Encyclopedia, Difference between revisions of "John Richard Hicks" - New World

From New World Encyclopedia
Line 4: Line 4:
 
[[Category:Economics]]
 
[[Category:Economics]]
 
{{epname}}
 
{{epname}}
'''Sir John Richard Hicks''' (born April 8, 1904 – died May 20, 1989) was a [[Great Britain|British]] [[economics|economist]], one of the most influential economists of the twentieth century. He contributed to the field of economics with his [[IS/LM model]], which summarized the [[Keynes]]ian view of [[macroeconomics]], and his statement of [[consumer theory|consumer demand theory]] in [[microeconomics]]. In 1972, Hicks was awarded the [[Nobel Prize]] in Economics for his contributions to general economic [[equilibrium theory]] and [[welfare theory]].  
+
'''Sir John Richard Hicks''' (April 8, 1904 – May 20, 1989) was a [[Great Britain|British]] [[economics|economist]], one of the most influential economists of the twentieth century. He contributed to the field of economics with his [[IS/LM model]], which summarized the [[Keynes]]ian view of [[macroeconomics]], and his statement of [[consumer theory|consumer demand theory]] in [[microeconomics]]. In 1972, Hicks was awarded the [[Nobel Prize]] in Economics for his contributions to general economic [[equilibrium theory]] and [[welfare theory]].  
  
 
==Life==
 
==Life==
  
John Richard Hicks was born in Leamington Spa, Warwickshire, [[England]], the son of a [[journalism|journalist]]. He was educated at [[Clifton College]] (1917-22) and later received a [[mathematics|mathematical]] scholarship to study at [[Balliol College]], at the [[University of Oxford]]. He enrolled at Oxford in 1923.  
+
'''John Richard Hicks''' was born in Leamington Spa, Warwickshire, [[England]], the son of a [[journalism|journalist]]. He was educated at [[Clifton College]] (1917-1922) and later received a [[mathematics|mathematical]] scholarship to study at [[Balliol College]], at the [[University of Oxford]], where he enrolled in 1923.  
  
Although initially specializing in [[mathematics]], Hicks was not content with mathematics and had a strong interest for [[literature]] and [[history]]. He transferred in 1923 to the newly opened School of Philosophy, Politics and Economics. He however did not have adequate qualification in any of the subjects that he had studied, and had graduated with a second-class degree.   
+
Although initially specializing in [[mathematics]], Hicks was not content and had a strong interest for [[literature]] and [[history]]. He transferred in 1923 to the newly opened School of Philosophy, Politics and Economics. However, he did not have adequate qualification in any of the subjects that he studied, and graduated with a second-class degree.   
  
[[economics|Economists]], in 1920s, were very scarce, so Hicks picked up a temporary lectureship at the [[London School of Economics]] and managed to get continued. He started as a [[labor economics|labor economist]], doing descriptive work on [[industry|industrial]] relations, but gradually moved over to the analytical side. He discovered that his mathematics, by that time almost forgotten, could be revived, and was sufficient to cope with what anyone used in economics.
+
In the 1920s, [[economics|economists]] were very scarce and so Hicks picked up a temporary lectureship at the [[London School of Economics]], which was then continued. He started as a [[labor economics|labor economist]], doing descriptive work on [[industrial relations]], but gradually moved over to the analytical side. He discovered that his mathematics, by that time almost forgotten, could be revived, and was sufficient to cope with what anyone used in economics.
  
In 1935, Hicks married his fellow economist, Ursula Webb, and transferred to the [[Cambridge University]] where he became lecturer in economics. During his three years in Cambridge, Hicks completed his ''Value and Capital'', which was based on the work he had done in London. He was also a fellow of Gonville and Caius College, at Cambridge, from 1935 to 1938.
+
In 1935, Hicks married fellow economist, Ursula Webb. At that time he transferred to [[Cambridge University]] where he became a lecturer in economics. During his three years in Cambridge, Hicks completed his ''Value and Capital'', which was based on the work he had done in London. He was also a fellow of Gonville and Caius College, at Cambridge, from 1935 to 1938.
  
In 1938, Hicks became professor at the [[University of Manchester]]. It was there that he started to focus mainly on [[welfare economics], and its application to social accounting. In 1946 he returned to [[Oxford University|Oxford]], first as a research fellow of [[Nuffield College, Oxford|Nuffield College]] (1946-52), then as Drummond Professor of [[Political Economy]] (1952-65), and finally as a research fellow of [[All Souls College]] (1965-71).
+
In 1938, Hicks became professor at the [[University of Manchester]]. It was there that he started to focus mainly on [[welfare economics], and its application to social accounting. In 1946 he returned to Oxford, first as a research fellow of [[Nuffield College, Oxford|Nuffield College]] (1946-1952), then as Drummond Professor of [[Political Economy]] (1952-1965), and finally as a research fellow of [[All Souls College]] (1965-1971).
  
