Difference between revisions of "Money" - New World Encyclopedia

From New World Encyclopedia
(fixed)
m
 
(75 intermediate revisions by 5 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
[[Category:Politics and social sciences]]
+
{{Copyedited}}{{Paid}}{{Approved}}{{Images OK}}{{Submitted}}{{Status}}
[[Category:Economics]]
+
[[File:Dollar bill and small change.jpg|thumb|upright=1|Coins and Notes are types of money. Above is a United States dollar bill, two nickels, and a penny]]
{{Claimed}}
 
[[Image:Fljhfdshrukeurrewfd.jpg|thumb|An example of '''Money'''. More specifically, Brazilian Real bills and coins.]]
 
[[Economics]] offers various definitions for '''money''', though it is now commonly defined by the functions attached to any good or token that functions in [[trade]] as a [[medium of exchange]], [[store of value]], and [[unit of account]].  Some authors explicitly require money to be a [[standard of deferred payment]], too [http://www.amosweb.com/cgi-bin/awb_nav.pl?s=wpd&c=dsp&k=standard%20of%20deferred%20payment].  In common usage, money refers more specifically to [[currency]], particularly the many [[list of circulating currencies|circulating currencies]] with [[legal tender]] status conferred by a [[nation]]al state;  [[deposit account]]s denominated in such currencies are also considered part of the [[money supply]], although these characteristics are historically comparatively recent.  Other older functions a money may possess are a means of rationing access to scarce resources, and a means of accumulating power of command over others.
 
  
The use of money provides an alternative to [[barter]]ing, which is often considered to be inefficient because it requires a [[coincidence of wants]] between traders, and an agreement that these needs are of equal value, before a [[transaction]] can occur.  The efficiency gains through the use of money are thought to encourage trade and the division of labour, in turn increasing productivity and [[wealth]].  
+
'''Money''' is any item or verifiable record that is generally accepted as [[payment]] for [[goods and services]] and repayment of [[debt]]s, such as [[taxes]], in a particular country or socio-economic context.<ref>{{cite book |title=The Economics of Money, Banking, and Financial Markets |last=Mishkin |first=Frederic S. |author-link=Frederic Mishkin |year=2007 |publisher=Addison Wesley |location=Boston |isbn=978-0-321-42177-7 |page=8|edition=Alternate }}</ref><ref>[https://books.google.com/books?id=MDU-NTEJziMC&pg=PA47 ''What Is Money?''] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20221205182603/https://books.google.com/books?id=MDU-NTEJziMC&pg=PA47 |date=2022-12-05 }} By John N. Smithin. Retrieved July-17-09.</ref><ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_M000217&edition=current&q=money&topicid=&result_number=5 |title=money : The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics |website=The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics |access-date=18 December 2010}}</ref> The primary functions which distinguish money are as a [[medium of exchange]], a [[unit of account]], a [[store of value]] and sometimes, a [[standard of deferred payment]].
  
A number of [[Commodity money|commodity money systems]] were amongst the earliest forms of money to emerge. For example
+
Money historically possessed intrinsic value as a [[commodity]] such as grain, gold, or silver. Nearly all contemporary money systems are based on unbacked [[fiat money]] without [[use value]].<ref name="mankiw"/> Its value is consequently derived by social convention, often declared by a [[government]] or regulatory entity to be [[legal tender]]; that is, it must be accepted as a form of payment within the boundaries of the country, for "all debts, public and private," in the case of the [[United States dollar]].
  
* the '''[[shekel]]''' referred to a specific volume of barley in ancient [[Babylon]]
+
The [[money supply]] of a country comprises all [[currency in circulation]] ([[banknote]]s and [[coin]]s currently issued) and, depending on the particular definition used, one or more types of [[Demand deposit|bank money]] (the balances held in [[transactional account|checking accounts]], [[savings account]]s, and other types of [[bank accounts]]). Bank money, whose value exists on the books of financial institutions and can be converted into physical notes or used for cashless payment, is the largest part of [[broad money]] in developed countries.
* [[iron]] sticks were used in [[Argos]], before [[Pheidon]]'s reforms.
+
{{toc}}
* '''[[cowrie]]s''' were used as a money in [[ancient China]] and throughout the South Pacific.
+
Because it has value, money has been a target of theft and fraud. Governments and powerful economic institutions have sought to regulate and control money. The corrupt use of public money has been rampant. [[Friedrich Hayek|Friedrich von Hayek]] argued that money is one of three spontaneous social institutions,<ref>The three primary spheres of society are based on three spontaneous orders that evolve in any human community—language, money, and law. James U. Blanchard III and F. A. Hayek, “Exclusive Interview with F.A. Hayek,” Cato Institute Policy Report, May-June 1984. https://www.cato.org/policy-report/may/june-1984/exclusive-interview-fa-hayek# </ref> and that governments continually interfere with its natural development.  
* '''[[salt]]''' was used as a currency in pre-coinage societies in Europe.
 
* ox-shaped ingots of '''[[copper]]''' seem to have functioned as a currency in the [[Bronze Age]] eastern Mediterranean.
 
* state certified weights of '''[[gold]] and [[silver]]''' have functioned as currency since the reign of [[Croesus]] of [[Lydia]], if not before.
 
* '''[[rum]]-currency''' operated in the early European settlement of [[Sydney]] cove in [[Australian history|Australia]].
 
  
Under a commodity money system, the objects used as money have [[intrinsic value]], i.e., they have value beyond their use as money.  For example, gold coins retain value because of gold's useful physical properties besides its value due to monetary usage, whereas paper notes are only worth as much as the monetary value assigned to them. Commodity money is usually adopted to simplify transactions in a barter economy, and so it functions first as a medium of exchange{{fact}}. It quickly begins functioning as a store of value{{fact}}, since holders of perishable goods can easily convert them into durable money.  
+
== History ==
 +
{{Main|History of money}}
 +
[[File:BMC 06.jpg|thumb|left|A 640 B.C.E. one-third [[stater]] [[electrum]] coin from [[Lydia#First coinage|Lydia]]]]
  
[[Fiat money]] is a relatively modern invention. A central authority (government) creates a new money object that has negligible [[intrinsic value|inherent value]]. The widespread acceptance of fiat money is most frequently enhanced by the central authority mandating the money's acceptance under penalty of law and demanding this money in payment of taxes or tribute. At various times in history, government-issued [[promissory note]]s have later become fiat currencies (e.g. the [[US Dollar]]) and fiat currencies have gone on to become a form of commodity currency (e.g. the [[Swiss Dinar]]) [http://www.ischool.berkeley.edu/~hal/people/hal/NYTimes/2004-01-15.html].
+
The use of [[barter]]-like methods may date back to the first human societies,<ref>Hayek argues that it is a natural "spontaneous" social instituion. James U. Blanchard III and F. A. Hayek, “Exclusive Interview with F.A. Hayek,” Cato Institute Policy Report, May-June 1984. https://www.cato.org/policy-report/may/june-1984/exclusive-interview-fa-hayek# </ref> Non-currency societies may have operated largely along the principles of [[gift economy]] and [[debt]].<ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.nakedcapitalism.com/2011/08/what-is-debt-%E2%80%93-an-interview-with-economic-anthropologist-david-graeber.html |title=What is Debt? – An Interview with Economic Anthropologist David Graeber |publisher=[[Naked Capitalism]]|date=2011-08-26 }}</ref><ref>David Graeber: ''Debt: The First 5000 Years'', Melville 2011. Cf. [http://socialtextjournal.org/a-history-of-debt/ review] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200420132635/https://socialtextjournal.org/a-history-of-debt/ |date=2020-04-20 }}</ref> Barter without stand money was necessary between complete strangers.<ref name="Graeber, David pp. 153-154">{{cite book |author=David Graeber |title=Toward an anthropological theory of value: the false coin of our own dreams |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=uo8tttilAlQC&pg=PA153 |access-date=10 February 2011 |year=2001 |publisher=Palgrave Macmillan |isbn=978-0-312-24045-5 |pages=153–154}}</ref>
  
==Etymology==
+
Many cultures worldwide eventually developed the use of [[commodity money]]. The Mesopotamian [[shekel]] was a unit of weight and relied on the mass of something like 160 [[Grain (unit)|grains]] of [[barley]].<ref>Kramer, ''History Begins at Sumer'', pp. 52–55.</ref> The first usage of the term came from [[Mesopotamia]] circa 3000 B.C.E., where the was wide civilizational travel and anonymous transactions. Some early societies in the Americas, Asia, Africa, and Australia used [[shell money]]. According to [[Herodotus]], the [[Lydians]] were the first people to introduce the use of [[gold coin|gold]] and [[silver coin]]s.<ref>Herodotus. ''Histories'', I, 94</ref> It is thought by modern scholars that these first stamped [[coins]] were minted around 650 to 600 B.C.E.<ref>{{cite web |url=http://rg.ancients.info/lion/article.html |author=Goldsborough, Reid |title=World's First Coin |publisher=rg.ancients.info |date=2003-10-02 |access-date=2009-04-20}}</ref>
  
See the Indo-European and Semitic etymology at [[History_of_money#Indo-European_and_Semitic_etymology|History_of_money]].
+
[[File:Jiao zi.jpg|thumb|upright|Song Dynasty ''Jiaozi'', the world's earliest paper money]]
  
In many languages, the word for money is the same as or similar to the word for silver or gold.  
+
The system of [[commodity money]] eventually spun off systems of representative money, i.e. promissory notes that were traded because gold and silver merchants or banks made them redeemable for the [[commodity money]] deposited. Paper money or [[banknotes]] were first used in China during the [[Song dynasty]]. These banknotes, known as "[[Jiaozi (currency)|jiaozi]]," evolved from [[promissory notes]] that had been used since the 7th century. However, they did not displace commodity money and were used alongside coins. In the 13th century, paper money became known in Europe through the accounts of travelers, such as [[Marco Polo]] and [[William of Rubruck]]<!-- Giljom de Rubruk —>.<ref>{{cite book |last=Moshenskyi |first=Sergii |title=History of the weksel: Bill of exchange and promissory note |year=2008 |isbn=978-1-4363-0694-2 |page=55}}</ref> Marco Polo's account of paper money during the [[Yuan dynasty]] is the subject of a chapter of his book, ''[[The Travels of Marco Polo]]'', titled "[[s:The Travels of Marco Polo/Book 2/Chapter 24|How the Great Kaan Causeth the Bark of Trees, Made Into Something Like Paper, to Pass for Money All Over his Country]]."<ref name="Marco Polo">{{cite book |author=Marco Polo |title=The Travels of Marco Polo, a Venetian, in the Thirteenth Century: Being a Description, by that Early Traveller, of Remarkable Places and Things, in the Eastern Parts of the World |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=JetQAAAAcAAJ&pg=PA353 |access-date=19 September 2012 |year=1818 |pages=353–355}}</ref>
The French, appart from the word ''Monnaie'', they also use the word ''argent'' (which means 'silver'), to mean money [http://www.bbc.co.uk/dna/h2g2/A873795| 1].  The word translated "money" Old Testament is "keseph," but this word actually means "silver."  Likewise, the Greek words underlying the translation "money" in the New Testament actually mean silver or a certain weight of silver.  The modern notion of the word "money" as currency (fiat money or paper notes) is a very recent development in the meaning of the word "money."  This shift began in 1913 with the creation of the Federal Reserve.  The change in meaning to pure paper notes was aided by Roosevelt in 1933 when Americans were required to turn in their gold for paper, but the silver coins in use continued to be "money" in the original sense (with a brief period of debasement during WWII) until 1964 when the silver was removed from U.S. coins.  Despite the attempt by the central bank to enforce the new meaning of the word money as standing for paper currency or electronic credits, there has always been a significant number of scholars who point out that this is just a deception and that "money" must be real substance, i.e. gold, silver, or some other commodity that functions well as a unit of exhange.
 
  
==History==
+
In 1609 the Bank of Amsterdam was created as an exchange bank, an early [[central bank]]. The small country was awash in coins and currencies from various issuers. The Bank of Amsterdam brokered the exchange of money and guaranteed the settlements in an accounting unit called the florin. The florin was the first instance of what is called stablecoin, a term developed to describe cryptocurrencies whose value is pegged to some outside reference to maintain price stability for commercial transactions. The bank formed a single economic function that escaped many government conflicts of interest.<ref>Gordon L. Anderson, ''Integral Society: Social Institutions and Individual Sovereignty'' (St. Paul, MN: Paragon House, 2023), pp. 113-115.</ref> Due to its sound financial practices, the Bank of Amsterdam’s currency became a reserve currency, the dominant currency in Europe in the 17th and 18th centuries.<ref>Stephen Quinn and William Roberds, “Death of a Reserve Currency,” ''International Journal of Central Banking,'' December 2016, pp. 63-103.</ref>
  
Money has developed over the years from gold, silver, copper, brass, iron, stones, or shells to paper, or electronic entries being managed by complex international banking systems.
+
The [[gold standard]], a [[monetary system]] where the medium of exchange is paper notes that are convertible into preset, fixed quantities of gold, replaced the use of gold coins as currency in the 17th–19th centuries in Europe. These gold standard notes were made [[legal tender]]. With the impending failure of the Bank of England in 1686, the redemption of gold coins was suspended and then later discouraged by the government, which needed the bank to have reserves for loans to spread the Empire. At the beginning of the 20th century, almost all countries had adopted the gold standard, backing their legal tender notes with fixed amounts of gold.
  
 +
After [[World War II]] and the [[Bretton Woods Conference]], most countries adopted fiat currencies that were fixed to the [[United States dollar|U.S. dollar]]. At the war's end, the U.S. had the largest amount of gold reserves, and the dollar became the world reserve currency. In 1971 the U.S. government suspended the convertibility of the dollar to gold, and many countries de-pegged their currencies from the U.S. dollar. The dollar remained the world reserve currency as most oil was traded in dollars, often termed "petro-dollars." Today most of the world's currencies are declared official by government laws that make it mandatory for merchants to accept payment in the national currency. In the West, fiat money is also backed by taxes. By imposing taxes, states create demand for the currency they issue.<ref>{{cite book |last1=Wray |first1=L. Randall |title=Modern money theory: a primer on macroeconomics for sovereign monetary systems |date=2012 |publisher=Palgrave Macmillan |location=Houndmills, Basingstoke, Hampshire |isbn=978-0230368897 |pages=45–50}}</ref> In the United States, the [[Sixteenth Amendment]] was required to allow direct taxation of citizen's to enable the Federal Reserve System to print money for the government against tax debt. The [[European Central Bank]], which also serves many sovereign states, was developed on that model.
  
