number of heirs and their wealth.

In both the U.S. and Great Britain, egalitarians tend to prefer an inheritance tax since this gives the deceased an incentive to spread wealth across many heirs (John Stuart Mill proposed an inheritance tax, for example) while pragmatists tend to support the estate tax because it is easier to administer and tends to raise more revenue than the inheritance tax (precisely because it cannot be avoided by increasing the number of heirs).

Gift tax is a related type of tax, applying to gratuitous transfers of money and property between living persons.

History

Inheritance taxes have a long history dating back to the Roman Empire, which levied taxes on inherited property to provide pensions for retired soldiers. Contemporary inheritance taxes are based on the feudal arrangement of the Middle Ages whereby the sovereign was the ultimate owner of all land and property, and permission was required to transfer property on the death of the immediate owner. In many European countries property could be transferred by payment of a "relief" when no direct descendant laid claim. Contemporary estate taxes can be traced back to such payments.

Although initially levied in the seventeenth century, estate taxes in the United Kingdom were established in their current form at the end of the nineteenth century. In the United States, various estate taxes were imposed for short periods, on both the state and federal levels. Pennsylvania was the first state to impose inheritance tax in 1826, and many states continue to tax inheritance. In 1916, a federal estate tax was imposed to help finance World War I, and it has remained in force since that time.

Calculation

For the purpose of illustrating how inheritance/estate tax is generally calculated, the United States is used as an example.

The first step is to calculate the fair market value of the entire estate. This includes cash, bank accounts, stocks and bonds, real state, insurance, and similar items of value. Included are life insurance and annuity proceeds payable to the estate or the heirs as well as the value of certain property transferred within a specified time period prior to the death. This last item involves a connection between gift taxes (and their exclusions) and inheritance tax.

The total fair market value of all these items is termed the "gross estate." The next step involves the calculation of any adjustments to the gross estate. Typical adjustments include the remaining balance on a mortgage, funeral expenses, the fees associated with settling the estate (which might include items such as estate administration fees or payments made to an attorney), and a "marital deduction" that can be taken for property that is left to a surviving spouse.

Once all the deductions have been taken from the gross estate, the remaining balance is considered the net value of the property—or the inheritance tax basis. The final deduction prior to calculation of the tax is the lifetime tax exclusion (or unified credit), which was $1 million in 2002, rising in steps to $3.5 million in 2009, and which includes taxable gifts. The remainder of the estate is taxable, at a rate that ranges from around 40 to 60 percent.

Rising problems with inheritance tax

Inheritance tax used to impact only the very wealthy, but in the twenty-first century, the proportion of people affected has become much larger. This has led to animated discussions about whether to limit, amend, or suppress inheritance taxes in many countries, particularly in Europe. The debate erupted when death duties, once paid only by the affluent, began to affect middle-class Europeans in significant and increasing numbers.

"Inheritance tax used to be a problem for the rich. Now it's a problem for you and me," said Anne Young, a tax expert at an Edinburgh financial-services firm. Young has estimated that as many as one third of British households have estates that could be subject to tax. She includes herself in this group (Gumbel 2006).

This increase in value of estates, with concomitant tax liability, has been blamed on the rise in house prices. Unlike their parents, European baby boomers tend to own their homes. As prices have risen these homeowners have enjoyed increases in the value of their assets. However, in many cases, this has pushed their net worth over the national minimum thresholds for inheritance tax, which have not been adjusted to keep up with changes in house prices. The result is that almost anyone owning a detached house in London or southeast England has an estate valued over the U.K. tax-free limit (Gumbel 2006).

Economic issues

Inheritance taxes have been controversial since their inception. A few excerpts from the writings of prominent economists should precede the discussion:

This does not imply that once-earned wealth perpetuates itself forever. On the contrary, even if a fortune were completely immune from risk it would tend to quickly dissipate so long as there is more than one heir in each generation. In a free market wealth is continually changing hands… Increasing and even maintaining a fortune requires entrepreneurial skill. …Consider how much easier it is to waste a million dollars than it is to make a million dollars. Nevertheless, wealth will typically last more than one generation so it is reasonable to argue that at least two generations of heirs are significantly harmed by the estate tax (von Mises 1981, 338–40).

In modern times the funds raised by the estate and gift tax have accounted for only a small proportion of government revenue…. In 1990 death and gift taxes raised just over $15 billion in revenue, approximately $11 billion of which was because of the Federal estate and gift tax the remainder because of state death and gift taxes (Tabarrok 1997).

