Bastiat, Claude Frederic

From New World Encyclopedia
({{Contracted}})
 
(26 intermediate revisions by 6 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
[[Category:Politics and social sciences]]
+
[[Category:Economists]]
[[Category:Economics]]
+
{{Images OK}}{{Submitted}}{{Approved}}{{Paid}}{{copyedited}}
{{Claimed}}{{Started}}{{Contracted}}
+
{{epname|Bastiat, Claude Frederic}}
{{epname}}
 
  
 
[[Image:Bastiat.jpg|right|frame|Frédéric Bastiat]]
 
[[Image:Bastiat.jpg|right|frame|Frédéric Bastiat]]
'''Claude Frédéric Bastiat''' (June 30, 1801–December 24, 1850) was a French [[classical liberalism|classical liberal]] theorist, [[political economy|political economist]], and member of the French assembly. He is buried at [[San Luigi dei Francesi]] in [[Rome]] .
+
'''Claude Frédéric Bastiat''' (June 30, 1801 - December 24, 1850) was a [[France|French]] [[economics|economist]], legislator, and writer who championed private [[property]], [[free market]]s, and limited [[government]]. His well known "Candlemakers' petition" cleverly highlights basic flaws in [[protectionism]] and has been used by economists since in defense of free trade. The main underlying theme of Bastiat's writings was that the free market was inherently a source of "economic harmony" among individuals, as long as government was restricted to the function of protecting the lives, liberties, and property of citizens from [[theft]] or [[aggression]]. Bastiat is also seen as a forerunner of the [[Austrian School of economics]] in his works showing the significance of the subjective, human factors in economics. While Bastiat regarded human beings as naturally driven by self-interest, he distinguished this from selfishness, and rather saw human economic exchanges as naturally tending towards that which benefits everyone. Government intervention, thus, Bastiat regarded as likely to disturb the natural harmony in society unless it was limited to protecting its citizens from those who would deliberately do them harm.
 +
{{toc}}
 +
==Biography==
 +
'''Claude Frédéric Bastiat''' was born in Bayonne, Aquitaine, [[France]], on June 30, 1801. When he was nine years old, he was [[orphan]]ed and became a ward of his father's parents. At age seventeen, he left school to become more involved with his family's [[business]].
 +
 
 +
When his grandfather died, Bastiat, at age twenty-five, inherited the family estate in Mugron, which enabled him to live the life of a gentleman farmer and scholar for the next twenty years. Bastiat hired people to operate the family farm so he could concentrate on his intellectual pursuits. He was a voracious reader, and he discussed and debated with friends on virtually all forms of literature. His closest friend was his neighbor, [[Felix Coudroy]], and through his reading and interactions he developed his ideas:
 +
<blockquote>Coudroy and Bastiat, worked their way through a tremendous number of books on philosophy, history, politics, religion, travel, poetry, political economy, biography, and so on…. It was in these conversations that the ideas of Bastiat developed and his thoughts matured (Russell 1969, p. 22-23).</blockquote>
 +
 
 +
Bastiat himself made no original contribution to [[economics]], if readers use "contribution" the way most economists use it. That is, one cannot associate one law, theorem, or path-breaking empirical study with his name. This would have been virtually impossible, since his public career as an economist lasted only five years. Yet, even in this very short time, he made a big contribution: His fresh and witty expressions of economic truths made them so understandable and compelling that the truths became hard to ignore, and—because of his stress on the role of consumer demand in initiating economic progress—Bastiat has been described by many great economists, among them [[F.A. Hayek]], as a forerunner of the [[Austrian School]].
 +
 
 +
At the end, Bastiat contracted [[tuberculosis]], probably during his tours throughout France to promote libertarian ideas. That illness eventually prevented him from making further speeches (particularly at the legislative assembly to which he was elected in 1848 and 1849) and took his life. Bastiat died in [[Rome]] on December 24, 1850.
 +
 
 +
== Views and ideas==
 +
===Forerunner of the Austrian School===
 +
Bastiat emphasized the plan-coordination function of the free [[market]], a major theme of the [[Austrian School]], because his thinking was influenced by some of [[Adam Smith]]'s writings and by the great French free-market economists [[Jean-Baptiste Say]], [[Francois Quesnay]], [[Destutt de Tracy]], [[Charles Comte]], [[Richard Cantillon]] (who was born in Ireland and emigrated to France), and [[Anne-Robert-Jacques Turgot]].
 +
 
 +
These French economists were among the precursors to the modern Austrian School. They first developed such concepts as the market as a dynamic, rivalrous process, the free-market evolution of [[money]], subjective value theory, the laws of diminishing [[marginal utility]] and marginal returns, the marginal productivity theory of resource pricing, and the futility of price controls in particular and of the government's economic interventionism in general.
 +
 
 +
In his ''Economic Harmonies,'' Bastiat stated:
 +
<blockquote>We cannot doubt that self-interest is the mainspring of human nature. It must be clearly understood that this word is used here to designate a universal, incontestable fact, resulting from the nature of man, and not an adverse judgment, as would be the word selfishness (1850).</blockquote>
 +
 
 +
Thornton (2002) posits that Bastiat, through taking this position on the motivations of human action, demonstrates a pronounced "Austrian flavor.”
 +
 
 +
==="Full picture" rule ===
 +
One of Bastiat's most important contributions to the field of [[economics]] was his admonition to the effect that good economic decisions can only be made by taking into account the "full picture." That is, economic truths should be arrived at by observing not only the immediate consequences—that is, benefits or liabilities—of an economic decision, but also by examining the long-term consequences. Additionally, one must examine the decision's effect not only on a single group of people (say candlemakers) or a single [[industry]] (say candles), but on all people and all industries in the [[society]] as a whole.
 +
 +
As Bastiat famously put it, an economist must take into account both "What is seen and what is not seen." Bastiat's "rule" was later expounded and developed by [[Henry Hazlitt]] in his work, ''Economics in One Lesson,'' in which Hazlitt borrowed Bastiat's polemics used in his "Broken Window Fallacy" and went on to demonstrate how it applies to a wide variety of economic falsehoods. As [[Friedrich von Hayek]] wrote:
 +
<blockquote>Nothing illustrates this better than the celebrated title of the first essay in the present volume. "What is seen and what is not seen in political economy." No one has ever stated more clearly in a single phrase the central difficulty of a rational economic policy and, I would like to add, the decisive argument for economic freedom. It is the idea compressed into these few words that made me use the word "genius" in the opening sentence. It is indeed a text around which one might expound a whole system of libertarian economic policy (F.A. Hayek 1848 in the introduction to Bastiat’s ''Selected Essays on Political Economy'').
 +
</blockquote>
 +
 
 +
==Work==
 +
Bastiat's first published article appeared in April of 1834. It was a response to a petition by the merchants of Bordeaux, Le Havre, and Lyons to eliminate [[tariff]]s on [[agriculture|agricultural]] products but to maintain them on [[manufacturing|manufactured]] goods. Bastiat praised the merchants for their position on agricultural products, but excoriated them for their hypocrisy in wanting [[protectionism]] for themselves. "You demand privilege for a few," he wrote, whereas "I demand liberty for all" (Russell 1969, p. 24). He then explained why all tariffs should be abolished completely.
  