Hicks became a fellow of the British Academy in 1942; a foreign member of the Royal [[Sweden|Swedish]] Academy in 1948, of the Accademia dei Lincei, [[Italy]], in 1952, and of the [[United States|American]] Academy in 1958. He was knighted in 1964. He received honorary doctor degree from several British Universities - Glasgow, Manchester, Leicester, East Anglia and Warwick - as well as of the Technical University of Lisbon, [[Portugal]].  
+
Hicks became a fellow of the British Academy in 1942; a foreign member of the Royal Swedish Academy in 1948, of the Accademia dei Lincei, [[Italy]], in 1952, and of the American Academy in 1958. He was knighted in 1964. He received honorary doctor degrees from several British Universities - Glasgow, Manchester, Leicester, East Anglia, and Warwick - as well as of the Technical University of Lisbon, [[Portugal]].  
  
 
In 1972, Hicks received the [[Nobel Prize]] in Economics, together with [[Kenneth J. Arrow]], for his work on general economic equilibrium theory and welfare theory.  
 
In 1972, Hicks received the [[Nobel Prize]] in Economics, together with [[Kenneth J. Arrow]], for his work on general economic equilibrium theory and welfare theory.  
Line 27: Line 27:
  
 
===Microeconomics===
 
===Microeconomics===
Hick's early work was as a [[labor economics|labor economist]] culminated in ''The Theory of Wages'' (1932), still considered standard in the field. In that book he gave his own interpretation of the [[marginal productivity theory]], attempting to revoke interest in it once again. In the book, he also introduced his famous "''elasticity of substitution''" “the elasticity of the ratio of two inputs to a production (or utility) function with respect to the ratio of their marginal products (or utilities)” (see [http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Elasticity_of_substitution Wikipedia]).
+
Hicks' early work was as a [[labor economics|labor economist]] culminated in ''The Theory of Wages'' (1932), still considered a standard in the field. In that book he gave his own interpretation of [[marginal productivity theory]], attempting to reinvoke interest in it. In the book he also introduced his famous "elasticity of substitution" which is defined as “the elasticity of the ratio of two inputs to a production (or utility) function with respect to the ratio of their marginal products (or utilities).”  
  
In the mid-1930s, Hicks worked on the way to unite various theories of imperfect competition, introducing the concept of "conjectural variations". He also attempted to resurrect the [[Lausanne School of economics]] by introducing some important concepts from it to the English-speaking world. In 1934 he tried to do the same with the review of [[Gunnar Myrdal]]'s work, which drew attention to the [[Stockholm School]].  
+
In the mid-1930s, Hicks worked on a way to unite various theories of imperfect [[competition]], introducing the concept of "conjectural variations." He also attempted to resurrect the [[Lausanne School of economics]] developed by [[Léon Walras]] and [[Vilfredo Pareto]]. The central feature of the Lausanne School was its development of [[general equilibrium theory]] which he attempted to introduce to the English-speaking world. In 1934 he tried to do the same with his review of [[Gunnar Myrdal]]'s work, which drew attention to the [[Stockholm School of economics]].  
  
His magnum opus was ''Value and Capital'', published in 1939. The book built upon [[ordinal utility]] and mainstreamed the now-standard distinction between the [[substitution effect]] and the [[income effect]] for an individual in [[Consumer theory|demand theory]] for the 2-good case. It generalized analysis to the case of one good and a [[composite good]], that is, all other goods. It aggregated individuals and businesses through demand and supply across the economy. It anticipated the [[aggregation problem]], most acutely for the stock of capital goods.  
+
His magnum opus was ''Value and Capital'', published in 1939. This book built upon [[ordinal utility]] and mainstreamed the now-standard distinction between the [[substitution effect]] and the [[income effect]] for an individual in [[Consumer theory|demand theory]] for the case of two [[consumer good]]s. It generalized analysis to the case of one consumer good and a [[composite good]], that is, all other goods. It also aggregated individuals and [[business]]es through demand and supply across the economy, anticipating the [[aggregation problem]], most acutely for the stock of capital goods.  
  