Those in favor of taxes on a person's estate argue that the amount of the tax is small and occurs only once, that it reduces savings to a lesser degree than income taxes, and is useful for redistributing wealth. Opponents argue that such taxes have a negative effect on incentives, discouraging people to build up their estate since a large part will not be given to their heirs. Those against this form of taxation claim that this leads to reductions in savings and hurts business incentives. In such cases it can be argued that the limit to the usefulness of such taxes exists when the accumulation of wealth is discouraged to the extent that the economy of the nation is harmed.

Inter-generation transfers

Bequest theory is an inter-generational transfer theory of saving. Hence, a tax on the transfer of property between the generations can affect savings by changing the behavior of the bequestor or the heir. The effect on the bequestor is composed of two parts: The price effect and the wealth effect.

Price effect

The tax raises the price of bequests and therefore reduces the desired bequest. The effect on savings, however, is ambiguous. The price effect can be summarized in terms of elasticities. If the demand to give bequests is inelastic the price effect works to increase savings. Little data exist on this elasticity but a demand curve must be elastic above some price, otherwise a consumer could be made to spend all of his income on the single taxed good (Wagner 1977, 19).

For example, in order to bequeath an estate of $1 million to his daughter an individual must save $1 million if there is no tax, but if there is a tax of 50 percent and he still wishes to bequeath $1 million he must increase his savings to $2 million. In most circumstances the bequestor may reduce the amount of bequest, but so long as the reduction in final bequest is less than 50 percent the price effect works to increase saving. At rates around 50 percent the demand for bequests is probably elastic, but if the rates were raised by any significant degree the amount of savings would be reduced.

Wealth effect

Reinforcing the reduced savings because of the price effect is the wealth effect. For a given size of bequest, an increase in the estate tax is equivalent to a reduction in wealth. The desire to give bequests decreases (increases) as wealth decreases (increases). In other words, bequests are a “normal” good.

An inheritance is a large, one-time, increase in wealth. Income smoothing requires that the bulk of this wealth be saved. A decrease in the heir’s inheritance is therefore ipso facto, a large decrease in savings. Indeed, if the bequestor and heir have similar wealth and value scales, the heir will want to save the principal portion of the estate so that it can be passed on to his own heirs. This is what accounts for the fact that family fortunes are typically the accumulated savings of more than one generation.

Bequest-saving tends to be long-term and continuous and therefore allows for what F. W. Taussig called "sustained accumulation and permanent investment" (Taussig 1920, 249). This is especially true when savings are passed along in the form of family businesses.

Inheritance as foundational to capitalism

Traditionally, many economists believed that the most important reason people saved was to give bequests. Alfred Marshall (1949, 227), however, held that "family affection is the main motive for saving." Similarly, Joseph Schumpeter (1942, 160) called the "family motive the 'mainspring' of savings," and F. W. Taussig (1920, 249) argued that for long-term savings "the main motives are domestic affection and family ambition."

Elsewhere Taussig (1920, 509) called inheritance "the great engine for the maintenance of capital" and, in his highly regarded principles text, Frank A. Fetter (1913, 371) argued that "much of the existing wealth probably never would have been created if men did not have [the] right of gift." In fact, the entire capitalist order for Schumpeter is founded on the "family motive:"

When the capitalist-entrepreneur-bourgeois is sundered from longterm family ties he becomes, to borrow a phrase, a wage slave or bureaucrat-cog easily crushed by the state and its philosophical apparatus (Schumpeter 1942, 160).

Those who are able to bequeath a material inheritance are also often able to bequeath a sound moral and educational inheritance. Along with pecuniary and physical capital the founding generation bequeaths human capital. In a capitalist society, therefore, the institution of inheritance is more than a moral institution, it is part of the process whereby wealth is transferred to those who can best use it to serve the wishes of consumers

Problems in government "investing" of the inheritance tax

One reason most neo-classical economists ignore the effect of the estate tax on the heir’s saving is the argument that the government can also “save” the estate tax by investing it in capital projects. Generally, however, there are several flaws with this argument:

First, the wealthy tend to have low rates of time preference, which allows family fortunes to be invested in long-term projects, as seen in Taussig’s "sustained accumulation and permanent investment" (Lawrence 1991).