==Biography==
+
Bastiat continued to hone his arguments in favor of economic freedom by writing a second essay in opposition to all domestic taxes on wine, entitled "The Tax and the Vine," and a third essay opposing all taxes on land and all forms of trade restrictions.  
Bastiat was born in [[Bayonne]], [[Aquitaine]], [[France]]. When he was nine years old, he was orphaned and became a ward of his father's parents. At age seventeen he left school to become more involved with his family's business as an [[exporter]]. Economist [[Thomas DiLorenzo]] suggests that this family business experience was crucial to Bastiat's later work because it allowed young Frédéric to acquire first-hand knowledge of some of the effects of trade regulations on the market.<ref name="DiLorenzo">DiLorenzo, Thomas. "Frederic Bastiat (1801-1850): Between the French and Marginalist Revolutions." ''Mises.org''.[http://www.mises.org/fredericbastiat.asp]</ref> [[Sheldon Richman]] notes that "he came of age during the [[Napoleonic wars]], with their extensive government intervention in economic affairs."<ref name="Richman">Richman, Sheldon. "Frédéric Bastiat: An Annotated Bibliography." The Library of Economics and Liberty. 2000. [http://www.econlib.org/library/Bastiat/BastiatBib.html]</ref>
 
  
When Bastiat was twenty-five, his grandfather and benefactor died, leaving the young man the family estate and providing him with the means to further his own theoretical inquiries. His areas of intellectual interest were diverse, including "[[philosophy]], [[history]], [[politics]], [[religion]], [[travel]], [[poetry]], [[political economy]], <nowiki>[and]</nowiki> [[biography]]."<ref name="DiLorenzo" />
+
Then, in the summer of 1844, Bastiat sent an unsolicited manuscript on the effects of French and English tariffs to the most prestigious economics journal in France, the ''Journal des Economistes''. The editors published the article, "The Influence of English and French Tariffs," in the October 1844 issue, and it unquestionably became the most persuasive argument for free trade in particular, and for economic freedom in general, that had ever appeared in France, if not all of Europe.
  
His public career as an economist began only in 1844, and was cut short by his untimely death in 1850. Bastiat had contracted [[tuberculosis]], probably during his tours throughout France to promote [[libertarian]] ideas, and that illness eventually prevented him from making further speeches (particularly at the legislative assembly to which he was elected in 1848 and 1849) and took his life. Bastiat died in [[Rome]] on December 24, 1850. He declared on his death bed that his friend [[Gustave de Molinari]] (publisher of Bastiat's masterpiece ''[[The Law (1849 book)|The Law]]'' in 1849) was his spiritual heir.
+
While Bastiat was shaping economic opinion in France, [[Karl Marx]] was writing ''Das Kapital,'' and the [[socialism|socialist]] notion of "class conflict" that the economic gains of [[capitalism|capitalists]] necessarily came at the expense of workers was gaining in popularity. Bastiat's second major work, ''Economic Harmonies,'' by way of contrast, explained that the interests of humankind are essentially harmonious if they can be cultivated in a free society where government confines its responsibilities to suppressing [[theft|thieves]], [[murder]]ers, and special-interest groups who seek to use the state as a means of plundering their fellow citizens.
  
== Views ==
+
Bastiat contributed to Austrian capital theory by masterfully explaining how the accumulation of [[capital]] results in the enrichment of the workers by raising labor's marginal productivity and, consequently, its remuneration. Capital accumulation, wrote Bastiat, would also result in cheaper and better quality consumer goods, which would also raise real wages. He also explained how the [[interest]] on capital declines as it becomes more plentiful.
Bastiat can be said to be of the "Harmonic" school of [[libertarians]], who consider [[utilitarian]] and [[natural law]] arguments as two complementary aspects of a same world. Bastiat did not take part in the [[anarchism|anarchist]]-[[minarchism|minarchist]] debate (arguably, he died too early for that); he seems to have considered the State as something inevitable as far as immediate practical matter&mdash;something that ought to be taken into account as long as it existed.  However, like all classical liberals, Bastiat maintained a deep distrust of all government, in any form, and worked all his life to demonstrate that government control of private individuals and regulation of private industry was inefficient, economically damaging, and morally wrong.
 
  
 +
Thus, in his view, the interests of capitalists and labor are indeed harmonious, and government interventions into capital markets will impoverish the workers as well as the owners of capital. Bastiat also explained why in a free market no one can accumulate capital unless he uses it in a way that benefits others, namely the consumers.
  
Because of his stress on the role of consumer demand in initiating economic progress, Bastiat has been described by [[Mark Thornton]], [[Thomas DiLorenzo]]<ref name="DiLorenzo" />, and other economists as a forerunner of the [[Austrian School]]. In his ''Economic Harmonies'', Bastiat states that,
+
In reality, wrote Bastiat, capital is always used to satisfy the desires of people who do not own it. In sharp contrast to most of his predecessors, Bastiat believed that "it is necessary to view economics from the viewpoint of the consumer. … All economic phenomena … must be judged by the advantages and disadvantages they bring to the consumer" (Bastiat 1848, Selected Essays, p. 1-50).
:''We cannot doubt that self-interest is the mainspring of human nature. It must be clearly understood that this word is used here to designate a universal, incontestable fact, resulting from the nature of man, and not an adverse judgment, as would be the word selfishness.''
 
Thornton posits that Bastiat, through taking this position on the motivations of human action, demonstrates a pronounced "Austrian flavor."<ref name="Thornton">Thornton, Mark. "Frédéric Bastiat as an Austrian Economist." ''Mises.org''. [http://www.mises.org/journals/scholar/BastiatAustrian.pdf .PDF]</ref>
 
  
One of Bastiat's most important contributions to the field of economics was his admonition to the effect that good economic decisions can only be made by taking into account the "full picture."  That is, economic truths should be arrived at by observing not only the immediate consequences — that is,  benefits or liabilities — of an economic decision, but also by examining the long-term consequences.  Additionally, one must examine the decision's effect not only on a single group of people (say candlemakers) or a single industry (say candles), but on all people and all industries in the society as a whole.  As Bastiat famously put it, an economist must take into account both "What is Seen and What is Not Seen.Bastiat's "rule" was later expounded and developed by [[Henry Hazlitt]] in his work ''[[Economics in One Lesson]],'' in which Hazlitt borrowed Bastiat's trenchant "[[parable of the broken window|Broken Window Fallacy]]" and went on to demonstrate how it applies to a wide variety of economic falsehoods.
+
Bastiat's greatest contribution to subjective value theory was how he rigorously applied the theory in his essay, "What is Seen and What is Not Seen" (Bastiat 1848, p. 1-50). In that essay, Bastiat, by relentlessly focusing on the hidden opportunity costs of governmental resource allocation, destroyed the notion that government spending can create jobs and [[wealth]].  
  
