Difference between revisions of "Value added tax" - New World Encyclopedia

From New World Encyclopedia
(Started)
 
(105 intermediate revisions by 8 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{Claimed}}{{Started}}
+
{{Copyedited}}{{Images OK}}{{Submitted}}{{Approved}}
 
[[Category:Politics and social sciences]]
 
[[Category:Politics and social sciences]]
 
[[Category:Economics]]
 
[[Category:Economics]]
 +
{{Taxation}}
 +
'''The Value Added Tax''' ('''VAT''') is a form of [[consumption tax]] that taxes all [[business]] [[profit]] and [[Labour (economics)|labor]]. The tax is levied on the value added to the product at each stage of its [[manufacturing]] cycle as well as the [[price]] paid by the final consumer. Commonly, the seller at each stage subtracts the sum of taxes paid on items purchased from the sum of taxes collected on items sold; the net tax liability is the difference between tax collected and tax paid. The cost of materials, subcomponents, tools, equipment, facilities, supplies, and so forth, and any services purchased from other businesses, are not retaxed under the VAT. Those purchases would have already been subjected to the VAT by the supplying businesses.
  
'''Value added tax''' ('''VAT'''), or '''goods and services tax''' ('''GST'''), is [[tax]] on exchanges. It is levied on the added value that results from each exchange. It differs from a [[sales tax]] because a sales tax is levied on the total value of the exchange. For this reason, a VAT is neutral with respect to the number of passages that there are between the producer and the final consumer.  A VAT is an [[indirect tax]], in that the tax is collected from someone other than the person who actually bears the cost of the tax (namely the seller rather than the consumer). To avoid double taxation on final consumption, exports (which by definition, are ''consumed'' abroad) are usually not subject to VAT and VAT charged under such circumstances is usually refundable.
+
The VAT was first adopted in [[France]] in 1954. By the end of the twentieth century it had been adopted throughout the [[European Union]] and in many countries in [[Africa]], [[Asia]], and [[South America]]. Notably, the [[United States]] and [[Canada]] did not follow suit.
  
The VAT was invented by a French economist in 1954. [[Maurice Lauré]], joint director of the French tax authority, the ''Direction générale des impôts'', as ''taxe sur la valeur ajoutée'' ([[:fr:Taxe sur la valeur ajoutée|TVA]] in [[French language|French]]) was first to introduce VAT with effect from 10 April 1954 for large businesses, and extended over time to all business sectors. In [[France]], it is the most important source of state finance, accounting for approximately 45% of state revenues.
+
The burden of VAT, like other consumption taxes, tends to be passed on to the consumer. Additionally, since this is a [[regressive tax]], lower income people have the greatest burden. To offset this, necessities are often taxed at a lower rate than luxury items. Advocates of the VAT contend that it is an efficient method of raising revenue, and would permit concomitant reductions in [[income tax]]. Opponents argue that, as a regressive tax, it puts too much burden on those who are least able to afford it.
 +
{{toc}}
 +
It is only when human nature changes from selfishness to caring for others and society as a whole that the problems inherent in taxation can be resolved, both by those designing the system and by those paying and collecting the taxes.
  
Personal end-consumers of products, consumers and services cannot recover VAT on purchases, but businesses are able to recover VAT on the materials and services that they buy to make further supplies or services directly or indirectly sold to end-users. In this way, the total tax levied at each stage in the economic chain of supply is a constant fraction of the value added by a business to its products, and most of the cost of collecting the tax is borne by business, rather than by the state. VAT was invented because very high sales taxes and tariffs encourage cheating and smuggling. It has been criticized on the grounds that it is a [[regressive tax]].
+
==Definition==
 +
'''Value added tax''' (usually shortened to '''VAT''') is a levy on the amount a [[business]] add to the [[price]] (hence the name "value added") of [[goods (economics)|goods]] during their production and distribution. Since it is a tax on commodities purchased, ultimately for consumption, rather than on the [[income]] of an individual or [[corporation]], it is essentially a [[consumption tax]].
  
==Comparison with a sales tax==
+
The VAT is usually collected by the tax credit method; each firm applies the tax rate to its taxable sales, but is allowed a credit for value-added tax paid on its purchases of goods and services for business use, including the tax paid on purchases of capital equipment under a [[consumption tax|consumption]]-type value-added tax. As a result, the only tax for which no credit would be allowed would be that collected on sales made to households, rather than to businesses.
VAT differs from a conventional [[sales tax]] in that VAT is levied on ''every'' business as a ''fraction'' of the price of each taxable sale they make, but they are in turn reimbursed VAT on their purchases, so the VAT is applied to the value added to the goods at each stage of production.  
 
  
Sales taxes are normally only charged on final sales to consumers: because of reimbursement, VAT has the same overall economic effect on final prices. The main difference is the extra accounting required by those in the middle of the supply chain; this disadvantage of VAT is balanced by application of the same tax to each member of the production chain regardless of its position in it and the position of its customers, reducing the effort required to check and certify their status. When the VAT has few, if any exemptions such as with [[Goods and Services Tax (New Zealand)|GST in New Zealand]], payment of VAT is even simpler.
+
Since the sum of the values added at all stages in the production and distribution of a good are equal to the retail selling price of the good, the revenue base of a retail sales tax and a value-added tax with the same coverage are theoretically identical, and a given tax rate will yield the same amount of tax revenue under either approach and under equal conditions of implementation, in other words, no exceptions or exemptions.
  
A general economic idea is that if sales taxes exceed 10%, people start engaging in widespread tax evading activity (like buying over the Internet, pretending to be a business, buying at wholesale, buying products through an employer etc.) On the other hand, total VAT rates can rise above 10% without widespread evasion because of the novel collection mechanism.{{Fact|date=February 2007}} However because of its particular mechanism of collection, VAT becomes quite easily the target of specific frauds like [[Missing trader fraud|carousel fraud]] which can be very expensive in terms of loss of tax incomes for states.
+
==History==
 +
The VAT was invented by a French economist in 1954. [[Maurice Lauré]], joint director of the French tax authority, the ''Direction générale des impôts'', as ''taxe sur la valeur ajoutée'' ([[:fr:Taxe sur la valeur ajoutée|TVA]] in [[French language|French]]) was first to introduce VAT with effect from April 10, 1954, for large businesses, and extended over time to all business sectors. In [[France]], it is the most important source of state finance, accounting for approximately 45 percent of state revenues.
 +
[[West Germany]] adopted VAT in 1968, and subsequently most other [[Western Europe]]an countries also implemented some form of VAT. Many countries in [[Africa]], [[Asia]], and [[South America]] have also followed suit. Although the [[United States]] as a whole has not, the state of [[Michigan]] has used a value added tax.  
  
=== Collection Mechanism ===
+
Today, all members of the [[European Union]] are required to implement VAT.
The standard way to implement a VAT is to say a business owes some percentage on the price of the product minus all taxes previously paid on the good. If VAT rates were 10%, an orange juice maker would pay 10% of the $5 per gallon price ($0.50) minus taxes previously paid by the orange farmer (maybe $0.20). In this example, the orange juice maker would have a $0.30 tax liability. Each business has a strong incentive for its suppliers to pay their taxes, allowing VAT rates to be higher with less tax evasion than a retail sales tax. </sup>
 
  
===Example===
+
==How VAT works==
Consider the manufacture and sale of any item, which in this case we will call a [[Placeholder name|widget]].  
+
VAT that is charged by a [[business]] and paid by its customers is known as output VAT (that is, VAT on its output supplies). VAT that is paid by a business to other businesses on the supplies that it receives is known as input VAT (that is, VAT on its input supplies). A business is generally able to recover input VAT to the extent that the input VAT is attributable to (that is, used to make) its taxable outputs. Input VAT is recovered by setting it against the output VAT for which the business is required to account to the government, or, if there is an excess, by claiming a repayment from the government.
  
====Without any sales tax====
+
Under the [[European Union]] system of VAT, where a person carrying on an economic activity supplies [[good (economics)|goods]] and [[service (economics)|services]] to another person, and the value of the supplies passes financial limits, the supplier is required to register with the local taxation authorities and charge its customers, and account to the local taxation authority for VAT (although the [[price]] may be inclusive of VAT, so VAT is included as part of the agreed price, or exclusive of VAT, so VAT is payable in addition to the agreed price).
* A widget manufacturer spends $1 on raw materials and uses them to make a widget.
 
* The widget is sold wholesale to a widget retailer for $1.20, making a profit of $0.20.
 
* The widget retailer then sells the widget to a widget consumer for $1.50, making a profit of $0.30
 
  
====With a North American (Canadian Provincial and U.S. State) sales tax====
+
Different rates of VAT apply in different EU member states. The minimum standard rate of VAT throughout the EU is 15 percent, although reduced rates of VAT, as low as five percent, are applied in various states on various sorts of supply (for example, domestic fuel and power in the UK). The maximum rate in the EU is 25 percent.
With a 10% sales tax:
 
* The manufacturer pays $1.00 for the raw materials, certifying it is not a final consumer.
 
* The manufacturer charges the retailer $1.20, checking that the retailer is not a consumer, leaving the same profit of $0.20.
 
* The retailer charges the consumer $1.65 ($1.50 + 10%) and pays the government $0.15, leaving the same profit of $0.30.
 
So the consumer has paid 10% ($0.15) extra, compared to the no taxation scheme, and the government has collected this amount in taxation. The retailers have not lost anything directly to the tax, but they do have the extra paperwork to do so that they correctly pass on to the government the sales tax they collect. Suppliers and manufacturers have the administrative burden of supplying correct certifications, and checking that their customers (retailers) aren't consumers.
 
  
====With a value added tax====
+
The Sixth VAT Directive requires certain goods and services to be exempt from VAT (for example, postal services, medical care, lending, insurance, betting), and certain other goods and services to be exempt from VAT but subject to the ability of an EU member state to opt to charge VAT on those supplies (such as land and certain financial services). Input VAT that is attributable to exempt supplies is not recoverable, although a business can increase its prices so the customer effectively bears the cost of the 'sticking' VAT (the effective rate will be lower than the headline rate and depend on the balance between previously taxed input and labor at the exempt stage).
With a 10% VAT:
 
* The manufacturer pays $1.10 ($1 + 10%) for the raw materials, and the seller of the raw materials pays the government $0.10.
 
* The manufacturer charges the retailer $1.32 ($1.20 + $1.20x10%) and pays the government $0.02 ($0.12 ''minus'' $0.10), leaving the same profit of $0.20.
 
* The retailer charges the consumer $1.65 ($1.50 + $1.50x10%) and pays the government $0.03 ($0.15 ''minus'' $0.12), leaving the same profit of $0.30.
 
So the consumer has paid 10% ($0.15) extra, compared to the no taxation scheme, and the government has collected this amount in taxation. The businesses have not lost anything directly to the tax, but they do have the extra paperwork to do so that they correctly pass on to the government the difference between what they collect in VAT (output VAT, an 11th of their income) and what they spend in VAT (input VAT, an 11th of their expenditure).
 
  
Note that in each case the VAT paid is equal to 10% of the profit, or 'value added'.
+
Finally, some goods and services are "zero-rated." The zero-rate is a positive rate of tax calculated at zero percent. Supplies subject to the zero-rate are still "taxable supplies," in other words, they have VAT charged on them. In the UK, examples include most food, books, drugs, and certain kinds of transport. The zero-rate is not featured in the EU Sixth Directive as it was intended that the minimum VAT rate throughout Europe would be five percent. However, zero-rating remains in some member states, most notably the UK, as a legacy of pre-EU legislation. These member states have been granted a derogation (partial revocation of the law) to continue existing zero-rating but cannot add new goods or services. The UK also exempts or lowers the rate on some products depending on situation; for example [[milk]] products are exempt from VAT, but a milk drink served in a restaurant is subject to VAT. Some products such as feminine hygiene products and baby products are charged at five percent VAT along with domestic fuel.
  