The '''history of money''' is a story spanning thousands of years.  Related to this, [[Numismatics]] is the scientific study of money and its history in all its varied forms.
+
== Functions ==
  
Money itself must be a [[scarcity|scarce]] good. Many items have been used as money, from naturally scarce [[precious metal]]s and [[conch shell]]s through [[cigarette]]s to entirely artificial money such as [[banknote]]s. Modern money (and most ancient money too) is essentially a token — in other words, an abstraction. Paper currency is perhaps the most common type of physical money today. <!-- Question: why 'perhaps'? Why can't this article say whether it is or isn't? —>However, goods such as [[gold]] or [[silver]] retain many of money's essential properties.
+
In ''Money and the Mechanism of Exchange (1875)'', [[William Stanley Jevons]] famously analyzed money in terms of four functions: a ''[[medium of exchange]]'', a ''common measure of value'' (or [[unit of account]]), a ''standard of value'' (or [[standard of deferred payment]]), and a ''[[store of value]]''. By 1919, Jevons's four functions of money were summarized in the [[couplet]]:
 +
:Money's a matter of functions four,
 +
:A Medium, a Measure, a Standard, a Store.<ref name="a_milnes">{{cite book |last=Milnes |first=Alfred |title=The economic foundations of reconstruction |url=https://archive.org/details/in.ernet.dli.2015.22790 |publisher=Macdonald and Evans |year=1919 |page=[https://archive.org/details/in.ernet.dli.2015.22790/page/n67 55]}}</ref>
  
===The emergence of money===
+
This couplet would later become widely popular in macroeconomics textbooks.<ref name="dwivedi">{{cite book |last=Dwivedi |first=DN |title=Macroeconomics: Theory and Policy |publisher=Tata McGraw-Hill |year=2005 |page=182}}</ref> Most modern textbooks now list only three functions, that of [[medium of exchange]], [[unit of account]], and [[store of value]], not considering a standard of deferred payment as a distinguished function, but rather subsuming it in the others.<ref name="mankiw">{{cite book |title=Macroeconomics |last=Mankiw |first=N. Gregory |author-link=N. Gregory Mankiw |year=2007 |edition=6th |pages=[https://archive.org/details/macroeconomics0000mank/page/22 22–32] |chapter=2 |publisher=Worth Publishers |location=New York |isbn=978-0-7167-6213-3 |chapter-url=https://archive.org/details/macroeconomics0000mank/page/22 }}</ref><ref name="krugman">Krugman, Paul & Wells, Robin, ''Economics'', Worth Publishers, New York (2006)</ref><ref name="abel_bernanke">{{cite book |last1=Abel |first1=Andrew |last2=Bernanke |first2=Ben |author-link2=Ben Bernanke |title=Macroeconomics |publisher=Pearson |year=2005 |edition=5th |pages=266–269 |chapter=7 |isbn=978-0-201-32789-2}}</ref>
  
[[Image:Blombosbeads3.jpg|thumb|left|250px| Shells of the pea-sized snail Nassarius kraussianus.  Blombos Cave, South Africa, 75,000 B.P.  Wear marks indicate the shells were strung on a necklace or bracelet.]]
+
There have been many historical disputes regarding the combination of money's functions, some arguing that they need more separation and that a single institution is insufficient to deal with them all. One of these arguments is that the role of money as a [[medium of exchange]] conflicts with its role as a [[store of value]]: its role as a store of value requires holding it without spending, whereas its role as a medium of exchange requires it to circulate.<ref name="greco">[[Thomas H. Greco, Jr.|T.H. Greco]]. ''Money: Understanding and Creating Alternatives to Legal Tender'', White River Junction, Vt: Chelsea Green Publishing (2001). ISBN 1-890132-37-3</ref> Others argue that the storing of value is just a deferral of the exchange, but this does not diminish the fact that money is a medium of exchange that can be transported both across space and time. The term "financial capital" is a more general and inclusive term for all liquid instruments, whether or not they are uniformly recognized tender.
The use of proto-money may date back to at least 100,000 [[Before Present|B.P]] [http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/science/nature/5099104.stm].  Trading in [[red ochre]] is attested in [[Swaziland]], from about that date, and ochre seems to have functioned as a proto-money in [[Australian Aborigines|Aboriginal Australia]]. Shell [[jewellery]] in the form of strung beads would have served as good with the basic attributes needed of early money. In cultures where metal working was unknown, shell or ivory jewellery were the most divisible, easily storable and transportable, scarce, and hard to counterfeit objects that could be made.  It is highly unlikely that there were formal markets in 100,000 B.P (any more than there are in recently observed hunter-gatherer cultures). Nevertheless, proto-money would have been useful in reducing the costs of less frequent transactions that were crucial to hunter-gatherer cultures, especially bride purchase, splitting property upon death, tribute, and intertribal trade in hunting ground rights (“starvation insurance”) and implements.  In the absence of a medium of exchange, all of these transactions suffer from the basic problem of [[barter]] — they require an improbable [[coincidence of wants]] or events. Jewellery has often been used for currency and wealth storage in some historical and contemporary societies, especially those in which modern forms of money are scarce, in addition to being used for decoration and display of status and wealth.
 
  
In cultures, of any era, that lack money, [[barter]]ing and some system of in-kind "credit" or "gift exchange" would be the only ways to exchange goods. Bartering has several problems, most notably the [[coincidence of wants]] problem. If one wishes to trade fruit for wheat, it can only be done when the fruit and wheat are both available at the same time and place, which may be for a very brief time, or may be never.  With an intermediate commodity (whether it be shells, rum, gold, etc.) fruit can be sold when it is ripe in exchange for the intermediate commodity. This intermediate commodity can then be used to buy wheat when the wheat harvest comes in. Thus the use of money makes all [[commodity|commodities]] become more [[liquidity|liquid]].
+
=== Medium of exchange ===
 +
{{Main|Medium of exchange}}
  
Where trade is common, [[barter|barter systems]] usually lead quite rapidly to several key goods being imbued with monetary properties. In the early British colony of [[New South Wales]] in [[Australia]], rum emerged quite soon after settlement as the most monetary of goods. When a nation is without a fiat currency system it is quite common for the fiat currency of a neighbouring nation to emerge as the dominant monetary good. In some prisons where conventional money is prohibited, it is quite common for goods such as cigarettes to take on a monetary quality. Gold has emerged naturally from the world of barter again and again to take on a monetary function.  It should be noted that the emergence of monetary goods is not dependent on central authority or government. It is a quite natural market phenomenon.
+
When money is used to intermediate the exchange of goods and services, it is performing a function as a ''medium of exchange''. It thereby avoids the inefficiencies of a barter system, such as the inability to permanently ensure "[[coincidence of wants]]". For example, between two parties in a barter system, one party may not have or make the item that the other wants, indicating the non-existence of the coincidence of wants. Having a medium of exchange can alleviate this issue because the former can have the freedom to spend time on other items, instead of being burdened to only serve the needs of the latter. Meanwhile, the latter can use the medium of exchange to seek for a party that can provide them with the item they want.
  
===Commodity money===
+
=== Measure of value ===
 +
{{Main|Unit of account}}
  
Many early instances of money were objects which were useful for their [[intrinsic value]] as well as their [[money|monetary properties]]. This has been called [[commodity money]]; historical examples include iron nails (in Scotland), [[pig]]s, rare [[seashell]]s, whale's teeth, and (often) [[cattle]]. In medieval [[Iraq]], [[bread]] was used as an early form of currency.
+
A ''unit of account'' (in economics)<ref>{{cite web|date=2017-10-11|title=Functions of Money|url=https://www.boundless.com/business/textbooks/boundless-business-textbook/the-functions-of-money-and-banking-21/money-as-a-tool-123/functions-of-money-568-3194/|url-status=dead|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20151018115939/https://www.boundless.com/business/textbooks/boundless-business-textbook/the-functions-of-money-and-banking-21/money-as-a-tool-123/functions-of-money-568-3194/|archive-date=October 18, 2015|website=[[Boundless (company)|boundless.com]]}}</ref> is a standard numerical monetary unit of measurement of the market value of goods, services, and other transactions. Also known as a "measure" or "standard" of relative worth and deferred payment, a unit of account is a necessary prerequisite for the formulation of commercial agreements that involve debt.
  
The use of shells or ivory was nearly universal before humans discovered how to work with precious metals; in [[China]], Africa, and many other areas, use of [[cowry|cowrie shells]] was common.  In China the use of cowrie shells was superseded by metal representations of the shells, as well as representations of metal tools.  These imitations may have been the precursors of coinage.
+
Money acts as a standard measure and a common denomination of trade. It is thus a basis for quoting and bargaining of prices. It is necessary for developing efficient accounting systems like [[double-entry bookkeeping]].
  
[[Salt]] and [[spices]] have been used as money. From 550 B.C.E., accepting salt from a person was synonymous with receiving a [[salary]], taking pay, or being in that person's service. Definite indications are available that both black and white [[black pepper|pepper]] have been used as commodity money for hundreds of years before [[Christ]], and several centuries thereafter. Being a valuable commodity, pepper has naturally been used as payment. [[Alaric]] reportedly  demanded 3,000 pounds in weight of pepper in 408 C.E. as part of a ransom for the city of Rome. In the [[Middle Ages]], there was a French saying, 'As dear as pepper'. In England, rent could be paid in pounds of pepper, and so a symbolic minimal amount is known as a "peppercorn rent."
+
=== Standard of deferred payment ===
[[Image:Gold ingots.jpg|thumb|right|150px|[[Precious metal]]s have been a common form of money, such as this [[gold]] from [[Sveriges Riksbank]].]]
+
{{Main|Standard of deferred payment}}
 +
While ''standard of deferred payment'' is distinguished by some texts,<ref name="greco" /> particularly older ones, other texts subsume this under other functions. A "standard of deferred payment" is an accepted way to settle a [[debt]]—a unit in which debts are denominated, and the status of money as [[legal tender]], which may be used the discharge of debts. When debts are denominated in money, the real value of debts may change due to inflation and [[deflation]], and for sovereign and international debts via [[debasement]] and [[devaluation]].
  
Even in the modern world, in the absence of other types of money, people have occasionally used commodities such as [[tobacco]] as money. This happened on a wide scale after [[World War II]] when cigarettes became used unofficially in [[Europe]], in parallel with other currencies, for a short time. It also occurs in some remote parts of countries such as [[Colombia]] and [[Bolivia]], where [[cocaine]], or its precursor, [[coca]] paste, is used as commodity money.
+
=== Store of value ===
 +
{{Main|Store of value}}
 +
Originally banks were storehouses to keep quantities of people's money safe for a fee. To act as a ''store of value'', money must be reliably saved, stored, and retrieved—and be predictably usable as a medium of exchange when it is retrieved. The value of the money must also remain stable over time. Some have argued that inflation, by reducing the value of printed money, diminishes the ability to use it as a store of value. In that case, gold and precious metals function better.
  
Another example of "commodity money" is ''shell money'' in the [[Solomon Islands]]. Shells are painstakingly chipped into rough circles, filed down, and threaded onto large necklaces, which are then used during marriage proposals; for instance, a father may charge twenty shell money necklaces for his daughter's hand in marriage.  
+
==Properties==
 +
The functions of money are that it is a medium of exchange, a unit of account, and a store of value.<ref>{{cite web |url=https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2012/09/basics.htm |title=What is Money? |access-date=28 December 2022| publisher=International Monetary Fund}}</ref> To fulfill these various functions, money must be:<ref name="dallasFedMoney">{{cite web |url=https://www.dallasfed.org/~/media/documents/educate/everyday/money.pdf |title=Money |publisher=Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas|access-date=28 December 2022}}</ref>
 +
* [[Fungibility|Fungible]]: its individual units must be capable of mutual substitution (i.e., interchangeability).
 +
* [[Durability|Durable]]: able to withstand repeated use.
 +
* Divisible: divisible to small units.
 +
* Portable: easily carried and transported.
 +
* Acceptable: most people must accept the money as payment
 +
* Scarce: its supply in circulation must be limited.
 +
* Anonymous: It must pass reliably without any restriction because of the previous holder.
  
One interesting example of commodity money is the huge [[limestone]] coins from the [[Micronesia]]n island of [[Yap]], quarried with great peril from a source several hundred miles away. The value of the coin was determined by its size &mdash; the largest of which could range from nine to twelve feet in diameter and weigh several tons. Displaying a large coin, often outside one's home, was a considerable [[status symbol]] and source of prestige in that society. (Owing to the great inconvenience, islanders would often trade only promises of ownership of an individual coin instead of actually moving it. In some cases, coins which had been lost at sea were still used for exchange in this way. These agreements could be thought of as a kind of ''representative money'', described below.)
+
== Money supply ==
 
+
{{Main|Money supply}}
Once a commodity becomes used as money, it takes on a value that is often different from its intrinsic worth or usefulness.  Having the propety of money adds an extra use to the commodity, and so increases its value.  This extra use is a convention of society, and the scope of its use as money within the society affects the value of the monetary commodity.  So although commodity money is real, it should not be seen as having a fixed value in absolute terms.  To a large extent its value is still socially determined.  A prime example is gold, which has been valued differently by many different societies, but perhaps valued most by those who used it as money.  Fluctuations in the value of commodity money can be strongly influenced by [[supply]] and [[demand]], whether current or predicted (if a local [[gold mine]] is about to run out of ore, the relative market value of gold may go up in anticipation of a shortage).
 
[[Image:Yap Stone Money.jpg|thumb|left|160px|An 8-foot "coin" from the village of Gachpar, on [[Yap]].]]
 
 
 
Money can be anything which the trading parties agree has transferable value, but the usability of a particular sort of money varies widely. Desirable features of a good basis for money include being able to be stored for long periods of time, dense so it can be carried about easily, and difficult to find on its own so it is actually worth something.
 
 
 
Metals like [[gold]] and [[silver]] have been used as commodity money for thousands of years, being in the form of metal dust, nuggets, rings, bracelets and assorted pieces. Eventually the [[Lydians]] began coining  gold and silver around 560 B.C.E.
 
 
 
Gold and silver are both quite soft metals, and coins minted from the pure metals suffer from wear or deformation in daily use. Fortunately these metals are also easily [[alloy|alloyed]] with a less expensive metal, frequently copper, to improve durability of the resulting coins. Typically alloys of [[coinage metal]]s, such as [[sterling silver]] or 22 [[carat (purity)|carat]] (92%) gold, are used to make coins more durable. These are alloys of 90% or more precious metal, for alloys of less than 90% do not improve hardness or durability much, and so are typically considered to be liable to fall into monetary debasement.
 
 
 
===Standardized coinage===
 
 
 
[[Image:Maximinus denarius.jpg|right|frame|A [[Ancient Rome|Roman]] [[denarius]], a standardized [[silver coin]].]]
 
It was the discovery of the [[touchstone]] which led the way for metal-based commodity money and coinage. Any soft metal can be tested for purity on a touchstone, allowing one to quickly calculate the total content of a particular metal in a lump. Gold is a soft metal, which is also hard to come by, dense, and storable. As a result, monetary gold spread very quickly from [[Asia Minor]], where it first gained wide usage, to the entire world.
 
 
 
Using such a system still required several steps and mathematical calculation. The touchstone allows one to estimate the amount of gold in an [[alloy]], which is then multiplied by the weight to find the amount of gold alone in a lump.
 
 
 
To make this process easier, the concept of standard coinage was introduced. [[Coin]]s were pre-weighed and pre-alloyed, so as long as the manufacturer was aware of the origin of the coin, no use of the touchstone was required. Coins were typically [[mint (coin)|minted]] by governments in a carefully protected process, and then stamped with an emblem that guaranteed the weight and value of the metal. It was, however, extremely common for governments to assert the value of such money lay in its emblem and thus to subsequently debase the currency by lowering the content of valuable metal.
 
 
 
Although gold and silver were commonly used to mint coins, other metals could be used.  For instance, Ancient [[Sparta]] minted coins from [[iron]] to discourage its citizens from engaging in foreign trade. In the early seventeenth century Sweden lacked more precious metal and so produced "plate money," which were large slabs of copper approximately 50cm or more in length and width, appropriately stamped with indications of their value.
 