== Works ==
+
=== ''Economic Sophisms'' ===
Bastiat was the author of many works on economics and political economy, generally characterized by their clear organization, forceful argumentation, and acerbic wit.  Among his most well known works is ''[http://www.econlib.org/library/Bastiat/basSoph.html  Economic Sophisms],'' which contains many strongly-worded attacks on [[statism|statist]] policies.  Bastiat wrote it while living in [[England]] to advise the shapers of the French Republic on pitfalls to avoid.
+
His first book, ''Economic Sophisms'' (Bastiat 1845), is to this day still arguably the best literary defense of free trade available. In this work, Bastiat masterfully created the most complete case for free trade ever constructed up to that time, which applied such economic concepts as the mutual advantage of voluntary trade, the law of comparative advantage, the benefits of [[competition]] to the producer as well as the consumer, and the historical link between trade barriers and [[war]].  
  
Contained within ''Economic Sophisms'' is the famous [[satire|satirical]] parable known as the "[[Candlemakers' petition]]" [http://silentpc.org/university/Candlemaker.pdf (pdf)] which presents itself as a demand from the candlemakers' guild to the French government, asking the government to block out [[Sun|the Sun]] to prevent its unfair competition with their products.  Much like [[Jonathan Swift]]'s ''[[A Modest Proposal]]'' or [[Benjamin Franklin]]'s anti-slavery works, Bastiat's argument cleverly highlights basic flaws in [[protectionism]] by demonstrating its absurdity through logical extremes.
+
Contained within ''Economic Sophisms'' is the famous [[satire|satirical]] parable known as the "[[Claude Frederic Bastiat#Candlemakers' petition|Candlemakers' petition]]" which presents itself as a demand from the candlemakers' [[guild]] to the French government. In this "petition," the candlemakers cite several economic "advantages" that might be had from blocking out the Sun, by increasing consumption of products: [[tallow]], leading to the increased production of meat, wool, hides, and so on; [[vegetable oil]], leading to the increased production of [[poppy|poppies]], [[olive]]s, and [[rapeseed]]; [[resin]]ous trees, leading to more [[bee]]s, hence crop pollination; [[whale oil]], leading to a larger [[merchant navy]] that would boost France's prestige and standing. Bastiat's argument cleverly highlights basic flaws in [[protectionism]] by demonstrating its absurdity through logical extremes.
  
Bastiat's most famous work, however, is undoubtedly ''[http://www.ozarkia.net/bill/anarchism/library/thelaw.html The Law]'', originally published as a pamphlet in 1850.  It defines, through development, a just system of laws and then demonstrates how such law facilitates a free society.
+
Free trade, Bastiat explained, would mean
 +
<blockquote>…an abundance of goods and services at lower prices; more jobs for more people at higher real wages; more profits for manufacturers; a higher level of living for farmers; more income to the state in the form of taxes at the customary or lower levels; the most productive use of capital, labor, and natural resources; the end of the "class struggle … was based primarily on such economic injustices as tariffs, monopolies, and other legal distortions of the market; the end of the "suicidal policy" of colonialism; the abolition of war as a national policy; and the best possible education, housing, and medical care for all the people (Russell 1969, p. 42).</blockquote>
  
== Bastiat's Negative Railroad ==
+
====Candlemakers’ Petition====
A famous section of ''Economic Sophisms'' concerns the way that tariffs are inherently counterproductive.  Bastiat posits a theoretical railway between Spain and France that is built in order to reduce the costs of trade between the two countries.  This is achieved, of course, by making goods move to and from the two nations faster and more easily.  Bastiat demonstrates that this situation benefits both countries' consumers because it reduces the cost of shipping goods, and therefore reduces the price at market for those goods. 
 
  
However, each country's producers begin to rail at their governments because the other country's producers can now provide certain goods to the domestic market at reduced price. Domestic producers of these goods are afraid of being out-competed by the newly viable industry from the other country. So, these domestic producers demand that tariffs be enacted to artificially raise the cost of the foreign goods back to their pre-railroad levels, so that they can continue to compete.
+
In this same book, ''Economic Sophisms,'' one can find probably of the most famous documents in the history of free-trade literature—Bastiat’s famous “Candlemakers’ Petition.” In that parody, Bastiat imagined the makers of candles and street lamps petitioning the French Chamber of Deputies for protection from a most dastardly foreign competitor:
 +
<blockquote>You are on the right track. You reject abstract theories and have little regard for abundance and low prices. You concern yourselves mainly with the fate of the producer. You wish to free him from foreign competition, that is, to reserve the domestic market for domestic industry (Bastiat 1845).</blockquote>
  
Bastiat raises two significant points here:
+
The argument continues in fully legal and economically sound discourse:
 +
<blockquote>We come to offer you a wonderful opportunity. …we are suffering from the ruinous competition of a rival who apparently works under conditions so far superior to our own for the production of light that he is flooding the domestic market with it at an incredibly low price; for the moment he appears, our sales cease, all the consumers turn to him, and a branch of French industry whose ramifications are innumerable is all at once reduced to complete stagnation. This rival … is none other than the sun (Ibid., 1845).</blockquote>
  
# Even if the producers in a society are benefitted by these tariffs (which, Bastiat claims, they are not), the consumers in that society are clearly hurt by the tariffs, as they are now unable to secure the goods they want at the low price they should be able to secure them at. 
+
For after all, Bastiat’s petitioners noted, how can the makers of candles and lanterns compete with a light source that is totally free?
# The tariffs completely negate any gains made by the railroad and therefore make it essentially pointless.
 
  
To further demonstrate his points, Bastiat suggests that, rather than enacting tariffs, the government should simply destroy the railroad anywhere that foreign goods can outcompete local goods. Since this would be just about everywhere, he goes on to suggest that that government should simply build a broken or "negative" railroad right from the start, and not waste time with tariffs and rail building.  This is an example of Bastiat's consummate skill with the ''reductio ad absurdum'' rhetorical technique.  Indeed, we can take Bastiat's argument even farther and see that, by examining everything from the perspective of the producer, society would be "best" if we were regressed to a cave-man state where supply of goods was at maximum scarcity.  Then people would have to work as hard as possible for as little as possible and never have to fear outside competition.
+
As a response to this publication, in 1846, Bastiat was elected a corresponding member of the French Academy of Science, and his work was immediately translated into English, Spanish, Italian, and German. Free-trade associations soon began to sprout up in Belgium, Italy, Sweden, Prussia, and Germany, and were all based on Bastiat's French Free Trade Association.
  