The advantage of the VAT system over the sales tax system is that businesses cannot hide consumption (such as wasted materials) by certifying it is not a consumer.
+
When goods are imported into the EU from other states, VAT is generally charged at the border, at the same time as [[customs duty]]. "Acquisition" VAT is payable when goods are acquired in one EU member state from another EU member state (this is done not at the border but through an accounting mechanism). EU businesses are often required to charge themselves VAT under the reverse charge mechanism where services are received from another member state or from outside of the EU.
  
====Limitations to example and VAT====
+
Businesses can be required to register for VAT in EU member states, other than the one in which they are based, if they supply goods via mail order to those states, over a certain threshold. Businesses that are established in one member state but which receive supplies in another member state may be able to reclaim VAT charged in the second state under the provisions of the Eighth VAT Directive (Directive 79/1072/EC). To do so, businesses have a value added tax identification number. A similar directive, the Thirteenth VAT Directive (Directive 86/560/EC), also allows businesses established outside the EU to recover VAT under certain circumstances.
In the above example, we assumed that the same number of widgets were made and sold both before and after the introduction of the tax. This is not true in real life.
 
  
The fundamentals of [[supply and demand]] suggest that any tax raises the cost of transaction for ''someone'', whether it is the seller or purchaser. In raising the cost, either the [[demand curve]] shifts leftward, or the [[supply curve]] shifts upward. The two are functionally equivalent. Consequently, the quantity of a good purchased, and/or the price for which it is sold, decrease.
+
==Differences between VAT and (retail) sales tax==
  
This shift in supply and demand is not incorporated into the above example, for simplicity and because these effects are different for every type of good. The above example assumes the tax is ''non-distortionary''.
+
Despite its multistage character, explained in the above section a value-added tax is very much like a retail [[sales tax]] in that it is a tax on expenditures by consumers or, in other words, it is just another type of [[consumption tax]]. Since the sum of the values added at all stages in the production and distribution of a good are equal to the retail selling price of the good, the revenue base of a retail sales tax and a value-added tax with the same coverage are theoretically identical, and a given tax rate will yield the same amount of tax revenue under either approach. There are, however, significant differences in the impacts of different types of consumption tax.
  
A VAT, like most taxes, distorts what would have happened without it. Because the price for ''someone'' rises, the quantity of goods traded decreases. Correspondingly, some people are ''worse'' off by ''more'' than the government is made ''better'' off by tax income . That is, more is lost due to supply and demand shifts than is gained in tax. This is known as a [[deadweight loss]]. The income lost by the economy is greater than the government's income; the tax is inefficient. The entire amount of the government's income (the tax revenue) may not be a deadweight drag, if the tax revenue is used for productive spending or has positive externalities - in other words, governments may do more than simply ''consume'' the tax income. While distortions occur, consumption taxes like VAT are often considered superior because they distort incentives to invest, save and work ''less'' than most other types of taxation - in other words, a VAT discourages consumption rather than production. However they are still considered inferior to taxes like [[land value tax]] which neither cause deadweight losses nor distort incentives.
+
'''Retail sales tax''', the familiar percentage tax on retail sales, is one type of consumption tax. In this tax, a simple percentage is added to the retail price of goods when sold to the consumer, but not when sold for resale to a retailer, or to a manufacturer as parts in production of a new commodity. Sales tax does not distort the production structure as would the VAT, and it would not skew individual preferences as would specific [[excise tax]]es (Rothbard 1994).
  
<div style="float:center; width:300px; padding:2px; margin-left:1em; text-align:center">
+
'''The VAT consumption tax''', standard in [[Europe]] and other parts of the world, imposes a hierarchical tax on the "value added" by each firm and business. This would tend to distort the structure of business. For one thing, there would be an incentive for uneconomic vertical integration, since the fewer the number of times a sale takes place, the fewer the imposed taxes. Also, as has happened in European countries with experience of the VAT, a flourishing industry may arise in issuing phony vouchers, so that businesses can over-inflate their alleged expenditures, and reduce their reported value added.
[[Image:TaxWithTax.svg|200px]]<br />''A Supply-Demand Analysis of a Taxed Market''<br align="center"></div>
 
In the above diagram,  
 
  
'''Deadweight loss''': the area of the triangle formed by the tax income box, the original supply curve, and the demand curve
+
A sales tax, other things being equal, seems to be both simpler, less distorting of resources, and enormously less [[bureaucracy|bureaucratic]] than the VAT. Indeed the VAT seems to have no clear advantage over the sales tax, except of course, if multiplying bureaucracy and bureaucratic power is considered a benefit (Rothbard 1994).
 
'''Government's tax income''': the grey area
 
  
'''Total [[consumer surplus]] after the shift''': the green area
+
Another way of looking at this issue is this. VAT differs from a conventional sales tax in that VAT is levied on every business as a fraction of the price of each taxable sale they make, but they are in turn reimbursed VAT on their purchases, so the VAT is applied to the value added to the goods at each stage of production (Sharma 2005: 916; quoted in Muller 2007:64).
  
'''Total [[producer surplus]] after the shift''': the yellow area
+
Sales taxes are normally only charged on final sales to consumers: because of reimbursement, VAT has the same overall economic effect on final prices. The main difference is the extra accounting required by those in the middle of the supply chain; this disadvantage of VAT is balanced by application of the same tax to each member of the production chain regardless of its position in it and the position of its customers, reducing the effort required to check and certify their status. When the VAT has few, if any exemptions such as with GST in [[New Zealand]], payment of VAT is even simpler.
  
==Criticisms==
+
Generally speaking, if sales taxes exceed ten percent, people start engaging in widespread tax evasion activities (like buying over the [[Internet]], pretending to be a business, buying at wholesale, buying products through an employer, and so forth). On the other hand, total VAT rates can rise above ten percent without widespread evasion because of the novel collection mechanism, which not only keeps the tax liability of the final consumer at a lower level but also makes such evasions impossible since all purchases are taxed, including wholesale and so on. However because of its particular mechanism of collection, VAT becomes quite easily the target of specific [[fraud]]s.
The "value added tax" has been criticized as the burden of it relies on personal end-consumers of products and is therefore a [[regressive tax]] (the poor pay more, in comparison, than the rich). However, this calculation is derived when the tax paid is divided not by the tax base (the amount spent) but by income, which is argued to create an arbitrary relationship.  The tax rate itself is proportional with higher income people paying more tax but at the same rate as they consume more.  If a value added tax is to be related to income, then the unspent income can be treated as deferred (spending savings at a later point in time), at which time it is taxed creating a [[proportional tax]] using an income base. Such taxes can have a [[progressive tax|progressive]] effect on the [[effective tax rate]] of consumption by using exemptions, rebates, or credits.
 
  
Revenues from a value added tax are frequently lower than expected because they are difficult and costly to administer and collect.{{dubious}} In many countries, however, where collection of personal income taxes and corporate profit taxes has been historically weak, VAT collection has been more successful than other types of taxes. VAT has become more important in many jurisdictions as tariff levels have fallen worldwide due to trade liberalisation, as VAT has essentially replaced lost tariff revenues. Whether the costs and distortions of value added taxes are lower than the economic inefficiencies and enforcement issues (e.g. smuggling) from high import tariffs is debated, but theory suggests value added taxes are far more efficient.
+
==Collection Mechanism==
  
Due to the fact that exports are generally zero-rated (and VAT refunded or offset against other taxes), this is often where VAT fraud occurs. In sectors or countries where VAT fraud is prevalent, attempts by authorities to control fraud may have unintended consequences, and raise costs for ''honest'' companies. This problem is also true of other types of taxation, however.
+
The standard way to implement a VAT is to say a business owes some percentage on the price of the product minus all taxes previously paid on the good. If VAT rates were ten percent, an [[orange juice]] maker would pay ten percent of the $5 per gallon price ($0.50) minus taxes previously paid by the [[Orange (fruit)|orange]] farmer (say $0.20). In this example, the orange juice maker would have a $0.30 tax liability. Each business has a strong incentive for its suppliers to pay their taxes, allowing VAT rates to be higher with less tax evasion than a retail sales tax.
  
Certain industries (small-scale services, for example) tend to have more VAT avoidance, particularly where cash transactions predominate, and VAT may be criticized for encouraging this. From the perspective of government, however, VAT may be preferable because it captures at least some of the value-added. For example, a carpenter may offer to provide services ''for cash'' (i.e. without a receipt, and without VAT) to a homeowner, who usually cannot claim input VAT back. The homeowner will hence bear lower costs and the carpenter may be able to avoid other taxes (profit or payroll taxes). The government, however, may still receive VAT for various other inputs (lumber, paint, gasoline, tools, etc) sold to the carpenter, who would be unable to reclaim the VAT on these inputs. While the total tax receipts may be lower ''compared to full compliance,'' it may not be lower than under other feasible taxation systems.
+
Consider the manufacture and sale of any item, which in this case we will call a widget.
  
In Europe, the main source of problems is called 'carousel' fraud.  Large quantities of valuable goods (often microchips or mobile phones) are transported from one member state to the other. During these transactions, some companies owe VAT, other acquire a right to reclaim VAT. The first companies, called 'missing traders' go bankrupt without paying.  The second group of companies can 'pump' money straight out of the national treasuries.
+
;(1) Without any sales tax
 +
*A widget manufacturer spends $1 on raw materials and uses them to make a widget.
 +
*The widget is sold wholesale to a widget retailer for $1.20, making a profit of $0.20.
 +
*The widget retailer then sells the widget to a widget consumer for $1.50, making a profit of $0.30
  
This kind of fraud originated in the 1970s in the Benelux-countries. Today, the British treasury is the main victim. The British judicial system is considered by such criminals as the weakest in the EU. Collaboration with other member states is poor, and the trial-by-jury system makes convictions difficult.
+
;(2) With a ten percent sales tax
 +
*The manufacturer pays $1.00 for the raw materials, certifying it is not a final consumer.
 +
*The manufacturer charges the retailer $1.20, checking that the retailer is not a consumer, leaving the same profit of $0.20.  
 +
*The retailer charges the consumer $1.65 ($1.50 + ten percent) and pays the government $0.15, leaving the same profit of $0.30.  
  
==VAT systems==
+
So the consumer has paid ten percent ($0.15) extra, compared to the no taxation scheme, and the government has collected this amount in taxation. The retailers have not lost anything directly to the tax, but they do have the extra paperwork to do so that they correctly pass on to the government the sales tax they collect. Suppliers and manufacturers have the administrative burden of supplying correct certifications, and checking that their customers (retailers) are not consumers.
===European Union===
 
A common VAT system is compulsory for [[European Union member states|member states]] of the [[European Union]]. The EU VAT system is imposed by a series of [[European Union directive]]s, the most important of which is the Sixth VAT Directive (Directive 77/388/EC). Nevertheless, some member states have negotiated variable rates ([[Madeira]] in [[Portugal]]) or VAT exemption for regions or territories. The regions below fall out of the scope of EU VAT:<ref>[http://www.vat.gov.mt/docs/vat_comments_new_act_1_march_2004.pdf VAT Comments (Malta)]</ref>
 
  
* [[Åland Islands]] ([[Finland]])
+
;(3) With a ten percent VAT
* [[Heligoland]] island, [[Büsingen]] territory ([[Germany]])
+
*The manufacturer pays $1.10 ($1 + ten percent) for the raw materials, and the seller of the raw materials pays the government $0.10.
* [[Guadeloupe]], [[Martinique]], [[French Guiana]], [[Réunion]] ([[France]])
+
*The manufacturer charges the retailer $1.32 ($1.20 + $1.20 x ten percent) and pays the government $0.02 ($0.12 minus $0.10), leaving the same profit of $0.20.
* [[Mount Athos]] ([[Greece]])
+
*The retailer charges the consumer $1.65 ($1.50 + $1.50 x ten percent) and pays the government $0.03 ($0.15 minus $0.12), leaving the same profit of $0.30.
* [[Ceuta]], [[Melilla]], [[The Canary Islands]] ([[Spain]])
 
* [[Livigno]], [[Campione d'Italia]], [[Lake Lugano]] ([[Italy]])
 
* [[Gibraltar]], [[The Channel Islands]] ([[United Kingdom]])
 
  
Under the EU system of VAT, where a person carrying on an economic activity supplies goods and services to another person, and the value of the supplies passes financial limits, the supplier is required to register with the local taxation authorities and charge its customers, and account to the local taxation authority for VAT (although the price may be ''inclusive'' of VAT, so VAT is included as part of the agreed price, or ''exclusive'' of VAT, so VAT is payable in addition to the agreed price).
+
So the consumer has paid ten percent ($0.15) extra, compared to the no taxation scheme, and the government has collected this amount in taxation. The businesses have not lost anything directly to the tax, but they do have the extra paperwork to do so that they correctly pass on to the government the difference between what they collect in VAT (output VAT, an 11th of their income) and what they spend in VAT (input VAT, an 11th of their expenditure).
  