  
Metal based coins had the advantage of carrying their value within the coins themselves &mdash; on the other hand, they induced manipulations: the clipping of coins in the attempt to get and recycle the precious metal. A greater problem was the simultaneous co-existence of gold, silver and copper coins in Europe. English and Spanish traders valued gold coins more than silver coins, as many of their neighbors did, with the effect that the English gold-based guinea coin began to rise against the English silver based crown in the 1670s and 1680s. Consequently, silver was ultimately pulled out of England for dubious amounts of gold coming into the country at a rate no other European nation would share. The effect was worsened with Asian traders not sharing the European appreciation of gold altogether &mdash; gold left Asia and silver left Europe in quantities European observers like [http://www.pierre-marteau.com/editions/1701-25-mint-reports.html Isaac Newton], Master of the Royal Mint observed with unease.
+
In economics, money is any [[Instrument (finance)|financial instrument]] that can fulfill the functions of money (detailed above). These financial instruments together are collectively referred to as the [[money supply]] of an economy. Since the money supply consists of various financial instruments (usually currency, demand deposits, and various other types of deposits), the amount of money in an economy is measured by adding together these financial instruments creating a ''monetary aggregate''.
  
Stability came into the system with national Banks guaranteeing to change money into gold at a promised rate; it did, however, not come easily. The Bank of England risked a national financial catastrophe in the 1730s when customers demanded their money be changed into gold in a moment of crisis. Eventually London's merchants saved the bank and the nation with financial guarantees.
+
Economists employ different ways to measure the stock of money or money supply, reflected in different types of monetary aggregates, using a categorization system that focuses on the [[Market liquidity|liquidity]] of the financial instrument used as money. The most commonly used monetary aggregates (or types of money) are conventionally designated M1, M2, and M3. These are successively larger aggregate categories: M1 is currency (coins and bills) plus [[demand deposit]]s (such as checking accounts); M2 is M1 plus some [[savings account]]s and [[time deposit]]s under $100,000; M3 is M2 plus larger time deposits and similar institutional accounts. M1 includes only the most liquid financial instruments, and M3 includes relatively illiquid instruments. The precise definition of M1, M2, etc. may differ by country.
  
See also: [[Roman currency]], [[coinage metal]], for conversions of the European coins before the introduction of paper money: [http://www.pierre-marteau.com/currency/converter.html The Marteau Early 18th-Century Currency Converter].
+
Another measure of money, M0, is also used. M0 is [[base money]], or the amount of money actually issued by the [[central bank]] of a country. It is measured as currency plus deposits of banks and other institutions at the central bank. M0 is the only money that can satisfy the [[reserve requirements]] of [[commercial banks]].
  
===Representative money===
+
=== Creation of money ===
 +
In current economic systems, money is created by two procedures:
  
[[Image:5 Silver US Dollars 1896.jpg|thumb|right|300px|An example of representative money, this 1896 note could be exchanged for five [[US Dollar]]s worth of [[silver]].]]
+
'''Legal tender''', or '''narrow money''' (M0), is the currency created by a Central Bank by minting coins and printing banknotes.
The system of [[commodity money]] in many instances evolved into a system of [[representative money]]. This occurred because banks would issue a paper receipt to their depositors, indicating that the receipt was redeemable for whatever precious goods were being stored (usually gold or silver money). It didn't take long before the receipts were traded as money, because everyone knew they were "as good as gold." Representative paper money made possible the practice of [[fractional reserve banking]], in which bankers would print receipts above and beyond the amount of acutal precious metal on deposit.  
 
  
So in this system, paper [[currency]] and non-precious coinage had very little intrinsic value, but achieved significant market value by being backed by a promise to redeem it for a given weight of precious metal, such as silver. This is the origin of the term "British Pound" for instance; it was a unit of money backed by a [[Pound (mass)|Tower pound]] of [[sterling silver]], hence the currency [[Pound Sterling]]. For much of the nineteenth and twentieth centuries, many currencies were based on [[representative money]] through use of the [[gold standard]].
+
'''Bank money''', or '''broad money''' (M1/M2), is the money created by private banks by recording loans as deposits of borrowing clients using [[fractional reserve banking]]. Currently, bank money is mostly created as electronic money.
  
===Fiat money===
+
Bank money, whose value exists on the books of financial institutions and can be converted into physical notes or used for cashless payment, forms by far the largest part of [[broad money]] in developed countries.<ref>{{cite book |last1=Boyle |first1=David |author-link1=David Boyle (author) |title=The Little Money Book |publisher=The Disinformation Company |year=2006 |page=37 |isbn=978-1-932857-26-9}}</ref><ref>{{cite web|title=History of Money|url=http://zzaponline.com/history-of-money/|url-status=dead|archive-url=https://archive.today/20150224234654/http://zzaponline.com/history-of-money/|archive-date=24 February 2015|access-date=24 February 2015|website=Zzaponline.com}}</ref><ref>Bernstein, Peter, ''A Primer on Money and Banking, and Gold'', Wiley, 2008 edition, pp. 29–39</ref> In most countries, most M1/M2 money is created by commercial banks making loans.
  
[[Fiat money]] refers to money that is not backed by reserves of another commodity.  The money itself is given value by government ''[[Fiat currency|fiat]]'' ([[Latin]] for "let it be done") or decree, enforcing ''legal tender laws'', previously known as "forced tender," whereby debtors are legally relieved of the debt if they (offer to) pay it off in the government's money. By law the refusal of "[[legal tender]]" money in favor of some other form of payment is illegal, and has at times in history ([[Roman Empire|Rome]] under [[Diocletian]], and [[French revolution|post-revolutionary France]] during the collapse of the assignats) invoked the [[death penalty]].
+
=== Market liquidity ===
[[Image:1e comm.png|right|frame|An example of fiat money is the new, international currency, the [[Euro]]. Its introduction changed the face of money, superseding many of the world's oldest currencies.]]
+
{{Main|Market liquidity}}
 +
"Market liquidity" describes how easily an item can be traded for another item, or into the common currency within an economy. Money is the most liquid asset because it is universally recognized and accepted as a common currency. In this way, money gives consumers the [[liberty|freedom]] to trade goods and services easily without having to barter.
  
Governments through history have often switched to forms of fiat money in times of need such as war, sometimes by suspending the service they provided of exchanging their money for gold, and other times by simply printing the money that they needed.  When governments produce money more rapidly than economic growth, the money supply overtakes economic value. Therefore, the excess money eventually dilutes the market value of all money issued. This is called [[inflation]]. See [[open market operations]].
+
Liquid financial instruments are easily [[tradable]] and have low [[transaction cost]]s. There should be no (or minimal) [[Bid/offer spread|spread]] between the prices to buy and sell the instrument being used as money.
  
In 1971 the [[United States|US]] finally switched to fiat money indefinitely.  At this point in time many of the economically developed countries' currencies were fixed to the [[US dollar]] (see [[Bretton Woods Conference]]), and so this single step meant that much of the western world's currencies became fiat money based.
+
== Types of Money==
  
Following the first [[Gulf War]] the president of Iraq, [[Saddam Hussein]], repealed the existing Iraqi fiat currency and replaced it with a new currency. Despite having no backing by a commodity and with no central authority mandating its use or defending its value the old currency continued to circulate within the politically isolated [[Kurd]]ish regions of Iraq. It became known as the [[Swiss Dinar]]. This currency remained relatively strong and stable for over a decade. It was formally replaced following the [[2003 invasion of Iraq|second Gulf War]].
+
=== Commodity ===
 +
{{Main|Commodity money}}
  
===Credit money===
+
Many items have been used as [[commodity money]] such as naturally scarce [[precious metal]]s, [[shell]]s, [[barley]], beads, etc., as well as many other things that are thought of as having [[Intrinsic theory of value|value]]. Commodity money value comes from the commodity out of which it is made. The commodity itself constitutes the money, and the money is the commodity.<ref name="Mises">Mises, Ludwig von. ''[[The Theory of Money and Credit]]'', (Indianapolis, IN: [[Liberty Fund, Inc.]], 1981), trans. H. E. Batson. Ch.3 Part One: The Nature of Money, Chapter 3: The Various Kinds of Money, Section 3: Commodity Money, Credit Money, and Fiat Money, Paragraph 25.</ref> Examples of commodities that have been used as mediums of exchange include gold, silver, copper, rice, [[Wampum]], salt, peppercorns, large stones, grain, shells, pelts, alcohol, cigarettes, etc. These items were sometimes used as a metric of perceived value in conjunction with one another in various commodity valuations or [[price system]] economies. The use of commodity money is like barter, but commodity money represents a [[unit of account]]. Although some [[gold coins]] such as the [[Krugerrand]] are considered [[legal tender]], there is no record of their face value on either side of the coin. The rationale is that emphasis is laid on their direct link to the prevailing value of their [[Millesimal fineness|fine gold]] content. [[American Gold Eagle|American Eagles]] are imprinted with their gold content and legal tender [[face value]].
  
[[Credit money]] often exists in conjunction with other money such as fiat money or commodity money, and from the user's point of view is indistinguishable from it. Most of the western world's money is credit money derived from national fiat money currencies.
+
=== Representative ===
 +
{{Main|Representative money}}
 +
In 1875, the British economist [[William Stanley Jevons]] described the money used at the time as "[[representative money]]". Representative money is money that consists of [[token coin]]s, [[paper money]] or other physical tokens such as certificates and notes that can be reliably exchanged for a fixed quantity of a commodity like gold or silver. While not having intrinsic value, representative money can be converted to commodities that have intrinsic value.<ref name="Jevons">{{cite book |last=Jevons |first=William Stanley |title=Money and the Mechanism of Exchange |year=1875 |chapter=XVI: Representative Money |chapter-url=https://archive.org/details/moneyandmechani00goog |access-date=2009-06-28 |isbn=978-1-59605-260-4}}</ref>
  
In a modern economy, a bank will lend all but a small portion of its deposits to borrowers, this is known as [[fractional reserve banking]]. In doing so, it increases the total [[money supply]] above that of the total amount of the fiat money in existence (also known as M0). While a bank will not have access to sufficient cash (fiat money) to meet all the obligations it has to depositors if they wish to withdraw the balance of their cheque accounts (credit money), the majority of transactions will occur using the credit money (cheques and electronic transfers).
+
=== Fiat ===
 +
{{Main|Fiat money}}
  
Strictly speaking a debt is not money, primarily because debt can not act as a unit of account. All debts are denominated in units of something external to the debt. However, credit money certainly acts as a substitute for money when it is used in other functions of money (medium of exchange and store of value).
+
Fiat money or currency has no intrinsic value or guarantees that it can be converted into a valuable commodity (such as gold). Instead, it has value only by government order (fiat). Usually, the government declares the fiat currency (typically notes and coins from a central bank, such as the [[Federal Reserve System]] in the U.S.) to be [[legal tender]], making it unlawful not to accept the fiat currency as a means of repayment for all debts, public and private.<ref name="www-personal.umich">{{cite web |author=Deardorff, Prof. Alan V. |year=2008 |title=Deardorff's Glossary of International Economics |url=http://www-personal.umich.edu/~alandear/glossary/f.html |publisher=Department of Economics, University of Michigan |access-date=2008-07-12}}</ref><ref name="BlackHenry">Black, Henry Campbell (1910). ''A Law Dictionary Containing Definitions Of The Terms And Phrases Of American And English Jurisprudence, Ancient And Modern'', p. 494. West Publishing Co. [[Black’s Law Dictionary]] defines the word "fiat" to mean "a short order or warrant of a Judge or magistrate directing some act to be done; an authority issuing from some competent source for the doing of some legal act"</ref> Some [[bullion coins]] such as the [[Australian Gold Nugget]] and [[American Gold Eagle|American Eagle]] are legal tender. However, they trade based on the [[market price]] of the metal content as a [[commodity]] rather than their legal tender [[face value]] (which is usually only a small fraction of their bullion value).<ref name="usmint.gov">[http://www.usmint.gov/mint_programs/american_eagles/index.cfm?flash=no&action=American_Eagle_Gold usmiNT.gov] . Retrieved July-18-09.</ref><ref>{{cite news |title=Crazy as a Gold Bug |author=Tom Bethell |work=New York |date=1980-02-04 |volume=13 |issue=5 |page=34 |publisher=New York Media |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=6OUCAAAAMBAJ&q=silver+krugerrand&pg=PA33}} Retrieved July-18-09</ref>
  
===Indo-European and Semitic etymology===
+
Fiat money, if physically represented as currency (paper or coins), can be accidentally damaged or destroyed. However, fiat money has an advantage over representative or commodity money because the same laws that created the money can also define rules for its replacement in case of damage or destruction. For example, the U.S. government will replace mutilated [[Federal Reserve Note]]s (U.S. fiat money) if at least half of the physical note can be reconstructed or if it can be otherwise proven to have been destroyed.<ref>[https://web.archive.org/web/20091018013943/http://www.bep.treas.gov/section.cfm/8/39 Shredded & Mutilated: Mutilated Currency], ''Bureau of Engraving and Printing''. Retrieved 2007-05-09.</ref> By contrast, commodity money that has been lost or destroyed cannot be recovered.
  
The origin of the word "money" comes from the Latin word "moneta," which comes from the temple of [[Juno (mythology)|Juno]] ([[Hera]]) the Moneta where the Roman money came from, in the [[History_of_Rome#Roman_Republic|early days of Rome]].
+
=== Coins ===
  
In [[Greek language]], "''Hera Mone tas''" means  the lonely Hera ("''Mone tas''" in [[Doric Greek]], "''Mone tes''" in [[Ionic dialect]]). [[Zeus]] punished Hera and tied her with a golden chain between the earth and sky. Hera, because she was alone between the sky and earth tied with gold, was called moneres or mone (μόνη) (lonely in Greek), and the word money was derived from this. Hera, with the help of [[Hephaestus]], broke the golden chain and released herself. It is said that all gold found on earth (which forms approximately a single cube 20 m a side) originates from the fragments of this golden chain, which fall from the sky and became human's mone (money).
+
These factors led to the shift of the store of value being the metal itself: at first silver, then both silver and gold, and at one point, bronze. Now we have copper coins and other non-precious metals as coins. Metals were mined, weighed, and stamped into coins. This was to assure the individual taking the coin that he was getting a certain known weight of precious metal. Coins could be counterfeited, but they also created a new [[unit of account]], which helped lead to banking. [[Archimedes' principle]] provided the next link: coins could now be easily tested for their [[Fineness|fine]] weight of the metal, and thus the value of a coin could be determined, even if it had been shaved, debased or otherwise tampered with (see [[Numismatics]]).
  