In short, the thrust of Bastiat's negative railroad hinges on two major points:  
+
===''Economic Harmonies''===
 +
In his second book, ''Economic Harmonies'' (Bastiat 1850) and subsequent articles, reprinted in newspapers and magazines all over France, Bastiat described economics as an intellectual endeavor in the way which is virtually identical to what modern Austrians call the science of human action, or praxaeology. Bastiat wrote in his ''Harmonies:''
 +
<blockquote>The subject of political economy is MAN … [who is] endowed with the ability to compare, judge, choose, and act…. This faculty … to work for each other, to transmit their efforts and to exchange their services through time and space … is precisely what constitutes Economic Science (Bastiat, 1850, p. 35).</blockquote>
  
# All economic decisions should be made with the consumer in mind. (This is central to Bastiat's ideas)
+
As with contemporary Austrians, Bastiat viewed economics as
# Tariffs serve no purpose but to negate the gains provided to society by technology, labor, ingenuity, determination and progress.
+
<blockquote>the Theory of Exchange where the desires of market participants cannot be weighed or measured…. Exchange is necessary in order to determine value (Bastiat, 1850, p. 36).</blockquote>
  
An important corollary to these conclusions is that the power that consumers wield with any governing body, while theoretically tremendous, is extremely diffuse.  Producers, on the other hand, while not as powerful on the whole as the sum total of consumers, have the ability to consolidate their power in ways that make it much more attractive for governing bodies to service their needs.  Thus, while consumers could theoretically shut down an entire industry (or government) by refusing to buy/sell/do something, the likelihood of the great mass of people organizing in this way for any reason whatever is so infinitesimal as to be practically impossible.  Producers, on the other hand, are able to threaten or cajole the government with shutting down a single industry, with reductions in political and financial contributions to the government agents who make certain decisions, &c.  It is for this reason that governments are much more likely to pander to the desires of producers than to consumers, and it is for this reason, Bastiat concludes, that governments are inherently adversarial to the interests of the people as a whole.  Indeed, they are even adversarial, in some way, to the interests of the producers themselves, as the producers of one good or service are still consumers of all the other goods and services.
+
Thus, to Bastiat, as with contemporary Austrians, '''value is subjective,''' and the only way of knowing how people value things is through their demonstrated preferences as revealed in market exchanges.  
  
== Selected quotations ==
+
Voluntary exchange, therefore, is necessarily mutually advantageous. This was an important theoretical innovation in the history of economic theory, for many of the British economists had succumbed to the "physical fallacy"—the misguided notion that value is determined by the production of physical objects alone.
* "If the natural tendencies of mankind are so bad that it is not safe to permit people to be free, how is it that the tendencies of these organizers are always good? Do not the legislators and their appointed agents also belong to the human race? Or do they believe that they themselves are made of a finer clay than the rest of mankind?"&mdash;from ''The Law''
 
  
* "Life, faculties, production—in other words, individuality, liberty, property—this is man. And in spite of the cunning of artful political leaders, these three gifts from God precede all human legislation, and are superior to it. Life, liberty, and property do not exist because men have made laws. On the contrary, it was the fact that life, liberty, and property existed beforehand that caused men to make laws in the first place."&mdash;from ''The Law''
+
The understanding that value is created by voluntary exchange, [[Murray Rothbard]] pointed out, "led Bastiat and the French school to stress the ways in which the free market leads to a smooth and harmonious organization of the economy" (Rothbard 1995, p. 446).
  
* "Government is the great fiction through which everybody endeavors to live at the expense of everybody else."&mdash;from ''Government''
+
=== Economy vs. state vs. law ===
 +
Bastiat is perhaps best known for his work in the field of political economy—the study of the interaction between the [[economy]] and the [[state]]—as opposed to pure economic theory. He sought to understand how the state operated and by what incentives it was driven, and he did so as well as anyone ever has.  
  
* "But how is this legal plunder to be identified? Quite simply. See if the law takes from some persons what belongs to them, and gives it to other persons to whom it does not belong. See if the law benefits one citizen at the expense of another by doing what the citizen himself cannot do without committing a crime."&mdash;from ''The Law''
+
Government was necessary, according to Bastiat, but only if restricted to its "essential" functions. He believed that "no society can exist unless the laws are respected to a certain degree, but at the same time that could only occur if the laws themselves were respectable” (Russell 1969, p. 5).
  
* "If socialists mean that under extraordinary circumstances, for urgent cases, the state should set aside some resources to assist certain unfortunate people, to help them adjust to changing conditions, we will, of course, agree. This is done now; we desire that it be done better.  There is however, a point on this road that must not be passed; it is the point where governmental foresight would step in to replace individual foresight and thus destroy it."&mdash;from ''Journal des Economistes''
+
The moral justification for a [[law]], moreover, can never be based on a majority vote, because "since no individual has the right to enslave another individual, then no group of individuals can possibly have such a right" (Russell 1969, p. 6). All income redistribution through majoritarian democracy is therefore "legal plunder" and is, by definition, immoral.
  
* "Socialism, like the ancient ideas from which it springs, confuses the distinction between government and society. As a result of this, every time we object to a thing being done by government, the socialists conclude that we object to its being done at all. We disapprove of state education. Then the socialists say that we are opposed to any education. We object to a state religion. Then the socialists say that we want no religion at all. We object to a state-enforced equality. Then they say that we are against equality. And so on, and so on. It is as if the socialists were to accuse us of not wanting persons to eat because we do not want the state to raise grain."&mdash;from ''The Law''
+
Bastiat understood that free-market competition was a "dynamic discovery procedure," in which individuals strove to coordinate their plans to achieve their economic goals. All forms of government intervention interrupt and distort that process because once a law or regulation is issued, "the people no longer need to discuss, to compare, to plan ahead; the law does all this for them. Intelligence becomes a useless prop for the people; they cease to be men; they lose their personality, their liberty, their property" (Russell 1969, p. 11).
  
* "[The socialists declare] that the state owes subsistence, well-being, and education to all its citizens; that it should be generous, charitable, involved in everything, devoted to everybody; ...that it should intervene directly to relieve all suffering, satisfy and anticipate all wants, furnish capital to all enterprises, enlightenment to all minds, balm for all wounds, asylums for all the unfortunate, and even aid to the point of shedding French blood, for all oppressed people on the face of the earth.<br/>Who would not like to see all these benefits flow forth upon the world from the law, as from an inexhaustible source? ...But is it possible? ...Whence does [the state] draw those resources that it is urged to dispense by way of benefits to individuals? Is it not from the individuals themselves? How, then, can these resources be increased by passing through the hands of a parasitical and voracious intermediary?<br/>...Finally...we shall see the entire people transformed into petitioners. Landed property, agriculture, industry, commerce, shipping, industrial companies, all will bestir themselves to claim favors from the state. The public treasury will be literally pillaged. Everyone will have good reasons to prove that legal [[Libert%C3%A9%2C_%C3%A9galit%C3%A9%2C_fraternit%C3%A9|fraternity]] should be interpreted in this sense: "Let me have the benefits, and let others pay the costs." Everyone's effort will be directed toward snatching a scrap of fraternal privilege from the legislature. The suffering classes, although having the greatest claim, will not always have the greatest success."&mdash;from ''Journal des Economistes''
+
The following quotation on the question of economy and the government legislation round up his views on the overall societal problems between the state and the general population:
 +
<blockquote>If the natural tendencies of mankind are so bad that it is not safe to permit people to be free, how is it that the tendencies of these organizers are always good? Do not the legislators and their appointed agents also belong to the human race? Or do they believe that they themselves are made of a finer clay than the rest of mankind? …Life, faculties, production—in other words, individuality, liberty, property—this is man. And in spite of the cunning of artful political leaders, these three gifts from God precede all human legislation, and are superior to it. Life, liberty, and property do not exist because men have made laws. On the contrary, it was the fact that life, liberty, and property existed beforehand that caused men to make laws in the first place (Bastiat, 1850).</blockquote>
  
* "Either [[Libert%C3%A9%2C_%C3%A9galit%C3%A9%2C_fraternit%C3%A9|fraternity]] is spontaneous, or it does not exist. To decree it is to annihilate it. The law can indeed force men to remain just; in vain would it would try to force them to be self-sacrificing."&mdash;from ''Journal des Economistes''
+
==Legacy==
 +
Bastiat's writing constitutes an intellectual bridge between the ideas of the pre-[[Austrian School|Austrian]] economists, such as [[Jean-Baptiste Say|Say]], [[Richard Cantillon|Cantillon]], [[Anne-Robert-Jacques Turgot|Turgot]], and [[Francois Quesnay|Quesnay]], and the Austrian tradition of [[Carl Menger]] and his students.  
  