VAT that is charged by a business and paid by its customers is known as ''output'' VAT (that is, VAT on its output supplies). VAT that is paid by a business to other businesses on the supplies that it receives is known as ''input'' VAT (that is, VAT on its input supplies). A business is generally able to recover input VAT to the extent that the input VAT is attributable to (that is, used to make) its taxable outputs. Input VAT is recovered by setting it against the output VAT for which the business is required to account to the government, or, if there is an excess, by claiming a repayment from the government.  
+
Note that in each case the VAT paid is equal to ten percent of the profit, or "value added."
  
Different rates of VAT apply in different EU member states. The minimum standard rate of VAT throughout the EU is 15%, although reduced rates of VAT, as low as 5%, are applied in various states on various sorts of supply (for example, domestic fuel and power in the UK). The maximum rate in the EU is 25%.
+
The advantage of the VAT system over the sales tax system is that businesses cannot hide consumption (such as wasted materials) by certifying it is not a consumer.
  
The Sixth VAT Directive requires certain goods and services to be exempt from VAT (for example, postal services, medical care, lending, insurance, betting), and certain other goods and services to be exempt from VAT but subject to the ability of an EU member state to opt to charge VAT on those supplies (such as land and certain financial services). Input VAT that is attributable to exempt supplies is not recoverable, although a business can increase its prices so the customer effectively bears the cost of the 'sticking' VAT (the effective rate will be lower than the headline rate and depend on the balance between previously taxed input and labour at the exempt stage).
+
==Disadvantages of VAT==
 +
===Impact on supply and demand===
 +
In the above example, it was assumed that the same number of widgets were made and sold both before and after the introduction of the tax. This is not true in real life. The fundamentals of [[supply and demand]] suggest that any tax raises the cost of transaction for someone, whether it is the seller or purchaser. In raising the cost, either the demand curve shifts leftward, or the supply curve shifts upward. The two are functionally equivalent. Consequently, the quantity of a good purchased, and/or the price for which it is sold, decrease. This shift in supply and demand is not incorporated into the above example, for simplicity and because these effects are different for every type of good. The widget example assumes the tax is non-distortionary.
  
Finally, some goods and services are "zero-rated." The zero-rate is a positive rate of tax calculated at 0%. Supplies subject to the zero-rate are still "taxable supplies," i.e. they have VAT charged on them. In the UK, examples include most food, books, drugs, and certain kinds of transport. The zero-rate is not featured in the EU Sixth Directive as it was intended that the minimum VAT rate throughout Europe would be 5%. However, zero-rating remains in some Member States, most notably the UK, as a legacy of pre-EU legislation. These Member States have been granted a derogation to continue existing zero-rating but cannot add new goods or services.
+
<div style="float:center; width:300px; padding:2px; margin-left:1em; text-align:center">
The UK also exempts or lowers the rate on some products depending on situation; for example milk products are exempt from VAT, but if you go into a restaurant and drink a milk drink it is VAT-able. Some products such as feminine hygiene products and baby products (nappies etc) are charged at 5% VAT along with domestic fuel.
+
[[Image:TaxWithTax.svg|200px]]<br />''A Supply-Demand Analysis of a Taxed Market''<br align="center"></div>
 +
In the above diagram,  
  
When goods are [[import]]ed into the EU from other states, VAT is generally charged at the [[border]], at the same time as [[customs duty]]. "Acquisition" VAT is payable when goods are acquired in one EU member state from another EU member state (this is done not at the border but through an accounting mechanism). EU businesses are often required to charge themselves VAT under the ''reverse charge'' mechanism where services are received from another member state or from outside of the EU.
+
*'''Deadweight loss''': the area of the triangle formed by the tax income box, the original supply curve, and the demand curve
 +
 +
*'''Government's tax income''': the grey rectangle
  
Businesses can be required to register for VAT in EU member states, other than the one in which they are based, if they supply goods via mail order to those states, over a certain threshold. Businesses that are established in one member state but which receive supplies in another member state may be able to reclaim VAT charged in the second state under the provisions of the Eighth VAT Directive (Directive 79/1072/EC). To do so, businesses have a [[value added tax identification number]]. A similar directive, the Thirteenth VAT Directive (Directive 86/560/EC), also allows businesses established outside the EU to recover VAT in certain circumstances.
+
*'''Total [[consumer surplus]] after the shift''': the green area
  
Following changes introduced on July 1, 2003, (under Directive 2002/38/EC), non-EU businesses providing digital [[electronic commerce]] and entertainment products and services to EU countries are also required to register with the tax authorities in the relevant EU member state, and to collect VAT on their sales at the appropriate rate, according to the location of the purchaser. Alternatively, under a special scheme, non-EU businesses may register and account for VAT on only one EU member state. This produces distortions as the rate of VAT is that of the member state of registration, not where the customer is located, and an alternative approach is therefore under negotiation, whereby VAT is charged at the rate of the member state where the purchaser is located.
+
*'''Total [[producer surplus]] after the shift''': the yellow area
  
The differences between different rates of VAT was often originally justified by certain products being "luxuries" and thus bearing high rates of VAT, whereas other items were deemed to be "essentials" and thus bearing lower rates of VAT. However, often high rates persisted long after the argument was no longer valid. For instance, [[France]] taxed cars as a luxury product (33%) up into the 1980s, when most of the French households owned one or more cars. Similarly, in the UK, clothing for children is "zero rated" whereas clothing for adults is subject to VAT at the standard rate of 17.5%.
+
A VAT, like most taxes, distorts what would have happened without it. Because the price rises for someone, the quantity of goods traded decreases. Correspondingly, some people are worse off by more than the government is made better off by the tax income. That is, more is lost due to supply and demand shifts than is gained in tax revenue. This is known as a deadweight loss. The income lost by the [[economy]] is greater than the government's income; the tax is inefficient. The entire amount of the government's income (the tax revenue) may not be a deadweight drag, if the tax revenue is used for productive spending or has positive [[externality|externalities]]—in other words, governments may do more than simply consume the tax income.  
  
====Rules on pricing within the EU====
+
While distortions occur with consumption taxes like VAT, they are often considered superior because they distort incentives to invest, save, and work less than most other types of taxation—in other words, a VAT discourages consumption rather than production. However, taxes on consumption still have negative impact, unlike land value tax which neither causes deadweight losses nor distorts incentives.
* Where most of the trade is business-to-consumer, displayed prices must include VAT and VAT must be charged.
 
* Where most of the trade is business-to-business, displayed prices do not have to include VAT. For business transactions the following rules apply:
 
** VAT must be charged if the buyer is in the same country as the seller. The buyer may be able to reclaim the VAT from the tax authorities.
 
** VAT does not need to be charged if the buyer is in a different country. The seller must record the VAT number of the buyer.
 
** Certain EU companies are VAT exempt, these companies must not be charged VAT, regardless of whether they are in the same or different country to the seller.
 
  
===Denmark, Norway, and Sweden (MOMS)===  
+
===Regressivity===
'''MOMS''' ([[Danish Language|Danish]]: ''Meromsætningsafgift'', [[Norwegian language|Norwegian]]: ''merverdiavgift'' (abriviated ''MVA''), [[Swedish language|Swedish]]: ''mervärdesskatt'', earlier ''mervärdesomsättningsskatt'') is a Danish, Norwegian and Swedish [[sales tax]]. MOMS is the Danish, Norwegian and Swedish term for [[Value Added Tax|VAT]]. Like other countries' sales and VAT taxes, MOMS is a [[Regressive tax|regressive]] [[indirect tax]].  
+
A tax is regressive if the average tax rate falls with an increase in income, proportional if the average tax rate is constant, and progressive if the average tax rate rises with income. Simply put, low-income people pay a higher fraction of their income in taxes than wealthier people if the tax is regressive and a lower fraction if the tax is progressive.  
  
In [[Denmark]], VAT is only applied at one level, and is not split into two levels as in other countries (e.g. Germany), where VAT is split into ''VAT for foodstuffs'' and ''VAT for nonfood''. The current percentage in Denmark is 25%. That makes Denmark one of the countries with the highest value added tax, alongside [[Norway]] and [[Sweden]].
+
VAT, as all types of consumption tax, is often criticized as unfair to lower income individuals and families. The regressivity of VAT, or the relatively higher burden of the tax at the lower income levels than at the higher income levels, may be offset by adjustments to [[income tax]] rates, or credits against the income tax. These measures, however, add to the administrative burden of VAT and tend to lead to increases in income taxes, at least for those in higher income brackets.  
  
In [[Norway]], VAT is split into three levels: 25% is the general VAT, 14% (formerly 13%, up on January 1, 2007) for foods and restaurant take-out (food eaten in a restaurant has 25%), 8% for person transport, movie tickets, and hotel stays. Most printed matters are still free of VAT.
+
The regressive effect may also be reduced by taxing necessities at lower rates than luxury items. Again, though, this increases the burden of collection by having multiple rates, as well as leading to [[lobbying]] of various sectors competing for lower tax rates for their goods and services.  
  
In [[Sweden]], VAT is split into three levels: 25% for most goods and services including restaurants bills, 12% for foods and hotel stays (but breakfast at 25%) and 6% for printed matter, cultural services,and transport of private persons. Some services are not taxable for example education of children and adults if public utility, but education is taxable at 25% in case of courses for adults at a private school.  
+
===Expands the cost of government===
 +
Countries with VATs have a much heavier total tax burden than those without VATs. Before the creation of VATs, the burden of taxation in Europe was not that much larger than it was in the United States. However, since the late 1960s, when countries in Europe began to adopt VATs, Europe’s aggregate tax burden has increased by about 50 percent while the U.S. tax burden has remained relatively constant (Bickley 2003).
  
MOMS replaced OMS (Danish "''Omsætningsafgift''," Swedish "''omsättningsskatt''") in 1967, which was a tax applied exclusively for retailers.
+
===Increases income tax rates===
 +
One of the main arguments for the VAT is that it is a less destructive way to raise revenue. This is theoretically true, but irrelevant. In the real world, the VAT has been used as an excuse to increase income taxes as a way to maintain “distributional neutrality.” Indeed, income taxes in Europe today are higher than they were when VATs were implemented.
  
{|class="toccolours" border="1" cellpadding="4" cellspacing="0" style="border-collapse: collapse; margin:1 auto;"
+
===Effect on prices===
|- style="text-align: Center;"
+
Assuming an accommodating monetary policy, a sales tax would almost certainly increase the price level by roughly the percentage it represents of consumption spending. That is, a four percent sales tax that applied to 75 percent of consumption expenditures would increase the general price level by about three percent.
|'''Year'''
 
|'''Tax level'''
 
|'''OMS/MOMS'''
 
<tr><td>1962</td><td>9%</td><td>OMS</td></tr>
 
<tr><td>1967</td><td>10%</td><td>MOMS</td></tr>
 
<tr><td>1968</td><td>12,5%</td><td>MOMS</td></tr>
 
<tr><td>1970</td><td>15%</td><td>MOMS</td></tr>
 
<tr><td>1977</td><td>18%</td><td>MOMS</td></tr>
 
<tr><td>1978</td><td>20.25%</td><td>MOMS</td></tr>
 
<tr><td>1980</td><td>22%</td><td>MOMS</td></tr>
 
<tr><td>1992</td><td>25%</td><td>MOMS</td></tr>
 
|}
 
  
===India===
+
Although this would be a one-time occurrence, not an annual increase, it might cause "ripples" of wage increases, because of cost-of-living adjustments and these could be reflected in further price increases. To the extent the sales tax replaced part of the income tax, there would be little offsetting reduction in prices or wages.
{{section cleanup|July 2006}}
 
In India, VAT replaced [[sales tax]] on 1 April 2005. Of the 21 Indian states, eight did not introduce VAT. [[Haryana]] had already adopted it on 1 April 2004. The "empowered committee" of the basic framework for uniform VAT laws in the states. Due to the federal nature of the Indian constitution, the states do have the power to set their own VAT rate.
 