Perhaps because of this fable, gold was used in ancient Greece only in temples, graves and jewels and there is not any ancient Greek golden coin, until the days around 390 B.C.E., when the Greek king [[Philip II of Macedon]] minted golden coins. The first golden coins in history were coined by [[Lydia|Lydian]] king [[Croesus]], around 560 B.C.E.. The first Greek coins were made initially of [[copper]], then of [[iron]] because copper and iron were powerful materials used to make weapons. [[Pheidon]] king of [[Argos]], around 700 B.C.E., changed the coins from iron to a rather useless and ornamental metal, [[silver]], and, according to [[Aristotle]], dedicated some of the remaining iron coins (which were actually iron sticks) to the temple of Hera[http://www.metrum.org/money/heraion.htm]. King Pheidon coined the silver coins at [[Aegina]], at the temple of the goddess of wisdom and war [[Athena]] the [[Aphaia]] (the vanisher), and engraved the coins with a [[Chelone]], which is to this day as a symbol of
+
In most major economies, using coinage, copper, silver, and gold formed three tiers of coins. Gold coins were used for large purchases, payment of the military, and backing of state activities. Silver coins were used for midsized transactions, and as a unit of account for taxes, dues, contracts, and fealty, while copper coins represented the coinage of common transactions. This system had been used in ancient [[Indian coinage|India]] since the time of the [[Mahajanapadas]]. In Europe, this system worked through the [[medieval]] period because there was virtually no new gold, silver, or copper introduced through mining or conquest. Thus the overall ratios of the three coinages remained roughly equivalent.
[[capitalism]]. Chelone coins[http://www.snible.org/coins/hn/aegina.html] were the first medium of exchange that was not backed by a real value good. They were widely accepted and used as the international medium of exchange until the days of [[Peloponnesian War]], when the Athenian [[Drachma]] replace them. According other fables, inventors of money were [[Demodike]](or [[Hermodike]]) of [[Kymi]] (the wife of [[Midas]]), [[Lykos]] (son of [[Pandion II]] and ancestor of the [[Lycia|Lycians]]) and [[Erichthonius of Athens|Erichthonius]], the [[Lydia|Lydians]] or the [[Naxos, Greece|Naxians]].
 
  
The word money in [[Greek language]] is not μόνη (money), it is νόμισμα (nomisma or numisma) which derives from the word νομίζω (nomizo=putative,I think so,I suppose so) and from the word νόμος (nomos=law). So [[Numismatic|numisma]] gives the exact meaning and definition of mone(y). It is something we think has value, or something which someone has convinced us has, but in reality has not. In case we are unconvinced that mone(y) has value and we do not recognize the mone(y) maker authority, mone(y) is also something that we are enforced by law to use it as the unique medium of exchange in trades. In case an individual or a community refuses to accept mone(y) as the unique medium of exchange, then the powerful mone(y) maker authority, using violence and the [[tax|taxes]] procedure, steals the real value goods (home,food,transport,energy) that the individual or the community owns. That is why
+
=== Paper ===
many individuals or communities hide their goods from mone(y)-maker authorities. The crime of hiding goods from a mone(y)-maker authority is called [[tax evasion]].
+
{{main|Banknote}}
 +
[[File:Hui_zi.jpg|thumb|upright|[[Huizi (currency)|Huizi currency]], issued in 1160]]
 +
In [[History of China|premodern China]], the need for credit and for circulating a medium that was less of a burden than exchanging thousands of [[Coin|copper coins]] led to the introduction of [[paper money]]. This economic phenomenon was a slow and gradual process that took place from the late [[Tang dynasty]] (618–907) into the [[Song dynasty]] (960–1279). It began as a means for merchants to exchange heavy coinage for [[receipt]]s of deposit issued as [[promissory note]]s from shops of wholesalers, notes that were valid for temporary use in a small regional territory. In the 10th century, the [[Song dynasty]] government began circulating these notes amongst the traders in their [[monopolized]] salt industry. The Song government granted several shops the sole right to issue banknotes, and in the early 12th century the government finally took over these shops to produce state-issued currency. Yet the banknotes issued were still regionally valid and temporary; it was not until the mid 13th century that a standard and uniform government issue of paper money was made into an acceptable nationwide currency. The already widespread methods of [[woodblock printing]] and then [[Pi Sheng]]'s [[movable type]] printing by the 11th century was the impetus for the massive production of paper money in premodern China.
  
"'' He who has an ear, let him hear what the Spirit says to the churches. To the winner, I will give some of the hidden [[manna]] and I will also give him a white vote with a new name written on it which no one knows except the one who receives it.''"([[Book of Revelation]] 2:17).
+
[[File:Money_poster.JPG|thumb|left|Paper money from different countries]]
 +
At around the same time in the [[Islamic Golden Age|medieval Islamic world]], a vigorous [[monetary economy]] was created during the 7th–12th centuries on the basis of the expanding levels of circulation of a stable high-value currency (the [[dinar]]). Innovations introduced by economists, traders and merchants of the Muslim world include the earliest uses of [[Credit (finance)|credit]],<ref name=Banaji>{{cite journal |last=Banaji |first=Jairus |year=2007 |title=Islam, the Mediterranean and the Rise of Capitalism |journal=Historical Materialism |volume=15 |issue=1 |pages=47–74 |issn=1465-4466 |doi=10.1163/156920607X171591 |oclc=440360743 |url=https://www.scribd.com/doc/14246569/Banaji-Jairus-Islam-The-Mediterranean-and-the-Rise-of-Capitalism |access-date=August 28, 2010 |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20090523015524/http://www.scribd.com/doc/14246569/Banaji-Jairus-Islam-The-Mediterranean-and-the-Rise-of-Capitalism |archive-date=May 23, 2009}}</ref> [[cheque]]s, [[savings account]]s, [[transactional account]]s, loaning, [[trusts]], [[exchange rate]]s, the transfer of credit and [[debt]],<ref name=Labib>{{cite journal |last=Labib |first=Subhi Y. |date=March 1969 |title=Capitalism in Medieval Islam |journal=The Journal of Economic History |volume=29 |issue=1 |pages=79–86 |issn=0022-0507 |oclc=478662641 |jstor=2115499|doi=10.1017/S0022050700097837 |s2cid=153962294 }}</ref> and [[banking institution]]s for loans and [[deposit account|deposits]].<ref name=Labib />
  
One of the words for money in the [[Hebrew language]] is [[mammon]]. Mammon does have more than one meaning depending on its linguistic and etymological contexts. The [[Hebrew Bible|Hebrew]] and [[Christian]] [[Bible]] gives the word mammon a broader context in its [[socioeconomic]], cultural, and [[theological]] usages.
+
In Europe, paper money was first introduced in [[Sweden]] in 1661. Sweden was rich in copper, thus, because of copper's low value, extraordinarily big coins (often weighing several kilograms) had to be made. The advantages of paper currency were numerous: it reduced transport of gold and silver, and thus lowered the risks; it made loaning gold or silver at interest easier since the specie (gold or silver) never left the possession of the lender until someone else redeemed the note; and it allowed for a division of currency into credit and specie backed forms. It enabled the sale of [[stock]] in [[joint stock companies]], and the redemption of those [[shares]] in the paper.
Mammon, a word of [[Aramaic]] origin, means "riches," but has an unclear etymology; scholars have suggested connections with a word meaning "entrusted," or with the [[Hebrew (language)|Hebrew]] word "matmon," meaning "treasure." {{fact}} It is also used in Hebrew as a word for "money" - ממון.  
 
  
The [[Greek language|Greek]] word for "Mammon," ''mamonas'', occurs in the [[Sermon on the Mount]] ([[Book of Matthew|Matthew]] vi 24) and in the parable of the Unjust Steward (Luke xvi 9-13). The [[Authorised Version]] keeps the Syriac word. Wycliffe uses "richessis." Other scholars derive Mammon from [[Phoenician languages|Phoenician]] "mommon," benefit. It is interesting to note that if mammon(as) (μαμων{{Polytonic|&#x1fb6;}}ς) is considered as a Greek word and as a composite one (the majority of Greek words are composites), the two parts "[[Manna|mam]]-mon(as)" could be explained (in Greek doric) as "lonely mother," which recalls Hera's myth mentioned above. Other explanations could be
+
However, these advantages are held within their disadvantages. First, since a note has no intrinsic value, unethical authorities printed more of it than they had specie to back it with. Second, because it increased the money supply, it increased inflationary pressures, a fact observed by [[David Hume]] in the 18th century. Thus, paper money would often lead to an inflationary bubble, which could collapse if people began demanding hard money, causing the demand for paper notes to fall to zero. The printing of paper money was also used for financing wars. It was also possible to counterfeit. For these reasons, paper currency was held in suspicion and hostility. It has been widely misused since the speculative profits of trade and capital creation were quite large. Major nations established [[mint (coin)|mints]] to print money and mint coins, and branches of their treasury to collect taxes and hold gold and silver stock.
mamm(means "mother" or "food")-onas(means "a place where you can find mamm"), also mam(means "mother" or "food")-m(means "with")-on(means "being")-as(with [[Circumflex]], means "owner or seller").
 
  
Another word for money in hebrew is the word Kessef-כסף, that translates to silver. Also the french word for money, [[Argent]], derives from the greek ''άργυρος'', and translates also to silver.
+
Both silver and gold have been [[legal tender]] and accepted by governments for taxes. However, the [[Gresham's law|instability in the ratio]] between the two grew over the 19th century, with the increase in the supply of these metals, particularly silver, and of trade. Bimetallism attempts to create a standard where both gold and silver-backed currency remain in circulation.
  
According to the Book of Revelation, the [[mark of the beast]] seems to be a form of money:
+
By 1900, most industrial nations were on some form of a gold standard, with paper notes and silver coins constituting the circulating medium. Private banks and governments worldwide followed [[Gresham's law]]: keeping gold and silver paid but paying out in notes. Gradually floating fiat currencies came into force. One of the last countries to break away from the [[gold standard]] was the United States in 1971.
"''And he causeth all, both small and great, rich and poor, free and bond, to receive a mark in their right hand, or in their foreheads: And that '''no man might buy or sell, save he that had the [[Mark of the Beast|mark]]''', or the name of the beast, or the number of his name. Here is wisdom. Let him that hath understanding vote the number of the beast: for it is the number of a man; and his(its) number is ΧΞς.''" ([[Book of Revelation]] 13:16-13:18).
 
  
 +
=== Commercial bank money creation ===
  
 +
Commercial bank money or [[demand deposit]]s are claims against financial institutions that can be used to purchase goods and services. A demand deposit account is an account from which funds can be withdrawn at any time by check or [[cash]] withdrawal without giving the bank or financial institution any prior notice. Banks are legally obligated to return funds held in demand deposits immediately upon demand (or 'at call'). Demand deposit withdrawals can be performed in person, via checks or bank drafts, using [[automatic teller machine]]s (ATMs), or through [[online banking]].<ref>{{cite book |last1=O'Sullivan |first1=Arthur |author-link=Arthur O'Sullivan (economist) |first2=Steven M. |last2=Sheffrin |author-link2=Steven M. Sheffrin |title=Economics: Principles in Action |url=https://archive.org/details/economicsprincip00osul |url-access=limited |publisher=Pearson Prentice Hall |year=2003 |location=Upper Saddle River, New Jersey |page=[https://archive.org/details/economicsprincip00osul/page/n274 258] |isbn=978-0-13-063085-8}}</ref>
  
==Essential characteristics==
+
New commercial bank money is created through [[fractional-reserve banking]], the banking practice where banks keep only a fraction of their [[demand deposit|deposits]] in [[bank reserves|reserve]] (as cash and other highly liquid assets) and lend out the remainder while maintaining the obligation to redeem all these deposits upon demand.<ref>''The Bank Credit Analysis Handbook: A Guide for Analysts, Bankers, and Investors'' by Jonathan Golin. Publisher: John Wiley & Sons (2001). ISBN 978-0-471-84217-0</ref><ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.bankintroductions.com/definition.html |website=Bankintroductions.com |title=Economic Definitions |access-date=7 October 2014 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150202090722/http://www.bankintroductions.com/definition.html |archive-date=2 February 2015 |url-status=dead }}</ref> Commercial bank money differs from commodity and fiat money in two ways: firstly it is non-physical, as its existence is only reflected in the account ledgers of banks and other financial institutions, and secondly, there is some element of risk that the claim will not be fulfilled if the financial institution becomes insolvent. The process of fractional-reserve banking has a cumulative effect of [[money creation]] by commercial banks, as it expands the [[money supply]] (cash and demand deposits) beyond what it would otherwise be. Because of the prevalence of fractional reserve banking, the [[M2 (economics)|broad money supply]] of most countries is a multiple (greater than 1) of the amount of [[Monetary base|base money]] created by the country's [[central bank]]. That multiple (called the [[money multiplier]]) is determined by the [[reserve requirement]] or other [[financial ratio]] requirements imposed by financial regulators.
Money is generally considered to have the following three characteristics:
 
  
'''1. It is a [[medium of exchange]]'''
+
===Digital or electronic===
 +
{{Main|Digital money}}
 +
The development of computer technology in the second part of the twentieth century allowed money to be represented digitally. By 1990, in the United States all money transferred between its central bank and commercial banks was in electronic form. By the 2000s, most money existed as [[digital currency]] in bank databases.<ref>{{cite web|url=https://money.howstuffworks.com/currency6.htm|title=How Currency Works|date=2 September 2003|access-date=22 October 2018|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190730143424/https://money.howstuffworks.com/currency6.htm|archive-date=30 July 2019|url-status=dead}}</ref> In 2012, by the number of transactions, 20 to 58 percent of transactions were electronic (dependent on country).<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.bbc.com/future/story/20150724-the-truth-about-the-death-of-cash|title=The truth about the death of cash|first=Rose|last=Eveleth}}</ref>
  
{{Main|medium of exchange}}
+
Anonymous digital currencies were developed in the early 2000s. Early examples include [[Ecash]], [[bit gold]], [[RPOW]], and [[b-money]]. Not much innovation occurred until the conception of [[Bitcoin]] in 2008, which introduced the concept of a decentralized currency using blockchain technology that requires no trusted third party.<ref>{{cite news |author = Wallace, Benjamin |title = The Rise and Fall of Bitcoin |url = https://www.wired.com/magazine/2011/11/mf_bitcoin/ |publisher = Wired |date = 23 November 2011 |access-date = 13 October 2012 |archive-url = https://web.archive.org/web/20131031043919/http://www.wired.com/magazine/2011/11/mf_bitcoin |archive-date = 31 October 2013 |url-status=live }}</ref> Bitcoin threatens national currencies by avoiding the corruption of government central banks, and it is used on black markets to evade government tracking of transactions. This caused the development of central bank digital currencies (CBDCs), where governments can track every transaction.
  
A '''medium of exchange''' is an intermediary used in [[trade]] to avoid the inconveniences of a pure [[barter]] system.
+
== Monetary policy ==
 +
{{Main|Monetary policy}}
 +
[[File:USCurrency Federal Reserve.jpg|thumbnail|US dollar banknotes]]
 +
When gold and silver are used as money, the money supply can grow only as the supply of these metals is increased by mining. This rate of increase during [[gold rush]]es and discoveries causing inflation as the value of gold goes down. If the rate of [[gold mining]] cannot keep up with the growth of the economy, gold becomes relatively more valuable, and prices (denominated in gold) will drop, causing deflation. Deflation was common when gold and paper money backed by gold were used as money in the 18th and 19th centuries. Thus, while the money had intrinsic value, it did not allow for natural economic expansion with monetary stability.  
  
'''2. It is a [[unit of account]]'''
+
Monetary systems based on fiat money and [[fractional reserve banking|fractional reserve lending]] can avoid this problem, as money can be created as people want to build and create businesses. When loans are repaid, the money supply decreases. The central bank can issue the needed amount of currency in circulation to keep the value of money stable. Monetary policy is when the [[monetary authority]] manages the [[money supply]].
  