* "When under the pretext of [[Libert%C3%A9%2C_%C3%A9galit%C3%A9%2C_fraternit%C3%A9|fraternity]], the legal code imposes mutual sacrifices on the citizens, human nature is not thereby abrogated. Everyone will then direct his efforts toward contributing little to, and taking much from, the common fund of sacrifices. Now, is it the most unfortunate who gains from this struggle? Certainly not, but rather the most influential and calculating."&mdash;from ''The Law''
+
He was also a model of scholarship for those Austrians who believed that general economic education, especially the kind of economic education that shatters the myriad myths and superstitions created by the state and its intellectual apologists, is an essential function (if not duty) of the economist. [[Ludwig von Mises]] was a superb follower in this regard, as were [[Henry Hazlitt]] and [[Murray Rothbard]], among others.  
  
* "It seems to me that this is theoretically right, for whatever the question under discussion—whether religious, philosophical, political, or economic; whether it concerns prosperity, morality, equality, right, justice, progress, responsibility, cooperation, property, labor, trade, capital, wages, taxes, population, finance, or government&mdash;at whatever point on the scientific horizon I begin my researches, I invariably reach this one conclusion: The solution to the problems of human relationships is to be found in liberty."&mdash;from ''The Law''
+
As Mises said, the early economists
 +
<blockquote>…devoted themselves to the study of the problems of economics … [and in] lecturing and writing books they were eager to communicate to their fellow citizens the results of their thinking. They tried to influence public opinion in order to make sound policies prevail (von Mises 1963, p.869).</blockquote>
  
* "Try to imagine a regulation of labor imposed by force that is not a violation of liberty; a transfer of wealth imposed by force that is not a violation of property. If you cannot reconcile these contradictions, then you must conclude that the law cannot organize labor and industry without organizing injustice."&mdash;from ''The Law''
+
Henry Hazlitt wrote that:
 +
<blockquote>My greatest debt, with respect to the kind of expository framework on which the present argument is hung, is Frederic Bastiat's essay, "What is Seen and What is Not Seen." The present work may, in fact, be regarded as a modernization, extension, and generalization of the approach found in Bastiat (Hazlitt, 1946, p. 1).</blockquote>
  
 +
To this day, Bastiat's work is not appreciated as much as it should be because, as Murray Rothbard explained, today's intemperate critics of economic freedom "find it difficult to believe that anyone who is ardently and consistently in favor of laissez-faire could possibly be an important scholar and economic theorist" (Rothbard 1995, p. 449). For Bastiat, indeed, believed in market forces as capable of maintaining a healthy economy. To Bastiat, governmental coercion was only legitimate if it served "to guarantee security of person, liberty, and property rights, to cause justice to reign over all" (Bastiat 1995, p. 52).
  
==Notes==
+
Therefore, it is, perhaps, not surprising that even some contemporary Austrian economists seem to believe that the act of communicating economic ideas especially economic policy ideas to the general public is somehow unworthy of a practitioner of "economic science." For that is exactly the model of scholarship that Mises himself adopted, which was carried forward most aggressively and brilliantly by Murray Rothbard, all in the tradition of the great French Austrian economist, Frederic Bastiat.
<references />
 
  
==Bastiat in English translation==
+
==Major publications==    
*1869 (1849). ''[http://bastiat.org/en/capital_and_interest.html Capital and Interest.]'' Translator unknown.
+
*Bastiat, F. [1845] 1996. "Economic Sophisms." In ''Foundation for Economic Education''. New York: Irvington-on-Hudson.
The following titles were originally published by the [[Foundation for Economic Education]] in Irvington-on-Hudson, NY, and are made available online by [http://www.econlib.org/index.html The Library of Economics and Liberty.]
+
*Bastiat, F. [1848] 1995. "Selected Essays on Political Economy." In ''Foundation for Economic Education''. New York: Irvington-on-Hudson.
*1996 (1845). ''[http://www.econlib.org/library/Bastiat/basSoph.html Economic Sophisms,]'' trans. and ed. by Arthur Goddard, with introduction by [[Henry Hazlitt]].
+
*Bastiat F. [1849] 1996. "Capital and Interest." In ''Foundation for Economic Education''. New York: Irvington-on-Hudson.
*1995 (1848). ''[http://www.econlib.org/library/Bastiat/basEss.html Selected Essays on Political Economy,]'' trans. by Seymour Cain; George B. de Huszar, ed., with introduction by [[Friedrich Hayek]].
+
*Bastiat F. [1849] 1996. "The Law" in ''Foundation for Economic Education''. New York: Irvington-on-Hudson.
*1995 (1850). ''[http://www.econlib.org/library/Bastiat/basEss2.html The Law,]'' trans. by Seymour Cain, with introduction by George B. de Huszar.  
+
*Bastiat, F. [1850] 1996. "Economic Harmonie" in ''Foundation for Economic Education''. New York: Irvington-on-Hudson.
*1998 (1850). ''[ The Law,]'' trans. by Dean Russell, with introduction by [[Walter E. Williams]] and foreword by [[Sheldon Richman]].
 
*1996 (1850). ''[http://www.econlib.org/library/Bastiat/basHar.html Economic Harmonies,]'' trans. by W. Hayden Boyers; George B. de Huszar, ed., with introduction by Dean Russell.
 
  
 
==References==
 
==References==
*[[Sheldon Richman]], 2000, "[http://www.econlib.org/library/Bastiat/basHar.html Annotated Bibliography,]" The Library of Economics and Liberty. Actually a biographical essay and an introduction to Bastiat's work.
+
*Hazlitt, H. 1946. "Economics in One Lesson." In ''Harper and Brothers''. New York.
 +
*Mises, L. 1963. ''Human Action: A Treatise on Economics''. Chicago: Henry Regnery.
 +
*Rothbard, M. 1995. "Classical Economics. Vol. 2. An Austrian Perspective on the History of Economic Thought." In ''Edward Elgar''. Cheltenham, U.K.
 +
*Russell, D. 1969. "Frédérick Bastiat: Ideas and Influence." In ''Foundation for Economic Education''. New York: Irvington-on-Hudson.
 +
*Thornton, Mark. 2002. [http://www.mises.org/journals/qjae/pdf/qjae5_3_6.pdf "Frederic Bastiat's Views on the Nature of Money."] In ''The Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics''. 5, No. 3: 81–86. Retrieved October 18, 2007.
  