Second, and more fundamentally, there is a crucial difference between government investment and private sector investment. "Only the private sector investment can be defined as welfare-enhancing" (Rothbard 1956). Private sector savings are necessarily allocated to maximize consumer and producer well-being. Rothbard (1970) has made a strong case that so called government investment is better understood as consumption by government officials rather than savings.

Adam Smith’s distinction between unproductive and productive labor was never more apt than when he wrote:

All taxes upon the transference of property … are all more or less unthrifty taxes that increase the revenue of the sovereign, which seldom maintains any but unproductive laborers; at the expense of the capital of the people, which maintains none but productive (Smith 1904).

To evaluate the effect of higher estate (or inheritance) taxes, it is therefore necessary to examine the "life cycle theory."

Cycle theory of saving

The theory of saving was the central component of post World War II Keynesian macroeconomics but the bequest theory was completely abandoned during this period. In its place was put the life cycle theory of saving by the main protagonists: Franco Modigliani and Richard Brumberg (1954).

The life cycle theory places the main motivation for saving on the desire to provide for retirement. The theory implies that savings should follow a “hump” pattern. Young adults begin the saving process by borrowing; as their career stabilizes they pay off old debts and begin to save; then, when retirement begins, they draw upon their savings until they die. In the simple model, everyone wishes to consume up to the moment of death and then die penniless. In more complicated models a bequest motive is tacked on as an afterthought.

Yet, far before the life cycle theory was born, Alfred Marshall recognized an important fact which casts doubt on the theory:

Men seldom spend, after they have retired from work, more than the income that comes in from their savings, preferring to leave their stored up wealth intact for their families (Marshall 1949, 228).

In other words, the elderly do not dissave as the life cycle theory predicts. Marshall’s observation has been verified by a number of studies. Far from dying penniless, the elderly often die richer than at any other point in their life. In addition, econometric work by Kotlikoff and Summers (1981) indicates that "the stock of wealth is far too large to be accounted for by life cycle reasons."

Hence, the theoretical and empirical shortcomings of the life cycle theory indicate that the bequest motive is an important determinant of savings. This means that far from being negligible increases in the estate tax and gift tax could significantly reduce total savings.

Ethical issues

In addition to various economic impacts of estate and inheritance taxes, there are also ethical considerations. Basically, this issue involves justifying the imposition of large taxes on the estate of the wealthy, people who earned or inherited their wealth and wish to transfer it to their descendants or other beneficiaries of their choice. This issue strikes at the heart of the rights of ownership.

Equality of opportunity

Economists and other writers have attempted to rationalize the imposition of estate and inheritance taxes by appealing to the principle of equality of opportunity. Economist and Nobel Prize winner James Buchanan, for example, argued that:

A guarantee of “some” equality of opportunity is inherent in the political philosophy of the free society (Buchanan 1975, 303).

Harold Groves (1939, 248) noted that equality of opportunity is often accepted as desirable “by the most ‘rugged’ of individualists.”

However, there are problems in the justification of inheritance taxes in terms of equality of opportunity. To increase opportunities for individuals to excel is a worthy goal but to restrict the opportunities of some in order to create “equality” among all is impossible, not to say "monstrous." In fact, among the opportunities it is desirable to increase is the opportunity to inherit wealth.

Inheritance taxes on the rich do not significantly improve the lot of the poor. Even if the taxes raised from the rich were redistributed to the poor, instead of spent on consumption by the state, the wealth of the poor would increase only trivially. Thus, in practical terms, equality of opportunity is a poor justification for the negative impact of such taxes on the wealthy.

Principle of desert

Closely linked with the idea of equality of opportunity is the principle of "desert." Many who reject as morally repugnant confiscatory income taxes accept the inheritance tax because the individual does not “earn” his inheritance and is therefore undeserving. Harlan Read stated the thesis boldly in his Abolition of Inheritance:

All estates are unearned by the heirs and should therefore, be taken by taxation (Read 1918, 279).

However, this argument in logically weak since the (correct) idea that a man deserves what he earns does not necessitate the conclusion that a man does not deserve what he does not earn.

The difficulties of defining “deserve” and “earn” and their relationship notwithstanding, if one accepts the assumption that in some sense the heir does not deserve his inheritance because he has not earned it, the question now becomes: How does it follow from this that the state deserves the inheritance? It is the owner of the estate who earned it and not the government. Furthermore, if the owner of the estate earned it and, thus, deserves it, he must also deserve the right to allocate the estate as he wishes. Thus, even accepting that a man does not deserve what he does not earn, this is no justification for inheritance taxes.