{{Main|unit of account}}
+
This management process gets more complex when governments and financial institutions receive nonproductive loans, i.e., loans used for fighting wars or speculating with secondary financial instruments, sub-prime mortgages, and other risky investments. Such nonproductive loans cause inflation and shift wealth from producers to nonproducers. The monetary policy then has to control inflationary pressures from money creation not backed by real economic expansion. A further complication is when private central banks charge interest on new money for their profit, shifting wealth from society to the central bank owners and causing states to stay in debt. This is the situation with the Federal Reserve System in the United States. The [[Federal Reserve Act]] that the [[Board of Governors]] and the [[Federal Open Market Committee]] should seek "to promote effectively the goals of maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates."<ref>The Federal Reserve. [http://www.federalreserve.gov/pf/pdf/pf_2.pdf 'Monetary Policy and the Economy".] ([[PDF]]) ''Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System'', (2005-07-05). Retrieved 2007-05-15.</ref> These goals are at cross-purposes and require a balancing act that pits economic growth against a targeted 2% inflation rate to allow for nonproductive new money. The insatiable appetite of governments and financial industries engaged in the nonproductive use of reserves caused this system to break in 1932. This was curtailed by the [[Glass-Steagall Act]] of 1933, which restrained bank speculating, and unleashed when the Act was repealed in 1999. The World Comm, Enron, and other scandals immediately followed in 2002, followed by the financial collapse and bailout of 2007-2008. However, rather than reinstating the Glass-Steagall Act, as the former Federal Reserve Chairman Paul Volcker recommended,<ref>Gordon L. Anderson, ''Integral Society: Social Institutions and Individual Sovereignty'' (St. Paul, MN: Paragon House, 2023), p. 119.</ref> the banks drafted laws that consolidated the big banks without addressing unsustainable government debt.
  
A '''unit of account''' is a standard numerical unit of measurement of the market value of goods, services, and other transactions.  
+
A failed monetary policy can cause [[hyperinflation]], [[stagflation]], [[recession]], high unemployment, shortages of imported goods, inability to export goods, government collapse, and total monetary collapse as happened in Russia, for instance, after the [[History of the Soviet Union (1985-1991)|fall of the Soviet Union]].
  
'''3. It is a [[store of value]]'''
+
Governments and central banks have taken regulatory and [[free market]] approaches to monetary policy. Some of the tools used to control the money supply include:
 
+
* changing the [[interest rate]] at which the central bank loans money to (or borrows money from) the commercial banks
{{Main|store of value}}
+
* currency purchases or sales
 
+
* increasing or lowering [[Government debt|government borrowing]]
To act as a '''store of value''', a [[commodity]], a form of money, or [[financial capital]] must be able to be reliably saved, stored, and retrieved - and be predictably useful when it is so retrieved.
+
* increasing or lowering [[government spending]]
 
+
* manipulation of [[exchange rate]]s
== Desirable features==
+
* raising or lowering bank reserve requirements
To function as money, the monetary item should possess a number of features:
+
* regulation or prohibition of [[Private currency|private currencies]]
 
+
* taxation or tax breaks on imports or exports of capital into a country
'''To be a [[medium of exchange]]:'''
 
* It should have [[liquidity]], and be easily [[trade|tradable]], with a low [[Bid/offer spread|spread]] between the prices to buy and sell, in other words, a low [[transaction cost]].
 
* It should be easily transportable; [[precious metal]]s have a high [[Value (economics)|value]] to weight ratio.  This is why [[petroleum|oil]], [[coal]], [[vermiculite]], or [[water]] are not suitable as money even though they are valuable. Paper notes have proved highly convenient in this regard.
 
* It should be durable.  Money is often left in pockets through the wash.  Australian bank notes are made of plastic for durability.  Gold coins are often mixed with copper to improve durability.
 
* It should minimize contamination and contagion. Since money is frequently handled it becomes a pathway for infectious disease transmission.  Recent studies have shown that the area in business offices that show the highest contamination by disease causing organisms is the accounting office where money must be counted and handled. Unlike paper, silver, as well as platinum and titanium, is used as a anti-bacterial and anti-viral agent. This property of silver has been recognised for millennia and used for eating utensils.
 
 
 
'''To be a [[unit of account]]:'''
 
* It should be divisible into small units without destroying its value; precious metals can be coined from bars, or melted down into bars again.  This is why leather, or live animals are not suitable as money.
 
* It should be [[fungible]]: that is, one unit or piece must be exactly equivalent to another, which is why [[diamond]]s, works of [[art]] or [[real estate]] are not suitable as money.
 
* It must be a specific weight, or measure, or size to be verifiably countable.  For instance, coins are often made with ridges around the edges, so that any removal of material from the coin (lowering its commodity value) will be easy to detect.
 
 
 
'''To be a [[store of value]]:'''
 
* It should be long lasting, durable, it must not be perishable or subject to decay.  This is why food items, expensive [[spice]]s, or even fine [[silk]]s or oriental [[rug]]s, are not generally suitable as money.
 
* It should have a stable value.
 
* It should be difficult to [[counterfeit]], and the genuine must be easily recognizable. 
 
 
 
'''To be [[Anonymity|anonymous]]:'''
 
* Money should not be subject to government tracking.
 
* It should be useable for purchases in a [[black market]].
 
* It should not require equipment, tools or electricity to use.
 
 
 
Money also is typically that which has the least declining [[marginal utility]], meaning that as you accumulate more units of it, each unit is worth about the same as the prior units, and not substantially less. 
 
 
 
For these reasons, [[gold]] and [[silver]] have been chosen again and again throughout [[history of money|history as money]] in more societies and in more cultures and over longer time periods than any other items.  [[Platinum]] and [[palladium]] have not been identified and refined until the last two hundred years, and do not therefore have a long history of use as money, but that may change in the future{{fact}}.
 
 
 
One key benefit of these features of money is that it facilitates and encourages [[trade]], as [[barter]] is far less efficient.
 
 
 
===Problems with gold as money===
 
There is no perfect money, although silver or gold may come closest to this standard.  Gold is not always the most liquid asset due to its higher valuation than silver.  Not many people want to carry a few ounces of gold around.  It's just too valuable, and so there are not as many people to exchange it with.  When gold is demonetized and forced to compete with paper currencies it does have a spread of about 4% to buy and sell in terms of the paper currency, whereas paper money can be exchanged without the 4 to 5 percent preminum imposed by the market preference for paper.  The exchange premium comes from the relative scarcity of people to exhange paper for gold or silver.  The scarcity has resulted in having to pay coin dealers a small profit for the service.  If silver and gold were remonetized, then there would be no shortage of sources for exchange.  Accordingly the premium's charged would drop to nothing in an economy that recognized silver or gold as lawful money.
 
Gold today is a relatively small market (in terms of paper currency), and the price of gold can move substantially higher if a few billion dollars tries to buy gold.  Although gold itself does not decay, gold coins are easily scratched or damaged, and this can reduce their value, and fungibility or of gold coins (athough no where near as fast as inflation reduces the value of paper).  Gold coins are often made with 10% copper for added durability, such as the [[Krugerrand]] and the U.S. Eagle, but then the gold is no longer 99.9% pure, or .999 fine.  The copper alloy, however, reduces the value by very little.  From 1980 to 2001, gold was a poor store of value as its own value was unstable due to the manipulations of the worlds central banks conspiring to manipulate the market by selling their reserves to keep the price down.; gold prices dropped from a high of $850/oz. to a low of $255/oz., and that is also being measured in terms of dollars that were also losing value, so the 1980 high might be more like $1600/oz., but a precisely accurate amount is nearly impossible to measure.  The advantage of gold and silver, however, lies in the fact that the supply cannot be increased by dishonest bankers.  In 2006 they were running low on gold and silver with which to manipulate the market, and the debt overhanging the fiat money fractional reserve system will soon deflate.  This will cause the buying power of silver and gold to rise to extreme levels at first, and then to be used as money until the next system of fiat money, or fiat electronic credit is imposed on the world.
 
 
 
In the history of the Several States of America such attitudes as "gold is the money of monarchs"* helped to maintain  a bi-metallic money system that rejected credit and debt as currency. (*Senator John J. Ingalls, a republican Senator from Kansas, in a speech delivered on the 14th of February, 1877 also Ingalls, "Globe," vol. cxxxvii, p. 1052.)
 
 
 
===Problems with paper as money===
 
Due to the ease of production paper money may lose value through [[inflation]] and can be easily damaged or destroyed. Despite the ease of production there have been notable instances paper money experiencing deflation. For example the British Pound after the 1925 revision of the [[gold standard]] and the Japanese Yen during the 1990s. Perhaps the biggest criticism of paper money relates to the fact that its stability is generally subject the whim of government regulation rather than the disciplines of market phenoma.
 
 
 
==Modern forms==
 
[[Banknote]]s (also known as paper money) and [[coin]]s are the most liquid forms of tangible money and are commonly used for small person-to-person transactions. Today, [[gold]] is commonly used as a store of value, but is not often used as a medium of exchange or a unit of account.  But central banks do use gold as a unit of account.
 
 
 
There are also less tangible forms of money, which nevertheless serve the same functions as money. [[cheque|Checks]], [[debit card]]s and [[wire transfer]]s are used as means to more easily transfer larger amounts of money between bank accounts. [[Electronic money]] is an entirely non-physical currency that is traded and used over the internet.
 
 
 
==Credit==
 
{{Main|Credit (finance)}} or {{Main|Usury}}
 
[[Credit (finance)|Credit]] is often loosely referred to as money.  Credit is debt or a promise to settle a debt, not money.  Money is what is used to make a payment in full.
 
 
 
This distinction between money and credit causes much confusion in discussions of [[monetary policy|monetary theory]]. In lay terms, and when convenient in academic discussion, credit and money are frequently used interchangeably. For example, bank deposits are generally included in summations of the national broad [[money supply]]. However, any detailed study of monetary theory needs to recognize the proper distinction between money and credit.
 
 
 
Bank notes are a form of credit.  Gold-backed bills are likewise also a debt of the bank, a promise to pay in gold. 
 
 
 
[[Federal Reserve note]]s, which are used as money in the United States, are difficult to describe in terms of credit or debt or money.  Federal Reserve notes are not a promise to pay in gold, and the notes are irredeemable by the issuer.  The Federal Reserve's notes are perhaps viewed best as a political promise to devalue (inflate) at a certain targeted rate.
 
 
 
Since Federal Reserve notes are used in the United States as the most common medium of exchange, unit of account, and store of value, they are considered money by the majority of the population.  To measure this kind of credit money, various forms of credit are counted together and listed as M1 or M2.  M3 was the most common measure of money, but the publication of M3 was discontinued in May, 2006.
 
 
 
== Economics==
 
Money is one of the most central topics studied in [[economics]] and forms its most cogent link to [[finance]]. [[Monetarism]] is an economic theory which predominantly deals with the supply and demand for money. The stability of the demand for money prior to the 1980s was a key finding of the work of [[Milton Friedman]], [[Anna Schwartz]], [[David Laidler]], and many others. Technical, institutional, and legal changes changed the nature of the demand for money during the 1980s.
 
 
 
[[Monetary policy]] aims to manage the [[money supply]], inflation and interest to affect [[output]] and [[employment]]. [[Inflation]] is the decrease in the value of a specific currency over time and can be caused by dramatic increases in the money supply. The [[interest rate]], the cost of borrowing money, is an important tool used to control inflation and economic growth in monetary economics. [[Central bank]]s are often made responsible for monitoring and controlling the money supply, interest rates and [[bank]]ing.
 
 
 
A monetary crisis can have very significant economic effects, particularly if it leads to monetary failure and the adoption of a much less efficient barter economy. This happened in Russia, for instance, after the [[History of the Soviet Union (1985-1991)|fall of the Soviet Union]].
 
 
 
There have been many historical arguments regarding the combination of money's functions, some arguing that they need more separation and that a single unit is insufficient to deal with them all. [[Financial capital]] is a more general and inclusive term for all liquid instruments, whether or not they are a uniformly recognized tender.
 
 
 
== Private currencies ==
 
{{Main|Private currency}}
 
In many countries, the issue of private paper currencies has been severely restricted by law.
 
 
 
[[Image:Delaware Bridge Company Dollar.jpg|thumb|300px|right|A private 1 dollar note, issued by the "Delaware Bridge Company" of [[New Jersey]] 1836-1841.]]
 
 
 
In the [[United States]], the [[Free Banking Era]] lasted between 1837 and 1866. States, municipalities, private banks, railroad and construction companies, stores, restaurants, churches and individuals printed an estimated 8,000 different monies by 1860. If the issuer went bankrupt, closed, left town, or otherwise went out of business the note would be worthless. Such organizations earned the nickname of "wildcat banks" for a reputation of unreliability and that they were often situated in far-off, unpopulated locales that were said to be more apt to wildcats than people. On the other hand, according to Lawrence H. White's article in
 
[http://www.fee.org/publications/the-freeman/article.asp?aid=2046 The Freeman: Ideas on Liberty - October 1993] "''it turns out that “wildcat” banking is largely a myth. Although stories about crooked banking practices are entertaining&mdash;and for that reason have been repeated endlessly by textbooks&mdash;modern economic historians have found that there were in fact very few banks that fit any reasonable definition of wildcat bank''."
 
In [[Australia]], the [[Australian Bank Notes Tax Act 1910|Bank Notes Tax Act of 1910]] basically shut down the circulation of private currencies by imposing a prohibitive tax on the practice. Many other nations have similar such policies that eliminate private sector competition.
 
 
 
In [[Scotland]] and [[Northern Ireland]] private sector banks are licensed to print their own paper money by the government.
 
Today privately issued [[electronic money]] is in circulation.  Some of these private currencies are backed by historic forms of money such as gold, as in the case of [[digital gold currency]].  Transactions in these currencies represent an annual turnover value in billions of US dollars.
 
 
 
It is possible for privately issued money to be backed by any other material, although some people argue about perishable materials. After all, gold, or platinum, or silver, have in some regards less utility than previously (their electrical properties notwithstanding), while currency backed by energy (measured in joules) or by transport (measured in kilogramme*kilometre/hour) or by food [http://www.economist.com/markets/bigmac/displayStory.cfm?story_id=3503641] is also possible and may be accepted by the people, if legalised. It is important to understand though that, as long as money is above all an agreement to use something as a medium of exchange, it is up to a community (or to whoever holds the power within a community) to decide whether money should be backed by whatever material or should be totally virtual.
 
 
 
==Future==
 
 
 
Paper money's greatest failure is as a stable store of value.  All paper money is plagued by inflation, the devaluation of money over time.  Although inflation may be good for debtors, it is not good for savers.
 
 
 
Investors seek to preserve or grow their wealth, and some seek to buy currencies that will stay strong and keep their value.  In 2006, the currency markets trade over $1 trillion each day.  In 2006, all the gold in all the world is valued at about $3.5 trillion.
 
 
 
Today, gold and paper money can be traded electronically via online systems.
 
 
 
==Supply==
 
{{Main|Money supply}}
 
  
[[Image:Money-supply.png|thumb|right|U.S. Money Supply from 1959-2006]]The money supply is the amount of money available within a specific economy available for purchasing goods or services. The supply is usually considered as four escalating categories M0, M1, M2 and M3. The categories grow in size with M3 representing all forms of money (including credit) and M0 being just base money (coins, bills, and central bank deposits). M0 is also money that can satisfy private banks' reserve requirements. In the [[United State]]s, the [[Federal Reserve]] is responsible for controlling the money supply, while in the [[Euro area]] the respective institution is the [[European Central Bank|ECB]]. Other central banks with greater impact on global finances are the [[Bank of Japan]], [[People's Bank of China]] and the [[Bank of England]].
+
In the U.S., the [[Federal Reserve]] is responsible for controlling the money supply, while in the [[Euro area]] the respective institution is the [[European Central Bank]]. Other central banks with a significant impact on global finances are the [[Bank of Japan]], [[People's Bank of China]], and the [[Bank of England]].
  