 
== External links ==
 
== External links ==
 
+
All links retrieved December 19, 2023.
 +
*[http://Bastiat.org/ Bastiat.org] all about Bastiat.
 +
*[http://www.mises.org/journals/qjae/pdf/qjae4_4_3.pdf Bastiat's Legacy in Economics] by Jorg Guido Hulsmann.
 +
*[http://bastiat.org/en/petition.html Candlemakers Petition], as translated into English.
 +
*[http://bastiat.org/fr/petition.html Candlemakers Petition], in French.
 +
*[http://www.newadvent.org/cathen/02345b.htm Catholic Encyclopedia article].
 +
*[http://www.mondopolitico.com/library/thelaw/mpintro.htm Mondo Politico Library's presentation of Frederic Bastiat's book, ''The Law'' (Dean Russell translation; full text; formatted for easy on-screen reading)].
 +
*[http://bastiat.org/en/twisatwins.html "That which is seen, and that which is not seen"].
 +
*[http://www.mises.org/books/thelaw.pdf The Law].
 
*{{gutenberg author|id=Bastiat|name=Frédéric Bastiat}}
 
*{{gutenberg author|id=Bastiat|name=Frédéric Bastiat}}
* [http://www.mondopolitico.com/library/thelaw/mpintro.htm Mondo Politico Library's presentation of Frederic Bastiat's book, ''The Law'' (Dean Russell translation; full text; formatted for easy on-screen reading)]
 
* [http://www.freeaudio.org FreeAudio.org's] free audio book of [http://www.freeaudio.org/fbastiat/thelaw.html ''The Law''].
 
* The [http://www.econlib.org/ Library of Economics and Liberty] publishes most English translations of his works.
 
* [http://Bastiat.org/ Bastiat.org] publishes or indexes all about Bastiat.
 
* [http://bastiat.org/en/twisatwins.html text of "That which is seen, and that which is not seen".]
 
* [http://Bastiat.net/ The Cercle Frederic Bastiat] also publishes about Bastiat, and promotes the same tradition of libertarianism.
 
* [http://www.udesa.edu.ar/profesores/deptoeconomia/cruces/fun/bastiat_en.html The Candlemakers' Petition - English translation]
 
* [http://www.freeaudio.org/fbastiat/candlemakerspetition.html The Candlemakers' Petition - Audio Book] at [http://www.freeaudio.org/ FreeAudio.org]
 
* [http://www.liberal-international.org/library/bastiat.html Biography with Literature index]
 
* [http://www.newadvent.org/cathen/02345b.htm Catholic Encyclopedia article]
 
*[http://www.mises.org/books/thelaw.pdf The Law] - pdf format
 
*[http://mises.org/content/bastiat200.asp Frédéric Bastiat: Two Hundred Years On] by Joseph R. Stromberg
 
*[http://www.mises.org/journals/qjae/pdf/qjae4_4_3.pdf Bastiat's Legacy in Economics] by Jorg Guido Hulsmann
 
*[http://www.mises.org/journals/qjae/pdf/qjae5_3_6.pdf Frederic Bastiat's Views on the Nature of Money] by [[Mark Thornton]]
 
*[http://www.lewrockwell.com/orig7/neglect-bastiat.html How English-speaking economists have neglected Bastiat] by [[Joseph Salerno]]
 
* [http://silentpc.org/university/bastiat.php Selection of C. F. Bastiat quotes with editorial comments] by Allan R. Wallace, Rector of [[Bastiat Free University]]
 
 
  
  
 
{{Credits|Frédéric_Bastiat|118960629|}}
 
{{Credits|Frédéric_Bastiat|118960629|}}

Latest revision as of 10:54, 19 December 2023


Frédéric Bastiat

Claude Frédéric Bastiat (June 30, 1801 - December 24, 1850) was a French economist, legislator, and writer who championed private property, free markets, and limited government. His well known "Candlemakers' petition" cleverly highlights basic flaws in protectionism and has been used by economists since in defense of free trade. The main underlying theme of Bastiat's writings was that the free market was inherently a source of "economic harmony" among individuals, as long as government was restricted to the function of protecting the lives, liberties, and property of citizens from theft or aggression. Bastiat is also seen as a forerunner of the Austrian School of economics in his works showing the significance of the subjective, human factors in economics. While Bastiat regarded human beings as naturally driven by self-interest, he distinguished this from selfishness, and rather saw human economic exchanges as naturally tending towards that which benefits everyone. Government intervention, thus, Bastiat regarded as likely to disturb the natural harmony in society unless it was limited to protecting its citizens from those who would deliberately do them harm.

Biography

Claude Frédéric Bastiat was born in Bayonne, Aquitaine, France, on June 30, 1801. When he was nine years old, he was orphaned and became a ward of his father's parents. At age seventeen, he left school to become more involved with his family's business.

When his grandfather died, Bastiat, at age twenty-five, inherited the family estate in Mugron, which enabled him to live the life of a gentleman farmer and scholar for the next twenty years. Bastiat hired people to operate the family farm so he could concentrate on his intellectual pursuits. He was a voracious reader, and he discussed and debated with friends on virtually all forms of literature. His closest friend was his neighbor, Felix Coudroy, and through his reading and interactions he developed his ideas:

Coudroy and Bastiat, worked their way through a tremendous number of books on philosophy, history, politics, religion, travel, poetry, political economy, biography, and so on…. It was in these conversations that the ideas of Bastiat developed and his thoughts matured (Russell 1969, p. 22-23).

Bastiat himself made no original contribution to economics, if readers use "contribution" the way most economists use it. That is, one cannot associate one law, theorem, or path-breaking empirical study with his name. This would have been virtually impossible, since his public career as an economist lasted only five years. Yet, even in this very short time, he made a big contribution: His fresh and witty expressions of economic truths made them so understandable and compelling that the truths became hard to ignore, and—because of his stress on the role of consumer demand in initiating economic progress—Bastiat has been described by many great economists, among them F.A. Hayek, as a forerunner of the Austrian School.

At the end, Bastiat contracted tuberculosis, probably during his tours throughout France to promote libertarian ideas. That illness eventually prevented him from making further speeches (particularly at the legislative assembly to which he was elected in 1848 and 1849) and took his life. Bastiat died in Rome on December 24, 1850.

Views and ideas

Forerunner of the Austrian School

Bastiat emphasized the plan-coordination function of the free market, a major theme of the Austrian School, because his thinking was influenced by some of Adam Smith's writings and by the great French free-market economists Jean-Baptiste Say, Francois Quesnay, Destutt de Tracy, Charles Comte, Richard Cantillon (who was born in Ireland and emigrated to France), and Anne-Robert-Jacques Turgot.

These French economists were among the precursors to the modern Austrian School. They first developed such concepts as the market as a dynamic, rivalrous process, the free-market evolution of money, subjective value theory, the laws of diminishing marginal utility and marginal returns, the marginal productivity theory of resource pricing, and the futility of price controls in particular and of the government's economic interventionism in general.

In his Economic Harmonies, Bastiat stated:

We cannot doubt that self-interest is the mainspring of human nature. It must be clearly understood that this word is used here to designate a universal, incontestable fact, resulting from the nature of man, and not an adverse judgment, as would be the word selfishness (1850).

Thornton (2002) posits that Bastiat, through taking this position on the motivations of human action, demonstrates a pronounced "Austrian flavor.”