Conclusion

In many ways, both practical—for long-term capital projects and efficiency of capital investment—and as noted by prominent economists including Adam Smith, David Ricardo, Alfred Marshall, F. W. Taussig, and others, the transfer of wealth between generations is beneficial. As as long as parents care for their children the dominant means of doing so will be through family inheritance.

The transference of wealth through the family benefits bequestor and heir, strengthens family ties, and increases long-term savings, which are the basis of economic growth. When the state intervenes significantly in this process it does so at the expense of the smooth operation of family, society, and economy. The estate tax has the greatest impact on these grounds, as Murray Rothbard has noted:

The inheritance tax is perhaps the most devastating example of a tax on pure capital (Rothbard 1970, 113).

However, until those who accumulate significant wealth in their lifetime show themselves able to use it to benefit society as a whole, in ways that reduce the need for government efforts, the imposition of these types of death duties continue to be seen as necessary and justifiable, provided the taxes are sufficiently progressive to ensure that only those with the greatest wealth are significantly impacted.

References
ISBN links support NWE through referral fees

  • Buchanan, James. [1969] 1999. Cost and Choice. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. ISBN 0865972249.
  • Fetter, Frank A. 1913. The Principles of Economics. New York: Century.
  • Groves, Harold. M. 1939. Financing Government. New York: Henry Holt.
  • Gumbel, Peter. 2006. Death's Other Sting. Time. August 27, 2006. Retrieved August 23, 2008.
  • Harwood, Sterling. 2001. "Is Inheritance Immoral?" In Louis P. Pojman, Political Philosophy. McGraw Hill. ISBN 978-0071131445.
  • Kotlikoff, L., and L. Summers. “The Role of Intergenerational Transfers in Aggregate Capital Accumulation." Journal of Political Economy 89 (1981): 706-732.
  • Lawrence, M., and Carl Davidson. 1991. "Tax Incidence in a Simple General Equilibrium Model with Collusion and Entry" Journal of Public Economics 45(2): 161-190.
  • Modigliani, Franco, and Richard Brumberg. [1954] 2003. Utility analysis and the consumption function: An interpretation of cross-section data. In Kenneth K. Kurihara (ed.) Post-Keynesian Economics. Routledge. ISBN 978-0415313766.
  • Read, Harlan. E. 1918. The Abolition of Inheritance. New York: MacMillan.
  • Ricardo, David. [1817] 2006. Principles of Political Economy and Taxation. Cosimo Classics. ISBN 978-1596059276.
  • Rothbard, Murray. 1956. "Towards the Reconstruction of Utility and Welfare Economics” in On Freedom and Free Enterprises. Mary Sennholtz (ed.). Princeton, NJ: Van Nostrand.
  • Rothbard, Murray. [1970] 1993. Man, Economy and State. Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute. ISBN 978-0945466321.
  • Schumpeter, Joseph A. [1942] 2005. Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. New York: Taylor & Francis. ISBN 0415107628.
  • Smith Adam. [1904] 2003. The Wealth of Nations. Bantam Classics. ISBN 978-0553585971.
  • Tabarrok, A. 1997. ”Death Taxes: Theory, History, and Ethics.” In Essays in Political Economy. Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.
  • Taussig, Frank W. [1920] 2007. Principles of Economics, Vol. 2. Cosimo Classics. ISBN 978-1602063433.
  • von Mises, Ludwig. [1934] 1981. Socialism. Indianapolis: Liberty Classics. ISBN 978-0913966631.
  • Wagner, R. 1977. Inheritance and the State: Tax Principles for a Free and Prosperous Commonwealth. Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research. ISBN 0844732524.

External links

All links retrieved March 3, 2018.

Credits

New World Encyclopedia writers and editors rewrote and completed the Wikipedia article in accordance with New World Encyclopedia standards. This article abides by terms of the Creative Commons CC-by-sa 3.0 License (CC-by-sa), which may be used and disseminated with proper attribution. Credit is due under the terms of this license that can reference both the New World Encyclopedia contributors and the selfless volunteer contributors of the Wikimedia Foundation. To cite this article click here for a list of acceptable citing formats.The history of earlier contributions by wikipedians is accessible to researchers here:

The history of this article since it was imported to New World Encyclopedia:

Note: Some restrictions may apply to use of individual images which are separately licensed.