When gold is used as money, the money supply can grow in either of two ways. First, the money supply can increase as the amount of gold increases by new gold mining at about 2% per year, but it can also increase more during periods of gold rushes and discoveries, such as when Columbus discovered the new world and brought gold back to Spain, or when gold was discovered in California in 1848. This kind of increase helps debtors, and causes inflation, as the value of gold goes down.  Second, the money supply can increase when the value of gold goes up, as this makes existing stocks of gold more valuable.  This kind of increase helps savers and creditors and is called deflation, where items for sale are increasingly less expensive in terms of gold.  Deflation was the more typical situation for over a [[century]] when gold was used as money in the U.S. from 1792 to 1913.
+
For many years monetary policy was influenced by an [[Economics|economic theory]] known as monetarism. [[Monetarism]] argues that management of the money supply should be the primary means of regulating economic activity. The stability of the demand for money before the 1980s was a key finding of [[Milton Friedman]] and [[Anna Schwartz]]<ref>{{cite book |author1=Milton Friedman |author2=Anna Jacobson Schwartz |title=Monetary History of the United States, 1867–1960 |publisher=[[Princeton University Press]] |location=Princeton, N.J |year=1971 |isbn=978-0-691-00354-2 }}</ref> supported by the work of [[David Laidler]],<ref>{{cite book |author1=David Laidler |title=Money and Macroeconomics: The Selected Essays of David Laidler (Economists of the Twentieth Century) |publisher=Edward Elgar Publishing |year=1997 |isbn=978-1-85898-596-1 |url=https://archive.org/details/moneymacroeconom0000laid }}</ref> and others. The nature of the demand for money changed during the 1980s owing to technical, institutional, and legal factors, such as [[supply-side]] economics, and the influence of monetarism has since decreased.
  
 +
== Financial crimes ==
  
 +
=== Counterfeiting ===
 +
{{Main|Counterfeit money}}
 +
Counterfeit money is imitation currency produced without the legal sanction of the state or government. Producing or using counterfeit money is a form of fraud or forgery. Counterfeiting is almost as old as money itself. Plated copies (known as [[Fourrée]]s) have been found of [[Lydia#First coinage|Lydian coins]] which are thought to be among the first western coins.<ref>{{cite web |title=A Case for the World's Oldest Coin |url=http://rg.ancients.info/lion/article.html |access-date=29 January 2013}}</ref> Historically, objects that were difficult to counterfeit (e.g. shells, rare stones, precious metals) were often chosen as money.<ref>{{Cite journal|last1=Gourinchas|first1=Pierre-Olivier|last2=Rey|first2=Hélène|last3=Sauzet|first3=Maxime|date=2019|title=The International Monetary and Financial System|url=https://www.annualreviews.org/doi/10.1146/annurev-economics-080217-053518|journal=Annual Review of Economics|language=en|volume=11|issue=1|pages=859–893|doi=10.1146/annurev-economics-080217-053518|s2cid=169545752|issn=1941-1383}}</ref> Before the introduction of [[Banknotes|paper money]], the most prevalent method of counterfeiting involved mixing base metals with pure gold or silver.
  
==Benchmark World Currencies==
+
A form of counterfeiting is the production of documents by legitimate printers in response to fraudulent instructions. During [[World War II]], the [[Nazis]] forged British pounds and American dollars. Today some of the finest counterfeit banknotes are called ''[[Superdollar]]s'' because of their high quality and likeness to the real U.S. dollar. There has been significant counterfeiting of [[Euro]] banknotes and coins since the launch of the currency in 2002, but considerably less than for the U.S. dollar.<ref name="autogenerated1">{{cite web |url=http://itsamoneything.com/money/counterfeiting-cash-money-infographic/#.VB71g5R_uJQ |title=Counterfeiting statistics for several currencies |publisher=Itsamoneything.com |access-date=2014-09-21|date=2012-06-09 }}</ref>
These are the major currencies used in trading<ref>[http://www.bloomberg.com/markets/currencies/fxc.html benchmark World Currencies at Bloomberg]</ref>.
 
*Australia - [[Australian Dollar]] (AUD)
 
*Canada - [[Canadian Dollar]] (CAD)
 
*European Monetary Union (EUR-12) - [[Euro]] (EUR)
 
*Hong Kong - [[Hong Kong Dollar]] (HKD)
 
*Japan - [[Japanese Yen]] (JPY)
 
*Switzerland - [[Swiss Franc]] (CHF)
 
*United Kingdom - [[Pound sterling|Pound Sterling]] (GBP)
 
*United States - [[United States Dollar|US Dollar]] (USD)
 
  
Besides these currencies gold and silver are traded globally on the currency markets:
+
Another form of counterfeiting, sometimes known as creating funny money, is when the central bank increases the legal money supply for nonproductive purposes like many government loans. This causes inflation and a government debt burden on the citizens, so it is legal but not ethical. This problem can be solved when laws prevent a central bank from lending money, buying securities, or charging interest, acting as an economic agent. A limitation on the role of a central bank as a referee that performs services for a fee can prevent corruption in modern central bank/government cabals. These services include an exchange bank, a clearing house, and a money supply manager.
Gold (XAU) quoted in 1 ounce increments
 
Silver (XAG) quoted in 1000 ounce increments
 
  
==Notes==
+
=== Money laundering ===
<references/>
+
{{Main|Money laundering}}
==References==
+
Money laundering is the process in which the proceeds of crime are transformed into ostensibly legitimate money or other assets. However, in several legal and regulatory systems, the term money laundering has become [[Conflation|conflated]] with other forms of financial crime and sometimes used more generally to include misuse of the financial system (involving things such as misdirected government funds, creating money with risky securities, [[digital currency|digital currencies]], credit cards, and traditional currency), including [[terrorism financing]], [[tax evasion]], and evading of [[international sanctions]].
* Davies, Glyn, [http://www.exeter.ac.uk/~RDavies/arian/llyfr.html History of Money from Ancient Times to the Present Day]
 
* Jevons, W. S. (1875), Money and the Mechanism of Exchange, London: Macmillan.
 
* Menger, Carl, [http://socserv.mcmaster.ca/econ/ugcm/3ll3/menger/money.txt "On the Origin of Money"]
 
* Szabo, Nick, [http://szabo.best.vwh.net/shell.html Shelling Out — The Origins of Money]
 
* [http://www.usmint.gov/ United States Mint]
 
* [http://www.royalmint.com/RoyalMint/web/site/Corporate/Home/corporate_homepage.asp Royal Mint]
 
* [http://www.money.org/AM/Template.cfm?Section=Home American Numismatic Association]
 
* [http://www.worldbank.org/index.html World Bank]
 
* Ingham, Geoffrey. 2004. ''The Nature of Money''. Polity Press. ISBN 074560997X ISBN 978-0745609973
 
* Mzumara, Macleans. 2006. ''The Theory of Money and Banking in Modern Times''. Tate Publishing & Enterprises. ISBN 1933290021 ISBN 978-1933290027
 
*Schwartz, Anna J. 1989. ''Money in Historical Perspective''. Chicago, IL: University Of Chicago Press. ISBN 0226742288 ISBN 978-0226742281
 
  
 +
== Conclusion ==
 +
[[Image:FvonHayek.jpg|thumbnail|right|150px|Friedrich Hayek]]
 +
<blockquote>"The great trouble is that money wasn’t allowed to develop. After two or three hundred years of the use of coins, governments stopped any further developments. We were not allowed to experiment on it, so money hasn’t been improved; it has rather become worse in the course of time.… Money was frozen in its most primitive form. What we have had since was mostly government abuses of money."—F.A. Hayek <ref>Friedrich A. Hayek. Interview by James U. Blanchard III, May 1, 1984. Cato Institute Policy Report May/June 1984. https://www.cato.org/policy-report/may/june-1984/exclusive-interview-fa-hayek#.</ref></blockquote>
  
==External links==
+
The evolution of money has shown that money as a medium of exchange works better as an [[accounting unit]] rather than being tied to precious metals whose supply never matches economic development demands. A currency that represents real economic growth, combined with regulated and insured [[Fractional Reserve Banking|fractional reserve banking]], can automatically adjust to market demands and escape the swings of inflation that come from precious metal-backed money or new money created from nonproductive loans. Unfortunately, attempts to rein in the nonproductive lending of central banks and speculation in financial industries by government laws have been illusive. The [[Glass-Steagall Act]], passed during the extreme economic crisis of the [[Great Recession]], restrained financial speculation for over 60 years until 1999 when banks in the U.S. pressured the government for its repeal. Later financial crises led to laws created by the banks that made the long-term stability of the U.S. dollar unlikely.
*[http://www.bu.edu/wcp/Papers/Econ/EconShep.htm Philosophy of Money] by Alla Sheptun
 
*[http://www.metrum.org/measures/heraion.htm The Heraion Standard.]
 
*[http://www.exeter.ac.uk/~RDavies/arian/llyfr.html History of Money from Ancient Times to the Present Day by Glyn Davies]
 
  
 +
However, greater economic reform is required than reinstating the [[Glass-Steagall]] act, which limited the role of commercial banks. Central banks should also be limited to the role of an economic referee engaged in managing the money supply, servicing banks, and regulating foreign exchange.  This would eliminate conflicts of interest associated with central bank lending, buying and selling securities and assets, storing reserves, and charging interest that debt finances the economy. A separation of government from the economy parallel to the separation of church and state would dramatically reduce the control of government by the banking sector and the temptation of governments to create funny money to finance wars.
  
 +
== References ==
 +
{{reflist}}
  
 +
==Further reading==
 +
* Chown, John F. ''A History of Money: from AD 800'' (Psychology Press, 1994).
 +
* Davies, Glyn, and Duncan Connors. ''A History of Money'' (4th ed. U of Wales Press, 2016) [https://www.amazon.com/History-Money-Fourth-Glyn-Davies/dp/1783163097/ excerpt] .
 +
* [[Niall Ferguson|Ferguson, Niall]]. ''The Ascent of Money: A Financial History of the World'' (2009) [https://www.amazon.com/Ascent-Money-Financial-History-World/dp/0143116177/ excerpt]
 +
* [[Steve Keen|Keen, Steve]] (February 2015). [https://www.forbes.com/sites/stevekeen/2015/02/28/what-is-money-and-how-is-it-created/ "What Is Money and How Is It Created?"] argues, "Banks create money by issuing a loan to a borrower; they record the loan as an asset, and the money they deposit in the borrower’s account as a liability. This, in one way, is no different to the way the Federal Reserve creates money ... money is simply a third party’s promise to pay which we accept as full payment in exchange for goods. The two main third parties whose promises we accept are the government and the banks ... money ... is not backed by anything physical, and instead relies on trust. Of course, that trust can be abused ... we continue to ignore the main game: what the banks do (for good and for ill) that really drives the economy." ''[[Forbes (magazine)|Forbes]]''
 +
* Kuroda, Akinobu. ''A Global History of Money'' (Routledge, 2020). [https://www.amazon.com/Global-History-Routledge-Explorations-Economic/dp/1032237619/ excerpt]
 +
* {{Cite news |last=Hartman |first=Mitchell |date=October 30, 2017 |title=How Much Money Is There in the World? |url=https://www.marketplace.org/2017/10/30/world/how-much-money-there-world |department=I've Always Wondered... (story series) |work=[[Marketplace (radio program)|Marketplace]] |publisher=[[American Public Media]] |access-date=October 31, 2017}}
 +
* [[John Lanchester|Lanchester, John]], "The Invention of Money: How the heresies of two bankers became the basis of our modern economy", ''[[The New Yorker]]'', 5 & 12 August 2019, pp.&nbsp;28–31.
 +
* Weatherford, Jack. ''The history of money'' (2009). by a cultural anthropologist. [https://www.amazon.com/History-Money-Jack-Weatherford/dp/0609801724/ excerpt]
  
{{Credit2|Money|87812724|History_of_money|86964776|}}
+
{{credits|1158379770}}

Latest revision as of 16:23, 18 June 2023

Coins and Notes are types of money. Above is a United States dollar bill, two nickels, and a penny

Money is any item or verifiable record that is generally accepted as payment for goods and services and repayment of debts, such as taxes, in a particular country or socio-economic context.[1][2][3] The primary functions which distinguish money are as a medium of exchange, a unit of account, a store of value and sometimes, a standard of deferred payment.

Money historically possessed intrinsic value as a commodity such as grain, gold, or silver. Nearly all contemporary money systems are based on unbacked fiat money without use value.[4] Its value is consequently derived by social convention, often declared by a government or regulatory entity to be legal tender; that is, it must be accepted as a form of payment within the boundaries of the country, for "all debts, public and private," in the case of the United States dollar.

The money supply of a country comprises all currency in circulation (banknotes and coins currently issued) and, depending on the particular definition used, one or more types of bank money (the balances held in checking accounts, savings accounts, and other types of bank accounts). Bank money, whose value exists on the books of financial institutions and can be converted into physical notes or used for cashless payment, is the largest part of broad money in developed countries.

Because it has value, money has been a target of theft and fraud. Governments and powerful economic institutions have sought to regulate and control money. The corrupt use of public money has been rampant. Friedrich von Hayek argued that money is one of three spontaneous social institutions,[5] and that governments continually interfere with its natural development.

History

A 640 B.C.E. one-third stater electrum coin from Lydia

The use of barter-like methods may date back to the first human societies,[6] Non-currency societies may have operated largely along the principles of gift economy and debt.[7][8] Barter without stand money was necessary between complete strangers.[9]

Many cultures worldwide eventually developed the use of commodity money. The Mesopotamian shekel was a unit of weight and relied on the mass of something like 160 grains of barley.[10] The first usage of the term came from Mesopotamia circa 3000 B.C.E., where the was wide civilizational travel and anonymous transactions. Some early societies in the Americas, Asia, Africa, and Australia used shell money. According to Herodotus, the Lydians were the first people to introduce the use of gold and silver coins.[11] It is thought by modern scholars that these first stamped coins were minted around 650 to 600 B.C.E.[12]

Song Dynasty Jiaozi, the world's earliest paper money

The system of commodity money eventually spun off systems of representative money, i.e. promissory notes that were traded because gold and silver merchants or banks made them redeemable for the commodity money deposited. Paper money or banknotes were first used in China during the Song dynasty. These banknotes, known as "jiaozi," evolved from promissory notes that had been used since the 7th century. However, they did not displace commodity money and were used alongside coins. In the 13th century, paper money became known in Europe through the accounts of travelers, such as Marco Polo and William of Rubruck.[13] Marco Polo's account of paper money during the Yuan dynasty is the subject of a chapter of his book, The Travels of Marco Polo, titled "How the Great Kaan Causeth the Bark of Trees, Made Into Something Like Paper, to Pass for Money All Over his Country."[14]

In 1609 the Bank of Amsterdam was created as an exchange bank, an early central bank. The small country was awash in coins and currencies from various issuers. The Bank of Amsterdam brokered the exchange of money and guaranteed the settlements in an accounting unit called the florin. The florin was the first instance of what is called stablecoin, a term developed to describe cryptocurrencies whose value is pegged to some outside reference to maintain price stability for commercial transactions. The bank formed a single economic function that escaped many government conflicts of interest.[15] Due to its sound financial practices, the Bank of Amsterdam’s currency became a reserve currency, the dominant currency in Europe in the 17th and 18th centuries.[16]

The gold standard, a monetary system where the medium of exchange is paper notes that are convertible into preset, fixed quantities of gold, replaced the use of gold coins as currency in the 17th–19th centuries in Europe. These gold standard notes were made legal tender. With the impending failure of the Bank of England in 1686, the redemption of gold coins was suspended and then later discouraged by the government, which needed the bank to have reserves for loans to spread the Empire. At the beginning of the 20th century, almost all countries had adopted the gold standard, backing their legal tender notes with fixed amounts of gold.