"Full picture" rule

One of Bastiat's most important contributions to the field of economics was his admonition to the effect that good economic decisions can only be made by taking into account the "full picture." That is, economic truths should be arrived at by observing not only the immediate consequences—that is, benefits or liabilities—of an economic decision, but also by examining the long-term consequences. Additionally, one must examine the decision's effect not only on a single group of people (say candlemakers) or a single industry (say candles), but on all people and all industries in the society as a whole.

As Bastiat famously put it, an economist must take into account both "What is seen and what is not seen." Bastiat's "rule" was later expounded and developed by Henry Hazlitt in his work, Economics in One Lesson, in which Hazlitt borrowed Bastiat's polemics used in his "Broken Window Fallacy" and went on to demonstrate how it applies to a wide variety of economic falsehoods. As Friedrich von Hayek wrote:

Nothing illustrates this better than the celebrated title of the first essay in the present volume. "What is seen and what is not seen in political economy." No one has ever stated more clearly in a single phrase the central difficulty of a rational economic policy and, I would like to add, the decisive argument for economic freedom. It is the idea compressed into these few words that made me use the word "genius" in the opening sentence. It is indeed a text around which one might expound a whole system of libertarian economic policy (F.A. Hayek 1848 in the introduction to Bastiat’s Selected Essays on Political Economy).

Work

Bastiat's first published article appeared in April of 1834. It was a response to a petition by the merchants of Bordeaux, Le Havre, and Lyons to eliminate tariffs on agricultural products but to maintain them on manufactured goods. Bastiat praised the merchants for their position on agricultural products, but excoriated them for their hypocrisy in wanting protectionism for themselves. "You demand privilege for a few," he wrote, whereas "I demand liberty for all" (Russell 1969, p. 24). He then explained why all tariffs should be abolished completely.

Bastiat continued to hone his arguments in favor of economic freedom by writing a second essay in opposition to all domestic taxes on wine, entitled "The Tax and the Vine," and a third essay opposing all taxes on land and all forms of trade restrictions.

Then, in the summer of 1844, Bastiat sent an unsolicited manuscript on the effects of French and English tariffs to the most prestigious economics journal in France, the Journal des Economistes. The editors published the article, "The Influence of English and French Tariffs," in the October 1844 issue, and it unquestionably became the most persuasive argument for free trade in particular, and for economic freedom in general, that had ever appeared in France, if not all of Europe.

While Bastiat was shaping economic opinion in France, Karl Marx was writing Das Kapital, and the socialist notion of "class conflict" that the economic gains of capitalists necessarily came at the expense of workers was gaining in popularity. Bastiat's second major work, Economic Harmonies, by way of contrast, explained that the interests of humankind are essentially harmonious if they can be cultivated in a free society where government confines its responsibilities to suppressing thieves, murderers, and special-interest groups who seek to use the state as a means of plundering their fellow citizens.

Bastiat contributed to Austrian capital theory by masterfully explaining how the accumulation of capital results in the enrichment of the workers by raising labor's marginal productivity and, consequently, its remuneration. Capital accumulation, wrote Bastiat, would also result in cheaper and better quality consumer goods, which would also raise real wages. He also explained how the interest on capital declines as it becomes more plentiful.

Thus, in his view, the interests of capitalists and labor are indeed harmonious, and government interventions into capital markets will impoverish the workers as well as the owners of capital. Bastiat also explained why in a free market no one can accumulate capital unless he uses it in a way that benefits others, namely the consumers.

In reality, wrote Bastiat, capital is always used to satisfy the desires of people who do not own it. In sharp contrast to most of his predecessors, Bastiat believed that "it is necessary to view economics from the viewpoint of the consumer. … All economic phenomena … must be judged by the advantages and disadvantages they bring to the consumer" (Bastiat 1848, Selected Essays, p. 1-50).

Bastiat's greatest contribution to subjective value theory was how he rigorously applied the theory in his essay, "What is Seen and What is Not Seen" (Bastiat 1848, p. 1-50). In that essay, Bastiat, by relentlessly focusing on the hidden opportunity costs of governmental resource allocation, destroyed the notion that government spending can create jobs and wealth.

Economic Sophisms

His first book, Economic Sophisms (Bastiat 1845), is to this day still arguably the best literary defense of free trade available. In this work, Bastiat masterfully created the most complete case for free trade ever constructed up to that time, which applied such economic concepts as the mutual advantage of voluntary trade, the law of comparative advantage, the benefits of competition to the producer as well as the consumer, and the historical link between trade barriers and war.

Contained within Economic Sophisms is the famous satirical parable known as the "Candlemakers' petition" which presents itself as a demand from the candlemakers' guild to the French government. In this "petition," the candlemakers cite several economic "advantages" that might be had from blocking out the Sun, by increasing consumption of products: tallow, leading to the increased production of meat, wool, hides, and so on; vegetable oil, leading to the increased production of poppies, olives, and rapeseed; resinous trees, leading to more bees, hence crop pollination; whale oil, leading to a larger merchant navy that would boost France's prestige and standing. Bastiat's argument cleverly highlights basic flaws in protectionism by demonstrating its absurdity through logical extremes.

Free trade, Bastiat explained, would mean

…an abundance of goods and services at lower prices; more jobs for more people at higher real wages; more profits for manufacturers; a higher level of living for farmers; more income to the state in the form of taxes at the customary or lower levels; the most productive use of capital, labor, and natural resources; the end of the "class struggle … was based primarily on such economic injustices as tariffs, monopolies, and other legal distortions of the market; the end of the "suicidal policy" of colonialism; the abolition of war as a national policy; and the best possible education, housing, and medical care for all the people (Russell 1969, p. 42).

Candlemakers’ Petition

In this same book, Economic Sophisms, one can find probably of the most famous documents in the history of free-trade literature—Bastiat’s famous “Candlemakers’ Petition.” In that parody, Bastiat imagined the makers of candles and street lamps petitioning the French Chamber of Deputies for protection from a most dastardly foreign competitor:

You are on the right track. You reject abstract theories and have little regard for abundance and low prices. You concern yourselves mainly with the fate of the producer. You wish to free him from foreign competition, that is, to reserve the domestic market for domestic industry (Bastiat 1845).

The argument continues in fully legal and economically sound discourse:

We come to offer you a wonderful opportunity. …we are suffering from the ruinous competition of a rival who apparently works under conditions so far superior to our own for the production of light that he is flooding the domestic market with it at an incredibly low price; for the moment he appears, our sales cease, all the consumers turn to him, and a branch of French industry whose ramifications are innumerable is all at once reduced to complete stagnation. This rival … is none other than the sun (Ibid., 1845).

For after all, Bastiat’s petitioners noted, how can the makers of candles and lanterns compete with a light source that is totally free?

As a response to this publication, in 1846, Bastiat was elected a corresponding member of the French Academy of Science, and his work was immediately translated into English, Spanish, Italian, and German. Free-trade associations soon began to sprout up in Belgium, Italy, Sweden, Prussia, and Germany, and were all based on Bastiat's French Free Trade Association.