The book also introduced [[general equilibrium theory]] to an English-speaking audience, refined the theory for dynamic analysis, and for the first time attempted a rigorous statement of stability conditions for general equilibrium. In the course of analysis Hicks formalized [[comparative statics]]. In the same year, he also developed the famous "compensation" criteria called [[Kaldor-Hicks efficiency]] for welfare comparisons of alternative public policies or economic states.  
+
Hicks' book introduced [[general equilibrium theory]] to an English-speaking audience, refined the theory for dynamic analysis, and for the first time attempted a rigorous statement of stability conditions for general equilibrium. In the course of analysis Hicks formalized [[comparative statics]]. In the same year, he also developed the famous "compensation" criteria called [[Kaldor-Hicks efficiency]] for welfare comparisons of alternative public policies or economic states.  
  
The book ''Value and Capital'' had tremendous impact. Much of modern microeconomics, as well as general equilibrium theory, have its roots in this book.
+
The book ''Value and Capital'' had tremendous impact. Much of modern [[microeconomics]], as well as general equilibrium theory, has its roots in this book.
  
 
===Macroeconomics===
 
===Macroeconomics===
His most familiar contribution in [[macroeconomics]] was the [[IS/LM model|Hicks-Hansen IS-LM model]], which formalized the theory of [[John Maynard Keynes]]. The model describes the economy as a balance between three commodities: [[money]], [[consumption]] and [[investment]]. The model eventually became the starting point of the Neo-Keynesian synthesis, in economical systems in the post-war period. The Neo-Keynesian system dominated economy in the mid-20th century, coming under criticism in early 1970s, when the high inflation and growing unemployment seemed to be incompatible with the predictions of the system. In one of his later works, published in 1980, Hicks criticized his own model, asserting it had omitted some crucial components of Keynes's arguments, especially those related to [[uncertainty]].
+
Hicks' most familiar contribution in [[macroeconomics]] was the [[IS/LM model|Hicks-Hansen IS-LM model]], which formalized the theory of [[John Maynard Keynes]]. The model describes the [[economy]] as a balance between three commodities: [[money]], [[consumption]], and [[investment]]. This model eventually became the starting point of the Neo-Keynesian synthesis in economic systems which dominated in the mid-twentieth century. It later came under criticism in the early 1970s, when high [[inflation]] and growing [[unemployment]] seemed to be incompatible with the predictions of the system. In one of his later works, published in 1980, Hicks criticized his own model, asserting it had omitted some crucial components of Keynes' arguments, especially those related to [[uncertainty]].
  
Among his other contributions to macroeconomics is the concept of "liquidity trap" – which happens in stagnant economy, when the nominal interest rate is close or equal to zero, and when people start to keep their savings only in short-term bank accounts, expecting the recession. He also developed the concept of "temporary equilibrium", enlarged the "Linear Theory" and elaborated on the [[John von Neumann|von Neumann]] turnpike.
+
Among his other contributions to macroeconomics is the concept of "liquidity trap" – which happens in a stagnant economy, when the nominal [[interest rate]] is close or equal to zero, and when people start to keep their savings only in short-term bank accounts, expecting a recession. He also developed the concept of "temporary equilibrium," enlarged the "Linear Theory" and elaborated on the [[John von Neumann|von Neumann]] turnpike.
  
In 1970s Hicks worked to resurrect the [[Austrian school]], attempting to formalize the Austrian theory of capital which included both fixed and circulating capital.
+
In the 1970s Hicks worked to resurrect the [[Austrian school of economics]], attempting to formalize the Austrian theory of [[capital]] which included both fixed and circulating capital.
  
 
==Legacy==
 
==Legacy==
  
John Richard Hicks was one of the most important and influential economists of the twentieth century. He broke up with Marshallian tradition that dominated Anglo-Saxon world in the 1930s, in what is commonly known as “Paretian revival”, and reintroduced the theories of Walrasian, Austrian, and Swedish schools. His work, together with other great economist thinkers such as [[Paul Samuelson]], [[Oskar Lange]], [[Abba Lerner]], [[Maurice Allais]], and [[Harold Hotellin]], helped consolidate the Marginalist revolution, which started some fifty years before.
+
John Richard Hicks was one of the most important and influential economists of the twentieth century. He broke with [[Alfred Marshall|Marshallian]] tradition that dominated the English-speaking world in the 1930s, in what is commonly known as “Paretian revival,and reintroduced the theories of [[Leon Walras]], the [[Austrian school]], and the Swedish school based on the work of [[Gunnar Myrdal]] and [[Bertil Ohlin]]. His work, together with other great economic thinkers such as [[Paul Samuelson]], [[Oskar Lange]], [[Abba Lerner]], [[Maurice Allais]], and [[Harold Hotellin]], helped consolidate the Marginalist revolution, which started some fifty years before.
  