  
====The Andhra Pradesh experience====
+
===Slows economic growth and destroy jobs===
In the Indian state of [[Andhra Pradesh]], the Andhra Pradesh Value Added Tax Act, 2005 came into force on 1 April 2005 and contains six schedules. Schedule I contains goods generally exempted from tax. Schedule II deals with zero rated transactions like exports and Schedule III contains goods taxable at 1%, namely jewellery made from bullion and precious stones. Goods taxable at 4% are listed under Schedule IV. The majority of foodgrains and goods of national importance, like iron and steel, are listed under this head. Schedule V deals with Standard Rate Goods, taxable at 12.5%. All goods that are not listed elsewhere in the Act fall under this head. The VI Schedule contains goods taxed at special rates, such as some liquor and petroleum products.
+
A VAT undermines [[economic growth]] in two ways. First, it reduces incentives to engage in productive behavior by driving a larger wedge between pre-tax income and post-tax consumption. Second, it facilitates larger government and the concomitant transfer of resources from the productive sector of the [[economy]] to the public sector, reducing jobs in production and diminishing economic efficiency (Engen and Skinner 1992).
  
The Act prescribes threshold limits for VAT registration - dealers with a taxable turnover of over Rs.40.00 lacs, in a tax period of 12 months, are mandatorily registered as VAT dealers. Dealers with a taxable turnover, in a tax period of 12 months, between Rs.5.00 to 40.00 lacs are registered as Turnover Tax (TOT) dealers. While the former category of dealers are eligible for input tax credit, the latter category of dealers are not. A VAT dealer pays tax at the rate specifed in the Schedules. The sales of a TOT dealer are all taxable at 1%. A VAT dealer has to file a monthly return disclosing purchases and sales. A TOT dealer has to file a quarterly return disclosing only sale turnovers. While a VAT dealer can buy goods for business from anywhere in the country, a TOT dealer is barred from buying outside the State of A.P.  
+
==Positive and negative effects of VAT in EU==
 +
The VAT was invented in Europe mainly to facilitate [[trade]], particularly among members of the [[European Union]]. They needed a tax that could be applied at the border on imports and rebated at the border on exports, thus preventing taxes from multiplying every time [[good (economics|good]]s passed through a country. The VAT does this by applying incremental taxes at each stage of production or distribution, with an invoice trail detailing how much tax was embedded in the [[price]] (Bartlett 2005).
  
The Act appears to be the most liberal VAT law in India. It has simplified the registration procedures and provides for across the board input tax credit (with a few exceptions) for business transactions.{{Verify source|date=April 2007}} A unique feature of registration in Andhra Pradesh is the facility of voluntary VAT registration and input tax credit for start-ups.
+
In supporting the VAT, [[Bruce Bartlett]], a senior fellow for the National Center for Policy Analysis, has argued:
 +
<blockquote>This is the best strategy tax economists have ever devised for raising revenue without investing a lot in enforcement and economic incentives. The V.A.T. is a kind of sales tax embedded in the price of goods. ... [T]he tax is largely self-enforcing. And because the tax is applied only to consumption, its impact on incentives is minimal (Bartlett 2006).</blockquote>
 +
 +
But is it self-enforcing? Since VATs continue to enter policy discussions, knowledge of how they have or have not worked in countries that have used them can be helpful. According to such analysis by the ''[[Financial Times]]'', there are two main problems with the VAT in Europe: [[fraud]] and complexity. In an often cited article “Evasion and exemptions erode VAT’s own value added,” the ''Financial Times'' (2006) concluded:
 +
<blockquote>In half a century, value added tax has taken the world by storm... But despite its reach, some are ready to declare it an idea whose time has gone…. VAT fraud has become pervasive and, at least in Europe, the tax is at a watershed. Can it survive in its current form? ...[I]t is in Europe that the weaknesses are at their most glaring. This month the European Commission launched an “in-depth debate” on whether VAT should be modified. ... European VAT is in a mess for two main reasons: its vulnerability to fraud and its complexity. Fraud, evasion and avoidance cost at least one in every 10 euros of the tax collected – roughly double that in other industrialised countries... VAT abuse takes many forms – most commonly the reluctance of traders in the black economy to have anything to do with the tax. But the biggest headache is sophisticated fraud (''Financial Times'' 2006).</blockquote>
  
The Act also provides for transitional relief (TR) for goods on hand as of 1 April 2005. However, these goods ought to have been purchased from registered dealers between 1 April 2005 to 31 March 2006. This is a bold step compared to the 3 months TR provided by several developed countries.
+
The problem lies largely in the refund process:
 +
<blockquote>VAT is normally self-policing: everyone in the supply chain has an incentive to act as tax-collectors as they offset the VAT they pay their suppliers against the VAT they charge their customers. But in some circumstances, notably when exporting goods – which are VAT-free under nearly all national systems – businesses can claim refunds. ... This fraud ... has forced governments to consider drastic remedies. ... Germany and Austria are pressing for a “reverse charge” mechanism that would in effect turn VAT into a hybrid sales tax. (''Financial Times'' 2006)</blockquote>
  
The Act not only provides for tax refunds for exporters (refund of tax paid on inputs used in the manufacture of goods exported), it also provides for refund of tax in cases where the inputs are taxed at 12.5% and outputs are taxed at 4%.  
+
As well as the administrative issues faced by exporters, businesses are often left paying heavy VAT bills as a result of governments’ exemption of certain types of goods and services, such as education, from the tax. As a result, some critics have argued that governments should reduce, if not eliminate, exemptions and reductions.
  
The VAT Act in Andhra Pradesh is administered by the Commercial Taxes Department (department to collect VAT and other taxes) using a networked software package called VATIS. The personnel were trained prior to the Act coming into force. VATIS is used to process documents and forms received and to generate registration certificates and tax demand notices.
+
==Conclusion==
 +
Proponents of the value-added tax have suggested that VAT might be able to improve economic performance by facilitating a reduction in other taxes, such as personal and corporate [[income tax]]es. A broad-based sales tax would almost certainly distort economic choices less than the income tax does. Additionally, an important advantage of the value-added form of sales tax is the fact that tax is collected as products move from stage to stage in the production-distribution process. Thus by the time a product reaches the retail stage, much of its total value has already been taxed.
  
VAT, to be successful, relies on voluntary tax compliance. Since VAT believes in self assessments, dealers are required to maintain proper records, issue tax invoices, file correct tax returns etc. The opposite seems to be happening in India. Businesses are still run on traditional lines. Cash transactions are order of the day. The unorganised sector dominates the market. The hope of higher tax compliance and lesser evasion is still a far cry in Andhra Pradesh. This is reflected in the high percentage of return defaulters (14%), credit returns (35%) and nil returns (20%). That is, roughly 70% of VAT dealers are presently not paying any tax. Filing of credit returns is rampant among FMCG, Consumer Durables, Drugs and Medicines and Fertilizers. The margins are low in this sector (ranging between 2 to 5%). The value addition is not enough to yield revenue as of now. Credits offered by manufacturers compounds the problem. The question is, in a typical purchases and sales scenario, can there be more output tax than input tax? When purchases consistently exceed sales, can output tax exceed input tax? If a VAT dealer can balance his/her purchases and sales, can there be a net tax to the State? Is there a mathematical model or paradigm which can give value added tax and which can reduce the percentage of credit returns? There are no ready answers for these queries. The only remedy seems to be the restriction of input tax to the corresponding purchase value of goods put to sales. In fact a two tier system can be adopted to counter the credit returns - allow full input tax to manufacturers and restrict input tax to the purchase value of goods put to sale to traders. Restricting input tax to 4% in the case of inter state sales and in the case of products taxable at 12.5% seems to be another solution.
+
===Theory vs. actual state of affairs===
 +
There are obviously two contradicting views on the very basics of VAT. If the VAT was actually used to eliminate all [[income tax]]es, this approach would have considerable merit. There is no doubt that personal and corporate income taxes do more damage per dollar raised than a VAT would (Guseh 1977).  
  
===Mexico===<!-- This section is linked from [[Vicente Fox]] —>
+
However, no nation has ever implemented a VAT (or a national sales tax) and used the money to eliminate all income taxes. Indeed, no government in the world—national, state, provincial, county, or city—has taken this step. No government has even eliminated just one of the two forms of income taxation (personal and corporate). The VAT always has been imposed in addition to existing personal and corporate income taxes (Grier and Tullock 1989).
  
''Impuesto al Valor Agregado'' ('''IVA''', "[[value-added tax]]" in [[Spanish (language)|Spanish]]) is a [[tax]] applied in [[Mexico]] and other countries of [[Latin America]] and [[Spain]]. In [[Chile]] it is called ''Impuesto a las Ventas y Servicios'', in Spain ''Impuesto sobre el Valor Añadido'' and in [[Peru]] it is called ''Impuesto General a las Ventas'' or ''IGV''.
+
Faced with this overwhelming real-world evidence, VAT advocates sometimes argue that the tax at least could be used to lower taxes on personal and corporate income. Just like the total replacement hypothesis, this partial-replacement hypothesis is an interesting theory, but it is equally implausible. All available statistics show that the aggregate tax burden on income and profits (a measure of the tax on personal and corporate income) has fallen slightly in the United States, but it has risen significantly in the [[European Union]], and this increased tax burden on productive activity took place after VATs became ubiquitous (Genetski et al 1988).
  
Prior to the IVA, a similar tax called ''impuesto a las ventas'' ("sales tax") had been applied in Mexico. In September, 1966, the first attempt to apply the IVA took place when revenue experts declared that the IVA should be a modern equivalent of the sales tax as it occurred in [[France]]. At the convention of the Inter-American Center of Revenue Administrators in April and May, 1967, the Mexican representation declared that the application of a value-added tax would not be possible in Mexico at the time. In November, 1967, other experts declared that although this is one of the most equitable indirect taxes, its application in Mexico could not take place.
+
===Considerations from classical economics===
 +
Let us seek help to this conundrum from the genuine free-market approach of [[Jean-Baptiste Say]], who contributed considerably more to [[economics]] than [[Say's law]]. Say was under no illusion that [[taxation]] is voluntary nor that government spending contributes productive services to the [[economy]]. Say pointed out that, in taxation,  
 +
<blockquote>The government exacts from a taxpayer the payment of a given tax in the shape of money. To meet this demand, the taxpayer exchanges part of the products at his disposal for coin, which he pays to the tax-gatherers (Say 1880).</blockquote>
  
In response to these statements, direct sampling of members in the private sector took place as well as field trips to the [[Europe]]an countries this tax was applied or it was soon to be applied. In 1969, the first attempt to substitute the mercantile-revenue tax for the value-added tax took place. On December 29, 1978 the Federal government published the official application of the tax beginning on January 1, 1980 in the Official Journal of the Federation ([[Diario Oficial de la Federación]]).
+
Eventually, the government spends the money on its own needs, so that
 +
<blockquote>in the end . . . this value is consumed; and then the portion of wealth, which passes from the hands of the taxpayer into those of the tax-gatherer, is destroyed and annihilated (Say 1880).</blockquote>
  
===New Zealand===
+
Note, that as is the case with many later economists, such as [[Murray Rothbard]], Say sees that taxation creates two conflicting classes, the '''taxpayers''' and the '''tax-gatherers''':
 +
<blockquote>Were it not for taxes, the taxpayer would have spent his money on his own consumption. As it is, the state. . enjoys the satisfaction resulting from that consumption (Say 1880).</blockquote>
  
Goods and Services Tax (GST) is a Value Added Tax introduced in [[New Zealand]] in 1986, which is currently 12.5%. It is notable for exempting few items from the tax...
+
Taxation, then, for Say is the transfer of a portion of the national products from the hands of individuals to those of the government, for the purpose of meeting the public consumption of expenditure:
 +
<blockquote>It is virtually a burthen imposed upon individuals, either in a separate or corporate character, by the ruling power... for the purpose of supplying the consumption it may think proper to make at their expense (Say 1880, 446).</blockquote>
 +
 +
But taxation, for Say, is not merely a zero-sum game. By levying a burden on the producers, he points out, "taxes, over time, cripple production itself."
 +
<blockquote>Taxation deprives the producer of a product, which he would otherwise have the option of deriving a personal gratification from, if consumed... or of turning to profit, if he preferred to devote it to an useful employment... Therefore, the subtraction of a product must needs diminish, instead of augmenting, productive power (Say 1880, 447).</blockquote>
  
===Australia===
+
J. B. Say's policy recommendation was crystal clear and consistent with his analysis and that of various comments on VAT:
 +
<blockquote>The best scheme of [public] finance is, to spend as little as possible; and the best tax is always the lightest (Say 1880).</blockquote>
  
Goods and Services Tax (GST) is a Value Added Tax introduced in [[Australia]] in 2000 which is collected by the Federal government but given to state governments.
+
To this, there is nothing more to add.
 