After World War II and the Bretton Woods Conference, most countries adopted fiat currencies that were fixed to the U.S. dollar. At the war's end, the U.S. had the largest amount of gold reserves, and the dollar became the world reserve currency. In 1971 the U.S. government suspended the convertibility of the dollar to gold, and many countries de-pegged their currencies from the U.S. dollar. The dollar remained the world reserve currency as most oil was traded in dollars, often termed "petro-dollars." Today most of the world's currencies are declared official by government laws that make it mandatory for merchants to accept payment in the national currency. In the West, fiat money is also backed by taxes. By imposing taxes, states create demand for the currency they issue.[17] In the United States, the Sixteenth Amendment was required to allow direct taxation of citizen's to enable the Federal Reserve System to print money for the government against tax debt. The European Central Bank, which also serves many sovereign states, was developed on that model.

Functions

In Money and the Mechanism of Exchange (1875), William Stanley Jevons famously analyzed money in terms of four functions: a medium of exchange, a common measure of value (or unit of account), a standard of value (or standard of deferred payment), and a store of value. By 1919, Jevons's four functions of money were summarized in the couplet:

Money's a matter of functions four,
A Medium, a Measure, a Standard, a Store.[18]

This couplet would later become widely popular in macroeconomics textbooks.[19] Most modern textbooks now list only three functions, that of medium of exchange, unit of account, and store of value, not considering a standard of deferred payment as a distinguished function, but rather subsuming it in the others.[4][20][21]

There have been many historical disputes regarding the combination of money's functions, some arguing that they need more separation and that a single institution is insufficient to deal with them all. One of these arguments is that the role of money as a medium of exchange conflicts with its role as a store of value: its role as a store of value requires holding it without spending, whereas its role as a medium of exchange requires it to circulate.[22] Others argue that the storing of value is just a deferral of the exchange, but this does not diminish the fact that money is a medium of exchange that can be transported both across space and time. The term "financial capital" is a more general and inclusive term for all liquid instruments, whether or not they are uniformly recognized tender.

Medium of exchange

When money is used to intermediate the exchange of goods and services, it is performing a function as a medium of exchange. It thereby avoids the inefficiencies of a barter system, such as the inability to permanently ensure "coincidence of wants". For example, between two parties in a barter system, one party may not have or make the item that the other wants, indicating the non-existence of the coincidence of wants. Having a medium of exchange can alleviate this issue because the former can have the freedom to spend time on other items, instead of being burdened to only serve the needs of the latter. Meanwhile, the latter can use the medium of exchange to seek for a party that can provide them with the item they want.

Measure of value

A unit of account (in economics)[23] is a standard numerical monetary unit of measurement of the market value of goods, services, and other transactions. Also known as a "measure" or "standard" of relative worth and deferred payment, a unit of account is a necessary prerequisite for the formulation of commercial agreements that involve debt.

Money acts as a standard measure and a common denomination of trade. It is thus a basis for quoting and bargaining of prices. It is necessary for developing efficient accounting systems like double-entry bookkeeping.

Standard of deferred payment

While standard of deferred payment is distinguished by some texts,[22] particularly older ones, other texts subsume this under other functions. A "standard of deferred payment" is an accepted way to settle a debt—a unit in which debts are denominated, and the status of money as legal tender, which may be used the discharge of debts. When debts are denominated in money, the real value of debts may change due to inflation and deflation, and for sovereign and international debts via debasement and devaluation.

Store of value

Originally banks were storehouses to keep quantities of people's money safe for a fee. To act as a store of value, money must be reliably saved, stored, and retrieved—and be predictably usable as a medium of exchange when it is retrieved. The value of the money must also remain stable over time. Some have argued that inflation, by reducing the value of printed money, diminishes the ability to use it as a store of value. In that case, gold and precious metals function better.

Properties

The functions of money are that it is a medium of exchange, a unit of account, and a store of value.[24] To fulfill these various functions, money must be:[25]

  • Fungible: its individual units must be capable of mutual substitution (i.e., interchangeability).
  • Durable: able to withstand repeated use.
  • Divisible: divisible to small units.
  • Portable: easily carried and transported.
  • Acceptable: most people must accept the money as payment
  • Scarce: its supply in circulation must be limited.
  • Anonymous: It must pass reliably without any restriction because of the previous holder.

Money supply

Main article: Money supply

In economics, money is any financial instrument that can fulfill the functions of money (detailed above). These financial instruments together are collectively referred to as the money supply of an economy. Since the money supply consists of various financial instruments (usually currency, demand deposits, and various other types of deposits), the amount of money in an economy is measured by adding together these financial instruments creating a monetary aggregate.

Economists employ different ways to measure the stock of money or money supply, reflected in different types of monetary aggregates, using a categorization system that focuses on the liquidity of the financial instrument used as money. The most commonly used monetary aggregates (or types of money) are conventionally designated M1, M2, and M3. These are successively larger aggregate categories: M1 is currency (coins and bills) plus demand deposits (such as checking accounts); M2 is M1 plus some savings accounts and time deposits under $100,000; M3 is M2 plus larger time deposits and similar institutional accounts. M1 includes only the most liquid financial instruments, and M3 includes relatively illiquid instruments. The precise definition of M1, M2, etc. may differ by country.

Another measure of money, M0, is also used. M0 is base money, or the amount of money actually issued by the central bank of a country. It is measured as currency plus deposits of banks and other institutions at the central bank. M0 is the only money that can satisfy the reserve requirements of commercial banks.

Creation of money

In current economic systems, money is created by two procedures:

Legal tender, or narrow money (M0), is the currency created by a Central Bank by minting coins and printing banknotes.

Bank money, or broad money (M1/M2), is the money created by private banks by recording loans as deposits of borrowing clients using fractional reserve banking. Currently, bank money is mostly created as electronic money.

Bank money, whose value exists on the books of financial institutions and can be converted into physical notes or used for cashless payment, forms by far the largest part of broad money in developed countries.[26][27][28] In most countries, most M1/M2 money is created by commercial banks making loans.

Market liquidity

"Market liquidity" describes how easily an item can be traded for another item, or into the common currency within an economy. Money is the most liquid asset because it is universally recognized and accepted as a common currency. In this way, money gives consumers the freedom to trade goods and services easily without having to barter.

Liquid financial instruments are easily tradable and have low transaction costs. There should be no (or minimal) spread between the prices to buy and sell the instrument being used as money.

Types of Money

Commodity

Many items have been used as commodity money such as naturally scarce precious metals, shells, barley, beads, etc., as well as many other things that are thought of as having value. Commodity money value comes from the commodity out of which it is made. The commodity itself constitutes the money, and the money is the commodity.[29] Examples of commodities that have been used as mediums of exchange include gold, silver, copper, rice, Wampum, salt, peppercorns, large stones, grain, shells, pelts, alcohol, cigarettes, etc. These items were sometimes used as a metric of perceived value in conjunction with one another in various commodity valuations or price system economies. The use of commodity money is like barter, but commodity money represents a unit of account. Although some gold coins such as the Krugerrand are considered legal tender, there is no record of their face value on either side of the coin. The rationale is that emphasis is laid on their direct link to the prevailing value of their fine gold content. American Eagles are imprinted with their gold content and legal tender face value.

Representative

In 1875, the British economist William Stanley Jevons described the money used at the time as "representative money". Representative money is money that consists of token coins, paper money or other physical tokens such as certificates and notes that can be reliably exchanged for a fixed quantity of a commodity like gold or silver. While not having intrinsic value, representative money can be converted to commodities that have intrinsic value.[30]

Fiat

Fiat money or currency has no intrinsic value or guarantees that it can be converted into a valuable commodity (such as gold). Instead, it has value only by government order (fiat). Usually, the government declares the fiat currency (typically notes and coins from a central bank, such as the Federal Reserve System in the U.S.) to be legal tender, making it unlawful not to accept the fiat currency as a means of repayment for all debts, public and private.[31][32] Some bullion coins such as the Australian Gold Nugget and American Eagle are legal tender. However, they trade based on the market price of the metal content as a commodity rather than their legal tender face value (which is usually only a small fraction of their bullion value).[33][34]

Fiat money, if physically represented as currency (paper or coins), can be accidentally damaged or destroyed. However, fiat money has an advantage over representative or commodity money because the same laws that created the money can also define rules for its replacement in case of damage or destruction. For example, the U.S. government will replace mutilated Federal Reserve Notes (U.S. fiat money) if at least half of the physical note can be reconstructed or if it can be otherwise proven to have been destroyed.[35] By contrast, commodity money that has been lost or destroyed cannot be recovered.

Coins

These factors led to the shift of the store of value being the metal itself: at first silver, then both silver and gold, and at one point, bronze. Now we have copper coins and other non-precious metals as coins. Metals were mined, weighed, and stamped into coins. This was to assure the individual taking the coin that he was getting a certain known weight of precious metal. Coins could be counterfeited, but they also created a new unit of account, which helped lead to banking. Archimedes' principle provided the next link: coins could now be easily tested for their fine weight of the metal, and thus the value of a coin could be determined, even if it had been shaved, debased or otherwise tampered with (see Numismatics).

In most major economies, using coinage, copper, silver, and gold formed three tiers of coins. Gold coins were used for large purchases, payment of the military, and backing of state activities. Silver coins were used for midsized transactions, and as a unit of account for taxes, dues, contracts, and fealty, while copper coins represented the coinage of common transactions. This system had been used in ancient India since the time of the Mahajanapadas. In Europe, this system worked through the medieval period because there was virtually no new gold, silver, or copper introduced through mining or conquest. Thus the overall ratios of the three coinages remained roughly equivalent.

Paper

Huizi currency, issued in 1160

In premodern China, the need for credit and for circulating a medium that was less of a burden than exchanging thousands of copper coins led to the introduction of paper money. This economic phenomenon was a slow and gradual process that took place from the late Tang dynasty (618–907) into the Song dynasty (960–1279). It began as a means for merchants to exchange heavy coinage for receipts of deposit issued as promissory notes from shops of wholesalers, notes that were valid for temporary use in a small regional territory. In the 10th century, the Song dynasty government began circulating these notes amongst the traders in their monopolized salt industry. The Song government granted several shops the sole right to issue banknotes, and in the early 12th century the government finally took over these shops to produce state-issued currency. Yet the banknotes issued were still regionally valid and temporary; it was not until the mid 13th century that a standard and uniform government issue of paper money was made into an acceptable nationwide currency. The already widespread methods of woodblock printing and then Pi Sheng's movable type printing by the 11th century was the impetus for the massive production of paper money in premodern China.

Paper money from different countries

At around the same time in the medieval Islamic world, a vigorous monetary economy was created during the 7th–12th centuries on the basis of the expanding levels of circulation of a stable high-value currency (the dinar). Innovations introduced by economists, traders and merchants of the Muslim world include the earliest uses of credit,[36] cheques, savings accounts, transactional accounts, loaning, trusts, exchange rates, the transfer of credit and debt,[37] and banking institutions for loans and deposits.[37]

In Europe, paper money was first introduced in Sweden in 1661. Sweden was rich in copper, thus, because of copper's low value, extraordinarily big coins (often weighing several kilograms) had to be made. The advantages of paper currency were numerous: it reduced transport of gold and silver, and thus lowered the risks; it made loaning gold or silver at interest easier since the specie (gold or silver) never left the possession of the lender until someone else redeemed the note; and it allowed for a division of currency into credit and specie backed forms. It enabled the sale of stock in joint stock companies, and the redemption of those shares in the paper.

However, these advantages are held within their disadvantages. First, since a note has no intrinsic value, unethical authorities printed more of it than they had specie to back it with. Second, because it increased the money supply, it increased inflationary pressures, a fact observed by David Hume in the 18th century. Thus, paper money would often lead to an inflationary bubble, which could collapse if people began demanding hard money, causing the demand for paper notes to fall to zero. The printing of paper money was also used for financing wars. It was also possible to counterfeit. For these reasons, paper currency was held in suspicion and hostility. It has been widely misused since the speculative profits of trade and capital creation were quite large. Major nations established mints to print money and mint coins, and branches of their treasury to collect taxes and hold gold and silver stock.

Both silver and gold have been legal tender and accepted by governments for taxes. However, the instability in the ratio between the two grew over the 19th century, with the increase in the supply of these metals, particularly silver, and of trade. Bimetallism attempts to create a standard where both gold and silver-backed currency remain in circulation.

By 1900, most industrial nations were on some form of a gold standard, with paper notes and silver coins constituting the circulating medium. Private banks and governments worldwide followed Gresham's law: keeping gold and silver paid but paying out in notes. Gradually floating fiat currencies came into force. One of the last countries to break away from the gold standard was the United States in 1971.

Commercial bank money creation

Commercial bank money or demand deposits are claims against financial institutions that can be used to purchase goods and services. A demand deposit account is an account from which funds can be withdrawn at any time by check or cash withdrawal without giving the bank or financial institution any prior notice. Banks are legally obligated to return funds held in demand deposits immediately upon demand (or 'at call'). Demand deposit withdrawals can be performed in person, via checks or bank drafts, using automatic teller machines (ATMs), or through online banking.[38]

New commercial bank money is created through fractional-reserve banking, the banking practice where banks keep only a fraction of their deposits in reserve (as cash and other highly liquid assets) and lend out the remainder while maintaining the obligation to redeem all these deposits upon demand.[39][40] Commercial bank money differs from commodity and fiat money in two ways: firstly it is non-physical, as its existence is only reflected in the account ledgers of banks and other financial institutions, and secondly, there is some element of risk that the claim will not be fulfilled if the financial institution becomes insolvent. The process of fractional-reserve banking has a cumulative effect of money creation by commercial banks, as it expands the money supply (cash and demand deposits) beyond what it would otherwise be. Because of the prevalence of fractional reserve banking, the broad money supply of most countries is a multiple (greater than 1) of the amount of base money created by the country's central bank. That multiple (called the money multiplier) is determined by the reserve requirement or other financial ratio requirements imposed by financial regulators.

Digital or electronic

The development of computer technology in the second part of the twentieth century allowed money to be represented digitally. By 1990, in the United States all money transferred between its central bank and commercial banks was in electronic form. By the 2000s, most money existed as digital currency in bank databases.[41] In 2012, by the number of transactions, 20 to 58 percent of transactions were electronic (dependent on country).[42]

Anonymous digital currencies were developed in the early 2000s. Early examples include Ecash, bit gold, RPOW, and b-money. Not much innovation occurred until the conception of Bitcoin in 2008, which introduced the concept of a decentralized currency using blockchain technology that requires no trusted third party.[43] Bitcoin threatens national currencies by avoiding the corruption of government central banks, and it is used on black markets to evade government tracking of transactions. This caused the development of central bank digital currencies (CBDCs), where governments can track every transaction.