Economic Harmonies

In his second book, Economic Harmonies (Bastiat 1850) and subsequent articles, reprinted in newspapers and magazines all over France, Bastiat described economics as an intellectual endeavor in the way which is virtually identical to what modern Austrians call the science of human action, or praxaeology. Bastiat wrote in his Harmonies:

The subject of political economy is MAN … [who is] endowed with the ability to compare, judge, choose, and act…. This faculty … to work for each other, to transmit their efforts and to exchange their services through time and space … is precisely what constitutes Economic Science (Bastiat, 1850, p. 35).

As with contemporary Austrians, Bastiat viewed economics as

the Theory of Exchange where the desires of market participants cannot be weighed or measured…. Exchange is necessary in order to determine value (Bastiat, 1850, p. 36).

Thus, to Bastiat, as with contemporary Austrians, value is subjective, and the only way of knowing how people value things is through their demonstrated preferences as revealed in market exchanges.

Voluntary exchange, therefore, is necessarily mutually advantageous. This was an important theoretical innovation in the history of economic theory, for many of the British economists had succumbed to the "physical fallacy"—the misguided notion that value is determined by the production of physical objects alone.

The understanding that value is created by voluntary exchange, Murray Rothbard pointed out, "led Bastiat and the French school to stress the ways in which the free market leads to a smooth and harmonious organization of the economy" (Rothbard 1995, p. 446).

Economy vs. state vs. law

Bastiat is perhaps best known for his work in the field of political economy—the study of the interaction between the economy and the state—as opposed to pure economic theory. He sought to understand how the state operated and by what incentives it was driven, and he did so as well as anyone ever has.

Government was necessary, according to Bastiat, but only if restricted to its "essential" functions. He believed that "no society can exist unless the laws are respected to a certain degree, but at the same time that could only occur if the laws themselves were respectable” (Russell 1969, p. 5).

The moral justification for a law, moreover, can never be based on a majority vote, because "since no individual has the right to enslave another individual, then no group of individuals can possibly have such a right" (Russell 1969, p. 6). All income redistribution through majoritarian democracy is therefore "legal plunder" and is, by definition, immoral.

Bastiat understood that free-market competition was a "dynamic discovery procedure," in which individuals strove to coordinate their plans to achieve their economic goals. All forms of government intervention interrupt and distort that process because once a law or regulation is issued, "the people no longer need to discuss, to compare, to plan ahead; the law does all this for them. Intelligence becomes a useless prop for the people; they cease to be men; they lose their personality, their liberty, their property" (Russell 1969, p. 11).

The following quotation on the question of economy and the government legislation round up his views on the overall societal problems between the state and the general population:

If the natural tendencies of mankind are so bad that it is not safe to permit people to be free, how is it that the tendencies of these organizers are always good? Do not the legislators and their appointed agents also belong to the human race? Or do they believe that they themselves are made of a finer clay than the rest of mankind? …Life, faculties, production—in other words, individuality, liberty, property—this is man. And in spite of the cunning of artful political leaders, these three gifts from God precede all human legislation, and are superior to it. Life, liberty, and property do not exist because men have made laws. On the contrary, it was the fact that life, liberty, and property existed beforehand that caused men to make laws in the first place (Bastiat, 1850).

Legacy

Bastiat's writing constitutes an intellectual bridge between the ideas of the pre-Austrian economists, such as Say, Cantillon, Turgot, and Quesnay, and the Austrian tradition of Carl Menger and his students.

He was also a model of scholarship for those Austrians who believed that general economic education, especially the kind of economic education that shatters the myriad myths and superstitions created by the state and its intellectual apologists, is an essential function (if not duty) of the economist. Ludwig von Mises was a superb follower in this regard, as were Henry Hazlitt and Murray Rothbard, among others.

As Mises said, the early economists

…devoted themselves to the study of the problems of economics … [and in] lecturing and writing books they were eager to communicate to their fellow citizens the results of their thinking. They tried to influence public opinion in order to make sound policies prevail (von Mises 1963, p.869).

Henry Hazlitt wrote that:

My greatest debt, with respect to the kind of expository framework on which the present argument is hung, is Frederic Bastiat's essay, "What is Seen and What is Not Seen." The present work may, in fact, be regarded as a modernization, extension, and generalization of the approach found in Bastiat (Hazlitt, 1946, p. 1).

To this day, Bastiat's work is not appreciated as much as it should be because, as Murray Rothbard explained, today's intemperate critics of economic freedom "find it difficult to believe that anyone who is ardently and consistently in favor of laissez-faire could possibly be an important scholar and economic theorist" (Rothbard 1995, p. 449). For Bastiat, indeed, believed in market forces as capable of maintaining a healthy economy. To Bastiat, governmental coercion was only legitimate if it served "to guarantee security of person, liberty, and property rights, to cause justice to reign over all" (Bastiat 1995, p. 52).

Therefore, it is, perhaps, not surprising that even some contemporary Austrian economists seem to believe that the act of communicating economic ideas especially economic policy ideas to the general public is somehow unworthy of a practitioner of "economic science." For that is exactly the model of scholarship that Mises himself adopted, which was carried forward most aggressively and brilliantly by Murray Rothbard, all in the tradition of the great French Austrian economist, Frederic Bastiat.

Major publications

  • Bastiat, F. [1845] 1996. "Economic Sophisms." In Foundation for Economic Education. New York: Irvington-on-Hudson.
  • Bastiat, F. [1848] 1995. "Selected Essays on Political Economy." In Foundation for Economic Education. New York: Irvington-on-Hudson.
  • Bastiat F. [1849] 1996. "Capital and Interest." In Foundation for Economic Education. New York: Irvington-on-Hudson.
  • Bastiat F. [1849] 1996. "The Law" in Foundation for Economic Education. New York: Irvington-on-Hudson.
  • Bastiat, F. [1850] 1996. "Economic Harmonie" in Foundation for Economic Education. New York: Irvington-on-Hudson.

References
ISBN links support NWE through referral fees

  • Hazlitt, H. 1946. "Economics in One Lesson." In Harper and Brothers. New York.
  • Mises, L. 1963. Human Action: A Treatise on Economics. Chicago: Henry Regnery.
  • Rothbard, M. 1995. "Classical Economics. Vol. 2. An Austrian Perspective on the History of Economic Thought." In Edward Elgar. Cheltenham, U.K.
  • Russell, D. 1969. "Frédérick Bastiat: Ideas and Influence." In Foundation for Economic Education. New York: Irvington-on-Hudson.
  • Thornton, Mark. 2002. "Frederic Bastiat's Views on the Nature of Money." In The Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics. 5, No. 3: 81–86. Retrieved October 18, 2007.

External links

All links retrieved December 19, 2023.


Credits

New World Encyclopedia writers and editors rewrote and completed the Wikipedia article in accordance with New World Encyclopedia standards. This article abides by terms of the Creative Commons CC-by-sa 3.0 License (CC-by-sa), which may be used and disseminated with proper attribution. Credit is due under the terms of this license that can reference both the New World Encyclopedia contributors and the selfless volunteer contributors of the Wikimedia Foundation. To cite this article click here for a list of acceptable citing formats.The history of earlier contributions by wikipedians is accessible to researchers here:

The history of this article since it was imported to New World Encyclopedia:

Note: Some restrictions may apply to use of individual images which are separately licensed.