 
===United States===
 
 
 
In the [[United States]], the state of [[Michigan]] uses a form of VAT known as the "Single Business Tax" (SBT) as its form of general business taxation. It is the only state in the U.S. to use a VAT. When it was adopted in 1975, it replaced seven business taxes, including a [[corporate income tax]]. On August 9, 2006, the Michigan legislature approved voter-initiated legislation to repeal the Single Business Tax. The repeal will be effective after December 31, 2007.<ref>[http://www.crcmich.org/TaxOutline/Business/sbt.html Single Business Tax - Outline of the Michigan Tax System], Citizens Research Council of Michigan, ''January 24, 2007''</ref>
 
 
 
Most states have sales taxes charged to the end buyer only. State sales taxes range from 0%-13% and municipalities often add an extra local sales tax <ref>[http://www.town-usa.com/statetax/statetaxlist.html], State Tax Rates, ''July 14, 2007''</ref>. In many stores, the price tags and/or advertised prices do not include the taxes, these will be added at the cash register before the customer pays. In many states, no sales tax is charged for services. This is a key difference between most sales taxes levied throughout the United States and the value added taxes in other countries.
 
 
 
==Tax Rates==
 
===EU countries===
 
{| class="wikitable"
 
|-
 
! rowspan=2 | Country
 
! colspan="2" | Rate
 
! rowspan=2 | Abbr.
 
! rowspan=2 | Name
 
|-
 
! Standard
 
! Reduced
 
|-
 
| {{AUT}}
 
| 20%
 
| 12% or 10%
 
| USt.
 
| Umsatzsteuer
 
|-
 
| {{BEL}}
 
| 21%
 
| 12% or 6%
 
| BTW <br /> TVA <br /> MWSt
 
| Belasting over de toegevoegde waarde <br /> Taxe sur la Valeur Ajoutée <br /> Mehrwertsteuer
 
|-
 
| {{BUL}}
 
| 20%
 
| 7%
 
| ДДС
 
| Данък Добавена Стойност
 
|-
 
| {{CYP}}
 
| 15%
 
| 5%
 
| ΦΠΑ
 
| Φόρος Προστιθεμένης Αξίας
 
|-
 
| {{CZE}}
 
| 19%
 
| 5%
 
| DPH
 
| Daň z přidané hodnoty
 
|-
 
| {{DEN}}
 
| 25%
 
|
 
| moms
 
| Merværdiomsætningsafgift
 
|-
 
| {{EST}}
 
| 18%
 
| 5%
 
| km
 
| käibemaks
 
|-
 
| {{FIN}}
 
| 22%
 
| 17% or 8%
 
| ALV<br />Moms
 
| Arvonlisävero<br />Mervärdesskatt
 
|-
 
| {{FRA}}
 
| 19.6%
 
| 5.5% or 2.1%
 
| TVA
 
| Taxe sur la Valeur Ajoutée
 
|-
 
| {{DEU}}
 
| 19%
 
| 7%
 
| MwSt./USt.
 
| Mehrwertsteuer/Umsatzsteuer
 
|-
 
| {{GRE}}
 
| 19%
 
| 9% or 4.5%<br />(reduced by 30% to 13%, 6% and 3% on islands)
 
| ΦΠΑ
 
| Φόρος Προστιθέμενης Αξίας
 
|-
 
| {{HUN}}
 
| 20%
 
| 5%
 
| ÁFA
 
| általános forgalmi adó
 
|-
 
| {{IRL}}
 
| 21%
 
| 13.5%, 4.8% or 0%
 
| CBL<br />VAT
 
| Cáin Bhreisluacha<br />Value Added Tax
 
|-
 
| {{ITA}}
 
| 20%
 
| 10%, 6%, or 4%
 
| IVA
 
| Imposta sul Valore Aggiunto
 
|-
 
| {{LAT}}
 
| 18%
 
| 5%
 
| PVN
 
| Pievienotās vērtības nodoklis
 
|-
 
| {{LTU}}
 
| 18%
 
| 9% or 5%
 
| PVM
 
| Pridėtinės vertės mokestis
 
|-
 
| {{LUX}}
 
| 15%
 
| 12%, 9%, 6%, or 3%
 
| TVA
 
| Taxe sur la Valeur Ajoutée
 
|-
 
| {{MLT}}
 
| 18%
 
| 5%
 
| TVM
 
| Taxxa tal-Valur Miżjud
 
|-
 
| {{NLD}}
 
| 19%
 
| 6%
 
| BTW
 
| Belasting over de toegevoegde waarde
 
|-
 
| {{POL}}
 
| 22%
 
| 7%, 3% or 0%
 
| PTU/VAT
 
| Podatek od towarów i usług
 
|-
 
| {{POR}}
 
| 21%
 
| 12% or 5%
 
| IVA
 
| Imposto sobre o Valor Acrescentado
 
|-
 
| {{ROM}}
 
| 19%
 
| 9%
 
| TVA
 
| Taxa pe valoarea adăugată
 
|-
 
| {{SVK}}
 
| 19%
 
| 10%
 
| DPH
 
| Daň z pridanej hodnoty
 
|-
 
| {{SLO}}
 
| 20%
 
| 8.5%
 
| DDV
 
| Davek na dodano vrednost
 
|-
 
| {{ESP}}
 
| 16%
 
| 7% or 4%
 
| IVA
 
| Impuesto sobre el valor añadido
 
|-
 
| {{SWE}}
 
| 25%
 
| 12% or 6%
 
| Moms
 
| Mervärdesskatt
 
|-
 
| {{UK}}
 
| 17.5%
 
| 5% or 0%
 
| VAT
 
| Value Added Tax
 
|}
 
 
 
===Non-EU countries===
 
{| class="wikitable"
 
|-
 
! rowspan=2 | Country
 
! colspan="2" | Rate
 
! rowspan=2 | Local name
 
|-
 
! Standard
 
! Reduced
 
|-
 
| {{ARG}}
 
| 21%
 
| 10.5% or 0%
 
| IVA = ''Impuesto al Valor Agregado''
 
|-
 
| {{AUS}}
 
| 10%
 
| 0%
 
| GST = ''[[Goods and Services Tax (Australia)|Goods and Services Tax]]''
 
|-
 
| {{BIH}}
 
| 17%
 
|
 
| PDV = ''porez na dodatu vrijednost''
 
|-
 
| {{CAN}}
 
| 6%-14%[[#CanadaRate|<sup id=fn1>1</sup>]]
 
| 4.5%
 
| GST = ''[[Goods and Services Tax (Canada)|Goods and Services Tax]], TPS = Taxe sur les produits et services, PST = [[Taxation_in_Canada#Sales_taxes|Provincial Sales Tax]], HST = Harmonized Sales Tax''
 
|-
 
| {{CHI}}
 
| 19%
 
|
 
| IVA = ''Impuesto al Valor Agregado''
 
|-
 
| {{COL}}
 
| 16%
 
|
 
| IVA = ''Impuesto sobre el Valor Agregado''
 
|-
 
| {{PRC}}[[#Footnote2|<sup id=fn2>2</sup>]]
 
| 17%
 
| 6% or 3%
 
| {{lang|zh-s|增值税}} ([[pinyin]]:''zēng zhí shuì'')
 
|-
 
| {{HRV}}
 
| 22%
 
| 0%
 
| PDV = ''Porez na dodanu vrijednost''
 
|-
 
| {{DOM}}
 
| 6%
 
| 12% or 0%
 
|-
 
| {{ECU}}
 
| 12%
 
|
 
| IVA = ''Impuesto al Valor Agregado''
 
|-
 
| {{EGY}}
 
|10%
 
|
 
| ''GST = Goods and Sales Tax''
 
|-
 
| {{ESA}}
 
| 13%
 
|
 
| IVA = ''Impuesto al Valor Agregado''
 
|-
 
| {{GEO}}
 
| 18%
 
| 0%
 
| ''DGhG = Damatebuli Ghirebulebis gdasakhadi'' დღგ = დამატებული ღირებულების გადასახადი
 
|-
 
| {{GUY}}
 
| 16%
 
| 14%
 
|-
 
| {{ISL}}
 
| 24.5%
 
| 7%[[#IcelandChanges|<sup id=fn3>3</sup>]]
 
| VSK = ''Virðisaukaskattur''
 
|-
 
| {{IND}}[[#India|<sup id=fn4>4</sup>]]
 
| 12.5%
 
| 4%, 1%, or 0%
 
| VAT = Valued Added Tax
 
|-
 
| {{INA}}
 
| 10%
 
| 5%
 
| PPN = Pajak Pertambahan Nilai
 
|-
 
| {{ISR}}[[#Eilat|<sup id=fn10>10</sup>]]
 
| 15.5%[[#IsraelChanges|<sup id=fn5>5</sup>]]
 
|
 
| Ma'am = ''מס ערך מוסף''
 
|-
 
| {{JPN}}
 
|5%
 
|
 
| [[Consumption tax]] = 消費税
 
|-
 
| {{KOR}}
 
| 10%
 
|
 
| VAT = 부가세(附加稅, ''Bugase'') = 부가가치세(附加價値稅, ''Bugagachise'')
 
|-
 
| {{JEY}}[[#Jersey|<sup id=fn9>9</sup>]]
 
| 3%
 
| 0%
 
| ''GST = Goods and Sales Tax''
 
|-
 
| {{JOR}}
 
|16%
 
|
 
| ''GST = Goods and Sales Tax''
 
|-
 
| {{KAZ}}
 
|14%
 
|
 
|-
 
| {{KSV}}
 
|15%
 
|0%
 
|
 
|-
 
| {{LBN}}
 
|10%
 
|
 
| TVA = ''Taxe sur la valeur ajoutée''
 
|-
 
| {{MDA}}
 
| 20%
 
| 5%
 
|TVA = ''Taxa pe Valoarea Adăugată''
 
|-
 
| {{MKD}}
 
| 18%
 
| 5%
 
|ДДВ = ''Данок на Додадена Вредност''
 
|-
 
| {{MYS}}[[#MalaysiaGST|<sup id=fn6>6</sup>]]
 
| 5%
 
|
 
|-
 
| {{MEX}}
 
| 15%
 
| 0%
 
|IVA = ''Impuesto al Valor Agregado''
 
|-
 
| {{MNE}}
 
| 17%
 
|
 
| PDV = ''Porez na dodatu vrijednost''
 
|-
 
| {{NZL}}
 
| 12.5%
 
|
 
| GST = ''[[Goods and Services Tax (New Zealand)|Goods and Services Tax]]''
 