Monetary policy

Main article: Monetary policy
US dollar banknotes

When gold and silver are used as money, the money supply can grow only as the supply of these metals is increased by mining. This rate of increase during gold rushes and discoveries causing inflation as the value of gold goes down. If the rate of gold mining cannot keep up with the growth of the economy, gold becomes relatively more valuable, and prices (denominated in gold) will drop, causing deflation. Deflation was common when gold and paper money backed by gold were used as money in the 18th and 19th centuries. Thus, while the money had intrinsic value, it did not allow for natural economic expansion with monetary stability.

Monetary systems based on fiat money and fractional reserve lending can avoid this problem, as money can be created as people want to build and create businesses. When loans are repaid, the money supply decreases. The central bank can issue the needed amount of currency in circulation to keep the value of money stable. Monetary policy is when the monetary authority manages the money supply.

This management process gets more complex when governments and financial institutions receive nonproductive loans, i.e., loans used for fighting wars or speculating with secondary financial instruments, sub-prime mortgages, and other risky investments. Such nonproductive loans cause inflation and shift wealth from producers to nonproducers. The monetary policy then has to control inflationary pressures from money creation not backed by real economic expansion. A further complication is when private central banks charge interest on new money for their profit, shifting wealth from society to the central bank owners and causing states to stay in debt. This is the situation with the Federal Reserve System in the United States. The Federal Reserve Act that the Board of Governors and the Federal Open Market Committee should seek "to promote effectively the goals of maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates."[44] These goals are at cross-purposes and require a balancing act that pits economic growth against a targeted 2% inflation rate to allow for nonproductive new money. The insatiable appetite of governments and financial industries engaged in the nonproductive use of reserves caused this system to break in 1932. This was curtailed by the Glass-Steagall Act of 1933, which restrained bank speculating, and unleashed when the Act was repealed in 1999. The World Comm, Enron, and other scandals immediately followed in 2002, followed by the financial collapse and bailout of 2007-2008. However, rather than reinstating the Glass-Steagall Act, as the former Federal Reserve Chairman Paul Volcker recommended,[45] the banks drafted laws that consolidated the big banks without addressing unsustainable government debt.

A failed monetary policy can cause hyperinflation, stagflation, recession, high unemployment, shortages of imported goods, inability to export goods, government collapse, and total monetary collapse as happened in Russia, for instance, after the fall of the Soviet Union.

Governments and central banks have taken regulatory and free market approaches to monetary policy. Some of the tools used to control the money supply include:

  • changing the interest rate at which the central bank loans money to (or borrows money from) the commercial banks
  • currency purchases or sales
  • increasing or lowering government borrowing
  • increasing or lowering government spending
  • manipulation of exchange rates
  • raising or lowering bank reserve requirements
  • regulation or prohibition of private currencies
  • taxation or tax breaks on imports or exports of capital into a country

In the U.S., the Federal Reserve is responsible for controlling the money supply, while in the Euro area the respective institution is the European Central Bank. Other central banks with a significant impact on global finances are the Bank of Japan, People's Bank of China, and the Bank of England.

For many years monetary policy was influenced by an economic theory known as monetarism. Monetarism argues that management of the money supply should be the primary means of regulating economic activity. The stability of the demand for money before the 1980s was a key finding of Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz[46] supported by the work of David Laidler,[47] and others. The nature of the demand for money changed during the 1980s owing to technical, institutional, and legal factors, such as supply-side economics, and the influence of monetarism has since decreased.

Financial crimes

Counterfeiting

Counterfeit money is imitation currency produced without the legal sanction of the state or government. Producing or using counterfeit money is a form of fraud or forgery. Counterfeiting is almost as old as money itself. Plated copies (known as Fourrées) have been found of Lydian coins which are thought to be among the first western coins.[48] Historically, objects that were difficult to counterfeit (e.g. shells, rare stones, precious metals) were often chosen as money.[49] Before the introduction of paper money, the most prevalent method of counterfeiting involved mixing base metals with pure gold or silver.

A form of counterfeiting is the production of documents by legitimate printers in response to fraudulent instructions. During World War II, the Nazis forged British pounds and American dollars. Today some of the finest counterfeit banknotes are called Superdollars because of their high quality and likeness to the real U.S. dollar. There has been significant counterfeiting of Euro banknotes and coins since the launch of the currency in 2002, but considerably less than for the U.S. dollar.[50]

Another form of counterfeiting, sometimes known as creating funny money, is when the central bank increases the legal money supply for nonproductive purposes like many government loans. This causes inflation and a government debt burden on the citizens, so it is legal but not ethical. This problem can be solved when laws prevent a central bank from lending money, buying securities, or charging interest, acting as an economic agent. A limitation on the role of a central bank as a referee that performs services for a fee can prevent corruption in modern central bank/government cabals. These services include an exchange bank, a clearing house, and a money supply manager.

Money laundering

Money laundering is the process in which the proceeds of crime are transformed into ostensibly legitimate money or other assets. However, in several legal and regulatory systems, the term money laundering has become conflated with other forms of financial crime and sometimes used more generally to include misuse of the financial system (involving things such as misdirected government funds, creating money with risky securities, digital currencies, credit cards, and traditional currency), including terrorism financing, tax evasion, and evading of international sanctions.

Conclusion

Friedrich Hayek

"The great trouble is that money wasn’t allowed to develop. After two or three hundred years of the use of coins, governments stopped any further developments. We were not allowed to experiment on it, so money hasn’t been improved; it has rather become worse in the course of time.… Money was frozen in its most primitive form. What we have had since was mostly government abuses of money."—F.A. Hayek [51]

The evolution of money has shown that money as a medium of exchange works better as an accounting unit rather than being tied to precious metals whose supply never matches economic development demands. A currency that represents real economic growth, combined with regulated and insured fractional reserve banking, can automatically adjust to market demands and escape the swings of inflation that come from precious metal-backed money or new money created from nonproductive loans. Unfortunately, attempts to rein in the nonproductive lending of central banks and speculation in financial industries by government laws have been illusive. The Glass-Steagall Act, passed during the extreme economic crisis of the Great Recession, restrained financial speculation for over 60 years until 1999 when banks in the U.S. pressured the government for its repeal. Later financial crises led to laws created by the banks that made the long-term stability of the U.S. dollar unlikely.

However, greater economic reform is required than reinstating the Glass-Steagall act, which limited the role of commercial banks. Central banks should also be limited to the role of an economic referee engaged in managing the money supply, servicing banks, and regulating foreign exchange. This would eliminate conflicts of interest associated with central bank lending, buying and selling securities and assets, storing reserves, and charging interest that debt finances the economy. A separation of government from the economy parallel to the separation of church and state would dramatically reduce the control of government by the banking sector and the temptation of governments to create funny money to finance wars.

References
ISBN links support NWE through referral fees

  1. Mishkin, Frederic S. (2007). The Economics of Money, Banking, and Financial Markets, Alternate, Boston: Addison Wesley. ISBN 978-0-321-42177-7. 
  2. What Is Money? {{#invoke:webarchive|webarchive}} By John N. Smithin. Retrieved July-17-09.
  3. money : The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics.
  4. 4.0 4.1 Mankiw, N. Gregory (2007). "2", Macroeconomics, 6th, New York: Worth Publishers, 22–32. ISBN 978-0-7167-6213-3. 
  5. The three primary spheres of society are based on three spontaneous orders that evolve in any human community—language, money, and law. James U. Blanchard III and F. A. Hayek, “Exclusive Interview with F.A. Hayek,” Cato Institute Policy Report, May-June 1984. https://www.cato.org/policy-report/may/june-1984/exclusive-interview-fa-hayek#
  6. Hayek argues that it is a natural "spontaneous" social instituion. James U. Blanchard III and F. A. Hayek, “Exclusive Interview with F.A. Hayek,” Cato Institute Policy Report, May-June 1984. https://www.cato.org/policy-report/may/june-1984/exclusive-interview-fa-hayek#
  7. What is Debt? – An Interview with Economic Anthropologist David Graeber. Naked Capitalism (2011-08-26).
  8. David Graeber: Debt: The First 5000 Years, Melville 2011. Cf. review {{#invoke:webarchive|webarchive}}
  9. David Graeber (2001). Toward an anthropological theory of value: the false coin of our own dreams. Palgrave Macmillan, 153–154. ISBN 978-0-312-24045-5. 
  10. Kramer, History Begins at Sumer, pp. 52–55.
  11. Herodotus. Histories, I, 94
  12. Goldsborough, Reid (2003-10-02). World's First Coin. rg.ancients.info.
  13. Moshenskyi, Sergii (2008). History of the weksel: Bill of exchange and promissory note. ISBN 978-1-4363-0694-2. 
  14. Marco Polo (1818). The Travels of Marco Polo, a Venetian, in the Thirteenth Century: Being a Description, by that Early Traveller, of Remarkable Places and Things, in the Eastern Parts of the World, 353–355. 
  15. Gordon L. Anderson, Integral Society: Social Institutions and Individual Sovereignty (St. Paul, MN: Paragon House, 2023), pp. 113-115.
  16. Stephen Quinn and William Roberds, “Death of a Reserve Currency,” International Journal of Central Banking, December 2016, pp. 63-103.
  17. (2012) Modern money theory: a primer on macroeconomics for sovereign monetary systems. Houndmills, Basingstoke, Hampshire: Palgrave Macmillan, 45–50. ISBN 978-0230368897. 
  18. Milnes, Alfred (1919). The economic foundations of reconstruction. Macdonald and Evans. 
  19. Dwivedi, DN (2005). Macroeconomics: Theory and Policy. Tata McGraw-Hill. 
  20. Krugman, Paul & Wells, Robin, Economics, Worth Publishers, New York (2006)
  21. (2005) "7", Macroeconomics, 5th, Pearson, 266–269. ISBN 978-0-201-32789-2. 
  22. 22.0 22.1 T.H. Greco. Money: Understanding and Creating Alternatives to Legal Tender, White River Junction, Vt: Chelsea Green Publishing (2001). ISBN 1-890132-37-3
  23. Functions of Money (2017-10-11).
  24. What is Money?. International Monetary Fund.
  25. Money. Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas.
  26. (2006) The Little Money Book. The Disinformation Company. ISBN 978-1-932857-26-9. 
  27. History of Money.
  28. Bernstein, Peter, A Primer on Money and Banking, and Gold, Wiley, 2008 edition, pp. 29–39
  29. Mises, Ludwig von. The Theory of Money and Credit, (Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Fund, Inc., 1981), trans. H. E. Batson. Ch.3 Part One: The Nature of Money, Chapter 3: The Various Kinds of Money, Section 3: Commodity Money, Credit Money, and Fiat Money, Paragraph 25.
  30. Jevons, William Stanley (1875). "XVI: Representative Money", Money and the Mechanism of Exchange. ISBN 978-1-59605-260-4. 
  31. Deardorff, Prof. Alan V. (2008). Deardorff's Glossary of International Economics. Department of Economics, University of Michigan.
  32. Black, Henry Campbell (1910). A Law Dictionary Containing Definitions Of The Terms And Phrases Of American And English Jurisprudence, Ancient And Modern, p. 494. West Publishing Co. Black’s Law Dictionary defines the word "fiat" to mean "a short order or warrant of a Judge or magistrate directing some act to be done; an authority issuing from some competent source for the doing of some legal act"
  33. usmiNT.gov . Retrieved July-18-09.
  34. Tom Bethell. "Crazy as a Gold Bug", New York, New York Media, 1980-02-04, p. 34. Retrieved July-18-09
  35. Shredded & Mutilated: Mutilated Currency, Bureau of Engraving and Printing. Retrieved 2007-05-09.
  36. Banaji, Jairus (2007). Islam, the Mediterranean and the Rise of Capitalism. Historical Materialism 15 (1): 47–74.
  37. 37.0 37.1 Labib, Subhi Y. (March 1969). Capitalism in Medieval Islam. The Journal of Economic History 29 (1): 79–86.
  38. (2003) Economics: Principles in Action. Upper Saddle River, New Jersey: Pearson Prentice Hall. ISBN 978-0-13-063085-8. 
  39. The Bank Credit Analysis Handbook: A Guide for Analysts, Bankers, and Investors by Jonathan Golin. Publisher: John Wiley & Sons (2001). ISBN 978-0-471-84217-0
  40. Economic Definitions.
  41. How Currency Works (2 September 2003).
  42. Eveleth, Rose. The truth about the death of cash.
  43. Wallace, Benjamin. "The Rise and Fall of Bitcoin", Wired, 23 November 2011.
  44. The Federal Reserve. 'Monetary Policy and the Economy". (PDF) Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, (2005-07-05). Retrieved 2007-05-15.
  45. Gordon L. Anderson, Integral Society: Social Institutions and Individual Sovereignty (St. Paul, MN: Paragon House, 2023), p. 119.
  46. (1971) Monetary History of the United States, 1867–1960. Princeton, N.J: Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0-691-00354-2. 
  47. (1997) Money and Macroeconomics: The Selected Essays of David Laidler (Economists of the Twentieth Century). Edward Elgar Publishing. ISBN 978-1-85898-596-1. 
  48. A Case for the World's Oldest Coin.
  49. (2019)The International Monetary and Financial System. Annual Review of Economics 11 (1): 859–893.
  50. Counterfeiting statistics for several currencies. Itsamoneything.com (2012-06-09).
  51. Friedrich A. Hayek. Interview by James U. Blanchard III, May 1, 1984. Cato Institute Policy Report May/June 1984. https://www.cato.org/policy-report/may/june-1984/exclusive-interview-fa-hayek#.

Further reading

  • Chown, John F. A History of Money: from AD 800 (Psychology Press, 1994).
  • Davies, Glyn, and Duncan Connors. A History of Money (4th ed. U of Wales Press, 2016) excerpt .
  • Ferguson, Niall. The Ascent of Money: A Financial History of the World (2009) excerpt
  • Keen, Steve (February 2015). "What Is Money and How Is It Created?" argues, "Banks create money by issuing a loan to a borrower; they record the loan as an asset, and the money they deposit in the borrower’s account as a liability. This, in one way, is no different to the way the Federal Reserve creates money ... money is simply a third party’s promise to pay which we accept as full payment in exchange for goods. The two main third parties whose promises we accept are the government and the banks ... money ... is not backed by anything physical, and instead relies on trust. Of course, that trust can be abused ... we continue to ignore the main game: what the banks do (for good and for ill) that really drives the economy." Forbes
  • Kuroda, Akinobu. A Global History of Money (Routledge, 2020). excerpt
  • Hartman, Mitchell, "How Much Money Is There in the World?", Marketplace, American Public Media, October 30, 2017.
  • Lanchester, John, "The Invention of Money: How the heresies of two bankers became the basis of our modern economy", The New Yorker, 5 & 12 August 2019, pp. 28–31.
  • Weatherford, Jack. The history of money (2009). by a cultural anthropologist. excerpt

Credits

New World Encyclopedia writers and editors rewrote and completed the Wikipedia article in accordance with New World Encyclopedia standards. This article abides by terms of the Creative Commons CC-by-sa 3.0 License (CC-by-sa), which may be used and disseminated with proper attribution. Credit is due under the terms of this license that can reference both the New World Encyclopedia contributors and the selfless volunteer contributors of the Wikimedia Foundation. To cite this article click here for a list of acceptable citing formats.The history of earlier contributions by wikipedians is accessible to researchers here:

The history of this article since it was imported to New World Encyclopedia:

Note: Some restrictions may apply to use of individual images which are separately licensed.