|-
 
| {{NOR}}
 
| 25%
 
| 14% or 8%
 
| MVA = ''Merverdiavgift'' (informally ''moms'')
 
|-
 
| {{PAK}}
 
| 7.5%
 
| 1% or 0%
 
|-
 
| {{PAN}}
 
| 5%
 
|
 
| ITBMS = ''Impuesto de Transferencia de Bienes Muebles y Servicios''
 
|-
 
| {{PAR}}
 
| 10%
 
| 5%
 
| GST= ''Impuesto al Valor Agregado''
 
|-
 
| {{PER}}
 
| 19%
 
|
 
| IGV = ''Impuesto General a la Ventas''
 
|-
 
| {{PHL}}
 
| 12%[[#PhilippinesRate|<sup id=fn7>7</sup>]]
 
|
 
| RVAT = '' RVAT or Reformed Value Added Tax'', locally known as ''Karagdagang Buwis''
 
|-
 
| {{RUS}}
 
| 18%
 
| 10% or 0%
 
|НДС ''NDS'' = Налог на добавленную стоимость ''Nalog na dobavlennuyu stoimost''
 
|-
 
| {{SRB}}
 
| 18%
 
| 8% or 0%
 
| PDV = ''Porez na dodatu vrednost''
 
|-
 
| {{SIN}}
 
| 7%
 
|
 
| GST = ''[[Goods and Services Tax (Singapore)|Goods and Services Tax]]''
 
|-
 
| {{ZAF}}
 
| 14%
 
| 0%
 
| VAT = ''Valued Added Tax''
 
|-
 
| {{LKA}}
 
| 15%
 
|
 
|-
 
| {{CHE}}
 
| 7.6%
 
| 3.6% or 2.4%
 
| MWST = Mehrwertsteuer, TVA = Taxe sur la valeur ajoutée, IVA = Imposta sul valore aggiunto, VAT = Value Added Tax
 
|-
 
| {{THA}}
 
| 7%
 
|
 
|-
 
| {{TRI}}
 
| 15%
 
|
 
|
 
|-
 
| {{TUR}}
 
| 18%
 
| 8% or 1%
 
| KDV= Katma değer vergisi
 
|-
 
| {{UKR}}
 
| 20%
 
| 0%
 
|ПДВ= ''Податок на додану вартість''
 
|-
 
| {{URU}}
 
| 23%
 
| 14%
 
| IVA = ''Impuesto al Valor Agregado''
 
|-
 
| {{VIE}}
 
| 10%
 
| 5% or 0%
 
| GTGT = ''Gia Tri Gia Tang''
 
|-
 
| {{VEN}}
 
| 9%
 
| 8%
 
| IVA = ''Impuesto al Valor Agregado''
 
|}
 
<div class="references-small">
 
<cite id=CanadaRate>[[#fn1|Note 1]]</cite>: Some Canadian provinces collect 14% for [[harmonized sales tax]], a combined federal/provincial VAT. In the rest, the federal GST is 6% and if the province charges sales tax it is separate and is not a VAT. No real "reduced rate" but rebates are generally available for new housing effectively reducing the tax to 4.5%
 
 
 
<cite id="Footnote2">[[#fn2|Note 2]]</cite>: These taxes do not apply in [[Hong Kong]] and [[Macau]], which are [[public finance|financially]] independent as [[special administrative region]]s.
 
 
 
<cite id="IcelandChanges">[[#fn3|Note 3]]</cite>: The reduced rate was 14% until 1 March 2007, when it was lowered to 7%. The reduced rate applies to heating costs, printed matter, restaurant bills, hotel stays, and most food.
 
 
 
<cite id="India">[[#fn4|Note 4]]</cite>: VAT is not implemented in 2 of India's 28 states.
 
 
 
<cite id=IsraelChanges>[[#fn5|Note 5]]</cite>: The VAT in Israel is in the process of being gradually reduced. It was reduced from 18% to 17% on March 2004, to 16.5% on September 2005, and was set to its current rate on July 1, 2006. There are plans to further reduce it in the near future, but they depend on political changes in the Israeli parliament.
 
 
 
<cite id="MalaysiaGST">[[#fn6|Note 6]]</cite>: In the 2005 Budget, the government announced that GST would be introduced in January 2007. Many details have not yet been confirmed but it has been stated that essential goods and small businesses would be exempted or zero rated. Rates have not yet been established as of June 2007.
 
 
 
<cite id=PhilippinesRate>[[#fn7|Note 7]]</cite>: The [[President of the Philippines]] has the power to raise the tax to 12% after January 1, 2006. The tax was raised to 12% on February 1.
 
 
 
<cite id="Jersey">[[#fn9|Note 9]]</cite>: The [[States of Jersey]] has for the few years, preparing for the introduction of a goods and sales tax to plug a large budget deficit in the island's government budget. It will be held at a flat rate of 3%, with possible exceptions to local food (food not subject to an “island tax” of 5%) and children's clothing.
 
 
 
<cite id="Eilat">[[#fn10|Note 10]]</cite>: Except Eilat, where VAT is not raised.<ref>[http://www.eccb06.org/new_pages/general_info/gen_info_fqs.html#taxRefund VAT in Eilat], ECCB</ref>
 
</div>
 
 
 
==VAT registered ==
 
''VAT registered'' means registered for [[VAT]] purposes, i.e. entered into an official VAT payers register of a country. Both natural persons and legal entities can be VAT registered. Countries that use VAT have established different thresholds for remuneration derived by natural persons/legal entities during a calendar year (or a different period) by exceeding which the VAT registration is compulsory. Natural persons/legal entities that are VAT registered are obliged to calculate VAT on certain goods/services that they supply and pay VAT into particular state budget. VAT registered persons/entities are entitled to VAT deduction under legislatory regulations of particular country. The introduction of a VAT can reduce the cash economy because businesses that wish to buy and sell with other VAT registered businesses must themselves be VAT registered.
 
 
 
==Notes==
 
<references/>
 
  
 
==References==
 
==References==
>
+
* Bartlett, Bruce. 2005. [http://www.nationalreview.com/nrof_bartlett/bartlett200503090845.asp The Right VATitude] ''National Review Online''. Retrieved June 24, 2008.
* '''MOMS''', Politikens Nudansk Leksikon 2002, ISBN 87-604-1578-9
+
* &mdash;&mdash;&mdash;. 2006. [http://bartlett.blogs.nytimes.com/2006/03/28/the-best-kind-of-tax/ The Best Kind of Tax] ''The New York Times''. Retrieved June 24, 2008.
* [http://www.pdicai.org/vatap/APVATACT_2005.pdf Andhra Pradesh Value Added Tax Act, 2005], Andhra Pradesh Gazette Extraordinary, 25 March 2005, retrieved on 16 March 2007.
+
* Bickley, James. 2003. [http://www.ncseonline.org/nle/crsreports/03May/IB92069.pdf A Value-Added Tax Contrasted with a National Sales Tax]. Congressional Research Service. Retrieved June 24, 2008.
 
+
* Engen, Eric M. and Jonathan Skinner. 1992. Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth. ''National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 4223''.
 +
* Financial Times. 2006. Evasion and exemptions erode VAT's own value added. ''Financial Times''.
 +
* Genetski, Robert J., Debra J. Bredael, and Brian S. Wesbury. 1988. The Impact of a Value-Added Tax on the U.S. Economy. ''Stotler Economics''.
 +
* Grier, Kevin B. and Gordon Tullock. 1989. An Empirical Analysis of Cross-National Economic Growth, 1951–80. ''Journal of Monetary Economics'' 24(2):259–276.
 +
* Guseh, James S. 1997. Government Size and Economic Growth in Developing Countries: A Political-Economy Framework. ''Journal of Macroeconomics'' 19(1):175–192.
 +
* Kesselman, J., Keith Banting, and Ken Battle (eds.). 1994. Public Policies To Combat Child Poverty: Goals and Options. ''A New Social Vision for Canada? Perspectives on the Federal Discussion Paper on Social Policy Reform''. Kingston, CA: Queen’s University, School of Policy Studies. ISBN 0889116873
 +
* Kesselman, J. 1997. ''General Payroll Taxes: Economics, Politics, and Design''. Toronto, CA: Canadian Tax Foundation. ISBN 0888081219
 +
* Rothbard, Murray. 1977. ''Power and Market: Government and the Economy''. Kansas City, KS: Sheed Andrews & McMeel. ISBN 0836207505
 +
* &mdash;&mdash;&mdash;. 1981. The Myth of Neutral Taxation. ''Cato Journal''. 1:551–54.
 +
* &mdash;&mdash;&mdash;. 1988. Review of A. Chafuen, Christians for Freedom: Late Scholastic Economics. ''International Philosophical Quarterly''. 28:112–14.
 +
* &mdash;&mdash;&mdash;. 1994. Consumption Tax: A Critique. ''Review of Austrian Economics''. 7(2):75–90.
 +
* Say, Jean-Baptiste. [1880] 2007. ''A Treatise on Political Economy'', 6th ed. Cosimo Classics. ISBN 978-1602061910
 +
* Tait, Alan A. 1988. ''The Value Added Tax: International Practice and Problems''. International Monetary Fund. ISBN 978-1557750129
  
 
==External links==
 
==External links==
*[http://dmoz.org/Business/Accounting/Tax_Negotiation_and_Representation/VAT_Related_Services/ VAT Related Services] at the Open Directory Project
+
All links retrieved May 3, 2023.
*[http://www.statevat.com VAT in INDIA]
 
*[http://europa.eu.int/comm/taxation_customs/taxation/vat/how_vat_works/index_en.htm What is VAT?: General overview]
 
*[http://www.duport.co.uk/guides/tax&vat/An%20Introduction%20to%20VAT.HTM An introduction to VAT]
 
*[http://www.hotrec.org/areas/taxation/04.html European VAT rates by service type]
 
*[http://www.mysme.de/index.php?module=pagemaster&PAGE_user_op=view_page&PAGE_id=63&MMN_position=26:6 German VAT]
 
*[http://www.deloitte.com/dtt/article/0,2297,sid%253D2959%2526cid%253D5028,00.html VAT/GST sales tax rates around the world]
 
*[http://europa.eu.int/eur-lex/en/consleg/pdf/1977/en_1977L0388_do_001.pdf Consolidated version of the Sixth VAT Directive (398k pdf)]
 
*[http://www.hmrc.gov.uk/ HM Revenue & Customs]
 
*[http://www.maap.co.uk/taxcard.php?choice=taxcard UK VAT Threshold Rates]
 
*[http://www.michigan.gov/treasury/0,1607,7-121-1750_2143_2153_3222-126184—,00.html What is the Single Business Tax? (Michigan Department of Treasury)]
 
*[http://www.itwh.pwc.com A Guide to the latest VAT news in the UK by PricewaterhouseCoopers]
 
 
 
  
 +
*[https://www.gov.uk/topic/business-tax/vat VAT]
  
  
{{Credits|Value_added_tax|149805831|}}
+
{{Credits|Value_added_tax|149805831|Ad_valorem_tax|211105825}}

Latest revision as of 14:16, 3 May 2023

Taxation
Assorted United States coins.jpg

Types of Tax
Ad valorem tax ·  Consumption tax
Corporate tax ·  Excise
Gift tax ·  Income tax
Inheritance tax ·  Land value tax
Luxury tax ·  Poll tax
Property tax ·  Sales tax
Tariff ·  Value added tax

Tax incidence
Flat tax ·  Progressive tax
Regressive tax ·  Tax haven
Tax rate

The Value Added Tax (VAT) is a form of consumption tax that taxes all business profit and labor. The tax is levied on the value added to the product at each stage of its manufacturing cycle as well as the price paid by the final consumer. Commonly, the seller at each stage subtracts the sum of taxes paid on items purchased from the sum of taxes collected on items sold; the net tax liability is the difference between tax collected and tax paid. The cost of materials, subcomponents, tools, equipment, facilities, supplies, and so forth, and any services purchased from other businesses, are not retaxed under the VAT. Those purchases would have already been subjected to the VAT by the supplying businesses.

The VAT was first adopted in France in 1954. By the end of the twentieth century it had been adopted throughout the European Union and in many countries in Africa, Asia, and South America. Notably, the United States and Canada did not follow suit.

The burden of VAT, like other consumption taxes, tends to be passed on to the consumer. Additionally, since this is a regressive tax, lower income people have the greatest burden. To offset this, necessities are often taxed at a lower rate than luxury items. Advocates of the VAT contend that it is an efficient method of raising revenue, and would permit concomitant reductions in income tax. Opponents argue that, as a regressive tax, it puts too much burden on those who are least able to afford it.

It is only when human nature changes from selfishness to caring for others and society as a whole that the problems inherent in taxation can be resolved, both by those designing the system and by those paying and collecting the taxes.

Definition

Value added tax (usually shortened to VAT) is a levy on the amount a business add to the price (hence the name "value added") of goods during their production and distribution. Since it is a tax on commodities purchased, ultimately for consumption, rather than on the income of an individual or corporation, it is essentially a consumption tax.

The VAT is usually collected by the tax credit method; each firm applies the tax rate to its taxable sales, but is allowed a credit for value-added tax paid on its purchases of goods and services for business use, including the tax paid on purchases of capital equipment under a consumption-type value-added tax. As a result, the only tax for which no credit would be allowed would be that collected on sales made to households, rather than to businesses.

Since the sum of the values added at all stages in the production and distribution of a good are equal to the retail selling price of the good, the revenue base of a retail sales tax and a value-added tax with the same coverage are theoretically identical, and a given tax rate will yield the same amount of tax revenue under either approach and under equal conditions of implementation, in other words, no exceptions or exemptions.

History

The VAT was invented by a French economist in 1954. Maurice Lauré, joint director of the French tax authority, the Direction générale des impôts, as taxe sur la valeur ajoutée (TVA in French) was first to introduce VAT with effect from April 10, 1954, for large businesses, and extended over time to all business sectors. In France, it is the most important source of state finance, accounting for approximately 45 percent of state revenues. West Germany adopted VAT in 1968, and subsequently most other Western European countries also implemented some form of VAT. Many countries in Africa, Asia, and South America have also followed suit. Although the United States as a whole has not, the state of Michigan has used a value added tax.

Today, all members of the European Union are required to implement VAT.

How VAT works

VAT that is charged by a business and paid by its customers is known as output VAT (that is, VAT on its output supplies). VAT that is paid by a business to other businesses on the supplies that it receives is known as input VAT (that is, VAT on its input supplies). A business is generally able to recover input VAT to the extent that the input VAT is attributable to (that is, used to make) its taxable outputs. Input VAT is recovered by setting it against the output VAT for which the business is required to account to the government, or, if there is an excess, by claiming a repayment from the government.

Under the European Union system of VAT, where a person carrying on an economic activity supplies goods and services to another person, and the value of the supplies passes financial limits, the supplier is required to register with the local taxation authorities and charge its customers, and account to the local taxation authority for VAT (although the price may be inclusive of VAT, so VAT is included as part of the agreed price, or exclusive of VAT, so VAT is payable in addition to the agreed price).

Different rates of VAT apply in different EU member states. The minimum standard rate of VAT throughout the EU is 15 percent, although reduced rates of VAT, as low as five percent, are applied in various states on various sorts of supply (for example, domestic fuel and power in the UK). The maximum rate in the EU is 25 percent.

The Sixth VAT Directive requires certain goods and services to be exempt from VAT (for example, postal services, medical care, lending, insurance, betting), and certain other goods and services to be exempt from VAT but subject to the ability of an EU member state to opt to charge VAT on those supplies (such as land and certain financial services). Input VAT that is attributable to exempt supplies is not recoverable, although a business can increase its prices so the customer effectively bears the cost of the 'sticking' VAT (the effective rate will be lower than the headline rate and depend on the balance between previously taxed input and labor at the exempt stage).

Finally, some goods and services are "zero-rated." The zero-rate is a positive rate of tax calculated at zero percent. Supplies subject to the zero-rate are still "taxable supplies," in other words, they have VAT charged on them. In the UK, examples include most food, books, drugs, and certain kinds of transport. The zero-rate is not featured in the EU Sixth Directive as it was intended that the minimum VAT rate throughout Europe would be five percent. However, zero-rating remains in some member states, most notably the UK, as a legacy of pre-EU legislation. These member states have been granted a derogation (partial revocation of the law) to continue existing zero-rating but cannot add new goods or services. The UK also exempts or lowers the rate on some products depending on situation; for example milk products are exempt from VAT, but a milk drink served in a restaurant is subject to VAT. Some products such as feminine hygiene products and baby products are charged at five percent VAT along with domestic fuel.

When goods are imported into the EU from other states, VAT is generally charged at the border, at the same time as customs duty. "Acquisition" VAT is payable when goods are acquired in one EU member state from another EU member state (this is done not at the border but through an accounting mechanism). EU businesses are often required to charge themselves VAT under the reverse charge mechanism where services are received from another member state or from outside of the EU.

Businesses can be required to register for VAT in EU member states, other than the one in which they are based, if they supply goods via mail order to those states, over a certain threshold. Businesses that are established in one member state but which receive supplies in another member state may be able to reclaim VAT charged in the second state under the provisions of the Eighth VAT Directive (Directive 79/1072/EC). To do so, businesses have a value added tax identification number. A similar directive, the Thirteenth VAT Directive (Directive 86/560/EC), also allows businesses established outside the EU to recover VAT under certain circumstances.

Differences between VAT and (retail) sales tax

Despite its multistage character, explained in the above section a value-added tax is very much like a retail sales tax in that it is a tax on expenditures by consumers or, in other words, it is just another type of consumption tax. Since the sum of the values added at all stages in the production and distribution of a good are equal to the retail selling price of the good, the revenue base of a retail sales tax and a value-added tax with the same coverage are theoretically identical, and a given tax rate will yield the same amount of tax revenue under either approach. There are, however, significant differences in the impacts of different types of consumption tax.

Retail sales tax, the familiar percentage tax on retail sales, is one type of consumption tax. In this tax, a simple percentage is added to the retail price of goods when sold to the consumer, but not when sold for resale to a retailer, or to a manufacturer as parts in production of a new commodity. Sales tax does not distort the production structure as would the VAT, and it would not skew individual preferences as would specific excise taxes (Rothbard 1994).

The VAT consumption tax, standard in Europe and other parts of the world, imposes a hierarchical tax on the "value added" by each firm and business. This would tend to distort the structure of business. For one thing, there would be an incentive for uneconomic vertical integration, since the fewer the number of times a sale takes place, the fewer the imposed taxes. Also, as has happened in European countries with experience of the VAT, a flourishing industry may arise in issuing phony vouchers, so that businesses can over-inflate their alleged expenditures, and reduce their reported value added.

A sales tax, other things being equal, seems to be both simpler, less distorting of resources, and enormously less bureaucratic than the VAT. Indeed the VAT seems to have no clear advantage over the sales tax, except of course, if multiplying bureaucracy and bureaucratic power is considered a benefit (Rothbard 1994).

Another way of looking at this issue is this. VAT differs from a conventional sales tax in that VAT is levied on every business as a fraction of the price of each taxable sale they make, but they are in turn reimbursed VAT on their purchases, so the VAT is applied to the value added to the goods at each stage of production (Sharma 2005: 916; quoted in Muller 2007:64).

Sales taxes are normally only charged on final sales to consumers: because of reimbursement, VAT has the same overall economic effect on final prices. The main difference is the extra accounting required by those in the middle of the supply chain; this disadvantage of VAT is balanced by application of the same tax to each member of the production chain regardless of its position in it and the position of its customers, reducing the effort required to check and certify their status. When the VAT has few, if any exemptions such as with GST in New Zealand, payment of VAT is even simpler.

Generally speaking, if sales taxes exceed ten percent, people start engaging in widespread tax evasion activities (like buying over the Internet, pretending to be a business, buying at wholesale, buying products through an employer, and so forth). On the other hand, total VAT rates can rise above ten percent without widespread evasion because of the novel collection mechanism, which not only keeps the tax liability of the final consumer at a lower level but also makes such evasions impossible since all purchases are taxed, including wholesale and so on. However because of its particular mechanism of collection, VAT becomes quite easily the target of specific frauds.

Collection Mechanism

The standard way to implement a VAT is to say a business owes some percentage on the price of the product minus all taxes previously paid on the good. If VAT rates were ten percent, an orange juice maker would pay ten percent of the $5 per gallon price ($0.50) minus taxes previously paid by the orange farmer (say $0.20). In this example, the orange juice maker would have a $0.30 tax liability. Each business has a strong incentive for its suppliers to pay their taxes, allowing VAT rates to be higher with less tax evasion than a retail sales tax.

Consider the manufacture and sale of any item, which in this case we will call a widget.

(1) Without any sales tax
  • A widget manufacturer spends $1 on raw materials and uses them to make a widget.
  • The widget is sold wholesale to a widget retailer for $1.20, making a profit of $0.20.
  • The widget retailer then sells the widget to a widget consumer for $1.50, making a profit of $0.30
(2) With a ten percent sales tax
  • The manufacturer pays $1.00 for the raw materials, certifying it is not a final consumer.
  • The manufacturer charges the retailer $1.20, checking that the retailer is not a consumer, leaving the same profit of $0.20.
  • The retailer charges the consumer $1.65 ($1.50 + ten percent) and pays the government $0.15, leaving the same profit of $0.30.

So the consumer has paid ten percent ($0.15) extra, compared to the no taxation scheme, and the government has collected this amount in taxation. The retailers have not lost anything directly to the tax, but they do have the extra paperwork to do so that they correctly pass on to the government the sales tax they collect. Suppliers and manufacturers have the administrative burden of supplying correct certifications, and checking that their customers (retailers) are not consumers.

(3) With a ten percent VAT
  • The manufacturer pays $1.10 ($1 + ten percent) for the raw materials, and the seller of the raw materials pays the government $0.10.
  • The manufacturer charges the retailer $1.32 ($1.20 + $1.20 x ten percent) and pays the government $0.02 ($0.12 minus $0.10), leaving the same profit of $0.20.
  • The retailer charges the consumer $1.65 ($1.50 + $1.50 x ten percent) and pays the government $0.03 ($0.15 minus $0.12), leaving the same profit of $0.30.

So the consumer has paid ten percent ($0.15) extra, compared to the no taxation scheme, and the government has collected this amount in taxation. The businesses have not lost anything directly to the tax, but they do have the extra paperwork to do so that they correctly pass on to the government the difference between what they collect in VAT (output VAT, an 11th of their income) and what they spend in VAT (input VAT, an 11th of their expenditure).

Note that in each case the VAT paid is equal to ten percent of the profit, or "value added."

The advantage of the VAT system over the sales tax system is that businesses cannot hide consumption (such as wasted materials) by certifying it is not a consumer.

Disadvantages of VAT

Impact on supply and demand

In the above example, it was assumed that the same number of widgets were made and sold both before and after the introduction of the tax. This is not true in real life. The fundamentals of supply and demand suggest that any tax raises the cost of transaction for someone, whether it is the seller or purchaser. In raising the cost, either the demand curve shifts leftward, or the supply curve shifts upward. The two are functionally equivalent. Consequently, the quantity of a good purchased, and/or the price for which it is sold, decrease. This shift in supply and demand is not incorporated into the above example, for simplicity and because these effects are different for every type of good. The widget example assumes the tax is non-distortionary.

TaxWithTax.svg
A Supply-Demand Analysis of a Taxed Market

In the above diagram,

  • Deadweight loss: the area of the triangle formed by the tax income box, the original supply curve, and the demand curve
  • Government's tax income: the grey rectangle
  • Total consumer surplus after the shift: the green area
  • Total producer surplus after the shift: the yellow area

A VAT, like most taxes, distorts what would have happened without it. Because the price rises for someone, the quantity of goods traded decreases. Correspondingly, some people are worse off by more than the government is made better off by the tax income. That is, more is lost due to supply and demand shifts than is gained in tax revenue. This is known as a deadweight loss. The income lost by the economy is greater than the government's income; the tax is inefficient. The entire amount of the government's income (the tax revenue) may not be a deadweight drag, if the tax revenue is used for productive spending or has positive externalities—in other words, governments may do more than simply consume the tax income.

While distortions occur with consumption taxes like VAT, they are often considered superior because they distort incentives to invest, save, and work less than most other types of taxation—in other words, a VAT discourages consumption rather than production. However, taxes on consumption still have negative impact, unlike land value tax which neither causes deadweight losses nor distorts incentives.

Regressivity

A tax is regressive if the average tax rate falls with an increase in income, proportional if the average tax rate is constant, and progressive if the average tax rate rises with income. Simply put, low-income people pay a higher fraction of their income in taxes than wealthier people if the tax is regressive and a lower fraction if the tax is progressive.

VAT, as all types of consumption tax, is often criticized as unfair to lower income individuals and families. The regressivity of VAT, or the relatively higher burden of the tax at the lower income levels than at the higher income levels, may be offset by adjustments to income tax rates, or credits against the income tax. These measures, however, add to the administrative burden of VAT and tend to lead to increases in income taxes, at least for those in higher income brackets.

The regressive effect may also be reduced by taxing necessities at lower rates than luxury items. Again, though, this increases the burden of collection by having multiple rates, as well as leading to lobbying of various sectors competing for lower tax rates for their goods and services.

Expands the cost of government

Countries with VATs have a much heavier total tax burden than those without VATs. Before the creation of VATs, the burden of taxation in Europe was not that much larger than it was in the United States. However, since the late 1960s, when countries in Europe began to adopt VATs, Europe’s aggregate tax burden has increased by about 50 percent while the U.S. tax burden has remained relatively constant (Bickley 2003).

Increases income tax rates

One of the main arguments for the VAT is that it is a less destructive way to raise revenue. This is theoretically true, but irrelevant. In the real world, the VAT has been used as an excuse to increase income taxes as a way to maintain “distributional neutrality.” Indeed, income taxes in Europe today are higher than they were when VATs were implemented.

Effect on prices

Assuming an accommodating monetary policy, a sales tax would almost certainly increase the price level by roughly the percentage it represents of consumption spending. That is, a four percent sales tax that applied to 75 percent of consumption expenditures would increase the general price level by about three percent.

Although this would be a one-time occurrence, not an annual increase, it might cause "ripples" of wage increases, because of cost-of-living adjustments and these could be reflected in further price increases. To the extent the sales tax replaced part of the income tax, there would be little offsetting reduction in prices or wages.

Slows economic growth and destroy jobs

A VAT undermines economic growth in two ways. First, it reduces incentives to engage in productive behavior by driving a larger wedge between pre-tax income and post-tax consumption. Second, it facilitates larger government and the concomitant transfer of resources from the productive sector of the economy to the public sector, reducing jobs in production and diminishing economic efficiency (Engen and Skinner 1992).

Positive and negative effects of VAT in EU

The VAT was invented in Europe mainly to facilitate trade, particularly among members of the European Union. They needed a tax that could be applied at the border on imports and rebated at the border on exports, thus preventing taxes from multiplying every time goods passed through a country. The VAT does this by applying incremental taxes at each stage of production or distribution, with an invoice trail detailing how much tax was embedded in the price (Bartlett 2005).

In supporting the VAT, Bruce Bartlett, a senior fellow for the National Center for Policy Analysis, has argued:

This is the best strategy tax economists have ever devised for raising revenue without investing a lot in enforcement and economic incentives. The V.A.T. is a kind of sales tax embedded in the price of goods. ... [T]he tax is largely self-enforcing. And because the tax is applied only to consumption, its impact on incentives is minimal (Bartlett 2006).

But is it self-enforcing? Since VATs continue to enter policy discussions, knowledge of how they have or have not worked in countries that have used them can be helpful. According to such analysis by the Financial Times, there are two main problems with the VAT in Europe: fraud and complexity. In an often cited article “Evasion and exemptions erode VAT’s own value added,” the Financial Times (2006) concluded:

In half a century, value added tax has taken the world by storm... But despite its reach, some are ready to declare it an idea whose time has gone…. VAT fraud has become pervasive and, at least in Europe, the tax is at a watershed. Can it survive in its current form? ...[I]t is in Europe that the weaknesses are at their most glaring. This month the European Commission launched an “in-depth debate” on whether VAT should be modified. ... European VAT is in a mess for two main reasons: its vulnerability to fraud and its complexity. Fraud, evasion and avoidance cost at least one in every 10 euros of the tax collected – roughly double that in other industrialised countries... VAT abuse takes many forms – most commonly the reluctance of traders in the black economy to have anything to do with the tax. But the biggest headache is sophisticated fraud (Financial Times 2006).

The problem lies largely in the refund process:

VAT is normally self-policing: everyone in the supply chain has an incentive to act as tax-collectors as they offset the VAT they pay their suppliers against the VAT they charge their customers. But in some circumstances, notably when exporting goods – which are VAT-free under nearly all national systems – businesses can claim refunds. ... This fraud ... has forced governments to consider drastic remedies. ... Germany and Austria are pressing for a “reverse charge” mechanism that would in effect turn VAT into a hybrid sales tax. (Financial Times 2006)

As well as the administrative issues faced by exporters, businesses are often left paying heavy VAT bills as a result of governments’ exemption of certain types of goods and services, such as education, from the tax. As a result, some critics have argued that governments should reduce, if not eliminate, exemptions and reductions.

Conclusion

Proponents of the value-added tax have suggested that VAT might be able to improve economic performance by facilitating a reduction in other taxes, such as personal and corporate income taxes. A broad-based sales tax would almost certainly distort economic choices less than the income tax does. Additionally, an important advantage of the value-added form of sales tax is the fact that tax is collected as products move from stage to stage in the production-distribution process. Thus by the time a product reaches the retail stage, much of its total value has already been taxed.

Theory vs. actual state of affairs

There are obviously two contradicting views on the very basics of VAT. If the VAT was actually used to eliminate all income taxes, this approach would have considerable merit. There is no doubt that personal and corporate income taxes do more damage per dollar raised than a VAT would (Guseh 1977).

However, no nation has ever implemented a VAT (or a national sales tax) and used the money to eliminate all income taxes. Indeed, no government in the world—national, state, provincial, county, or city—has taken this step. No government has even eliminated just one of the two forms of income taxation (personal and corporate). The VAT always has been imposed in addition to existing personal and corporate income taxes (Grier and Tullock 1989).

Faced with this overwhelming real-world evidence, VAT advocates sometimes argue that the tax at least could be used to lower taxes on personal and corporate income. Just like the total replacement hypothesis, this partial-replacement hypothesis is an interesting theory, but it is equally implausible. All available statistics show that the aggregate tax burden on income and profits (a measure of the tax on personal and corporate income) has fallen slightly in the United States, but it has risen significantly in the European Union, and this increased tax burden on productive activity took place after VATs became ubiquitous (Genetski et al 1988).

Considerations from classical economics

Let us seek help to this conundrum from the genuine free-market approach of Jean-Baptiste Say, who contributed considerably more to economics than Say's law. Say was under no illusion that taxation is voluntary nor that government spending contributes productive services to the economy. Say pointed out that, in taxation,

The government exacts from a taxpayer the payment of a given tax in the shape of money. To meet this demand, the taxpayer exchanges part of the products at his disposal for coin, which he pays to the tax-gatherers (Say 1880).

Eventually, the government spends the money on its own needs, so that

in the end . . . this value is consumed; and then the portion of wealth, which passes from the hands of the taxpayer into those of the tax-gatherer, is destroyed and annihilated (Say 1880).

Note, that as is the case with many later economists, such as Murray Rothbard, Say sees that taxation creates two conflicting classes, the taxpayers and the tax-gatherers:

Were it not for taxes, the taxpayer would have spent his money on his own consumption. As it is, the state. . enjoys the satisfaction resulting from that consumption (Say 1880).

Taxation, then, for Say is the transfer of a portion of the national products from the hands of individuals to those of the government, for the purpose of meeting the public consumption of expenditure:

It is virtually a burthen imposed upon individuals, either in a separate or corporate character, by the ruling power... for the purpose of supplying the consumption it may think proper to make at their expense (Say 1880, 446).

But taxation, for Say, is not merely a zero-sum game. By levying a burden on the producers, he points out, "taxes, over time, cripple production itself."

Taxation deprives the producer of a product, which he would otherwise have the option of deriving a personal gratification from, if consumed... or of turning to profit, if he preferred to devote it to an useful employment... Therefore, the subtraction of a product must needs diminish, instead of augmenting, productive power (Say 1880, 447).

J. B. Say's policy recommendation was crystal clear and consistent with his analysis and that of various comments on VAT:

The best scheme of [public] finance is, to spend as little as possible; and the best tax is always the lightest (Say 1880).

To this, there is nothing more to add.

References
ISBN links support NWE through referral fees

  • Bartlett, Bruce. 2005. The Right VATitude National Review Online. Retrieved June 24, 2008.
  • ———. 2006. The Best Kind of Tax The New York Times. Retrieved June 24, 2008.
  • Bickley, James. 2003. A Value-Added Tax Contrasted with a National Sales Tax. Congressional Research Service. Retrieved June 24, 2008.
  • Engen, Eric M. and Jonathan Skinner. 1992. Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 4223.
  • Financial Times. 2006. Evasion and exemptions erode VAT's own value added. Financial Times.
  • Genetski, Robert J., Debra J. Bredael, and Brian S. Wesbury. 1988. The Impact of a Value-Added Tax on the U.S. Economy. Stotler Economics.
  • Grier, Kevin B. and Gordon Tullock. 1989. An Empirical Analysis of Cross-National Economic Growth, 1951–80. Journal of Monetary Economics 24(2):259–276.
  • Guseh, James S. 1997. Government Size and Economic Growth in Developing Countries: A Political-Economy Framework. Journal of Macroeconomics 19(1):175–192.
  • Kesselman, J., Keith Banting, and Ken Battle (eds.). 1994. Public Policies To Combat Child Poverty: Goals and Options. A New Social Vision for Canada? Perspectives on the Federal Discussion Paper on Social Policy Reform. Kingston, CA: Queen’s University, School of Policy Studies. ISBN 0889116873
  • Kesselman, J. 1997. General Payroll Taxes: Economics, Politics, and Design. Toronto, CA: Canadian Tax Foundation. ISBN 0888081219
  • Rothbard, Murray. 1977. Power and Market: Government and the Economy. Kansas City, KS: Sheed Andrews & McMeel. ISBN 0836207505
  • ———. 1981. The Myth of Neutral Taxation. Cato Journal. 1:551–54.
  • ———. 1988. Review of A. Chafuen, Christians for Freedom: Late Scholastic Economics. International Philosophical Quarterly. 28:112–14.
  • ———. 1994. Consumption Tax: A Critique. Review of Austrian Economics. 7(2):75–90.
  • Say, Jean-Baptiste. [1880] 2007. A Treatise on Political Economy, 6th ed. Cosimo Classics. ISBN 978-1602061910
  • Tait, Alan A. 1988. The Value Added Tax: International Practice and Problems. International Monetary Fund. ISBN 978-1557750129

External links

All links retrieved May 3, 2023.


Credits

New World Encyclopedia writers and editors rewrote and completed the Wikipedia article in accordance with New World Encyclopedia standards. This article abides by terms of the Creative Commons CC-by-sa 3.0 License (CC-by-sa), which may be used and disseminated with proper attribution. Credit is due under the terms of this license that can reference both the New World Encyclopedia contributors and the selfless volunteer contributors of the Wikimedia Foundation. To cite this article click here for a list of acceptable citing formats.The history of earlier contributions by wikipedians is accessible to researchers here:

The history of this article since it was imported to New World Encyclopedia:

Note: Some restrictions may apply to use of individual images which are separately licensed.