Although his work was deep enough, and his influence strong enough to form a school of thought, Hicks never gathered any greater number of followers. The reason for this is probably that his approach was critical and eclectic, building upon every school that had something to offer. He however inspired generations of thinkers, especially in the tradition of Neo-Walrasianism, such as [[Michio Morishima]], [[Frank H. Hahn]], and [[Takashi Negishi]].
+
Although his work was deep enough, and his influence strong enough to form a school of thought, Hicks never gathered any great number of followers. The reason for this is probably that his approach was critical and eclectic, building upon every school that had something to offer. He however inspired generations of thinkers, especially in the neo-Walrasian tradition, including [[Michio Morishima]], [[Frank H. Hahn]], and [[Takashi Negishi]].
  
 
==Publications==
 
==Publications==
  
 
* Hicks, John R. 1932. ''The Theory of Wages''. London: Macmillan.
 
* Hicks, John R. 1932. ''The Theory of Wages''. London: Macmillan.
* Hicks, John R. 1939. "The Foundations of Welfare Economics". ''Economic Journal'', 69, 696-712.
+
* Hicks, John R. 1939. "The Foundations of Welfare Economics." ''Economic Journal'', 69, 696-712.
 
* Hicks, John R. [1939] 2001. ''Value and Capital''. Oxford University Press. ISBN 0198282699
 
* Hicks, John R. [1939] 2001. ''Value and Capital''. Oxford University Press. ISBN 0198282699
 
* Hicks, John R. 1940. "The Valuation of Social Income." ''Economica,'' 7, 105-24.
 
* Hicks, John R. 1940. "The Valuation of Social Income." ''Economica,'' 7, 105-24.
Line 78: Line 78:
 
==External links==
 
==External links==
  
* [http://nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economics/laureates/1972/hicks-autobio.html Autobiography] – Hicks’s autobiography from 1992
+
* [http://nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economics/laureates/1972/hicks-autobio.html Autobiography] – Hicks’s autobiography from 1992 Retrieved July 12, 2007.
* [http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/multacc/hicksacc.htm Hicks's Trade Cycle] – On Hicks’s work
+
* [http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/multacc/hicksacc.htm Hicks's Trade Cycle] – On Hicks’s work Retrieved July 12, 2007.
* [http://www.bized.co.uk/virtual/economy/library/economists/hicksth.htm Hicks’s work] – On some of Hicks’s theories
+
* [http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/keynes/hickshansen.htm The Hicks-Hansen IS-LM Model] – On the model Retrieved July 12, 2007.
* [http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/keynes/hickshansen.htm The Hicks-Hansen IS-LM Model] – On the model  
+
* [http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/hicks.htm John Richard Hicks] - Biography Retrieved July 12, 2007.
* [http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/hicks.htm John Richard Hicks] - Biography
+
* [http://nobelprize.org/economics/laureates/1972/hicks-lecture.html The Mainspring of Economic Growth] – Hicks’s Nobel Prize lecture from 1973 Retrieved July 12, 2007.
* [http://www.britannica.com/eb/article-9040364/Sir-John-R-Hicks John Richard Hicks] – Biography on Encyclopedia Britannica
+
* [http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/margrev/distrib.htm The Neoclassical Theory of Distribution] – On the context of Hisks’ work Retrieved July 12, 2007.
* [http://nobelprize.org/economics/laureates/1972/hicks-lecture.html The Mainspring of Economic Growth] – Hicks’s Nobel Prize lecture from 1973  
+
* [http://nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economics/laureates/1972/press.html Press Release] of Nobel award (1972) Retrieved July 12, 2007.
* [http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/margrev/distrib.htm The Neoclassical Theory of Distribution] – On the context of Hisks’s work
+
* [http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/bios/Hicks.html Biography of John R. Hicks (1904-1989)] The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics Retrieved July 12, 2007.
* [http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/keynes/islmcont.htm The Neo-Keynesian World] – Neo-Keynesian theories
 
* [http://nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economics/laureates/1972/press.html Press Release] of Nobel award (1972)
 
  
 
{{Credits|John_Hicks|125804703|}}
 
{{Credits|John_Hicks|125804703|}}

Revision as of 22:54, 12 July 2007

Sir John Richard Hicks (April 8, 1904 – May 20, 1989) was a British economist, one of the most influential economists of the twentieth century. He contributed to the field of economics with his IS/LM model, which summarized the Keynesian view of macroeconomics, and his statement of consumer demand theory in microeconomics. In 1972, Hicks was awarded the Nobel Prize in Economics for his contributions to general economic equilibrium theory and welfare theory.

Life

John Richard Hicks was born in Leamington Spa, Warwickshire, England, the son of a journalist. He was educated at Clifton College (1917-1922) and later received a mathematical scholarship to study at Balliol College, at the University of Oxford, where he enrolled in 1923.

Although initially specializing in mathematics, Hicks was not content and had a strong interest for literature and history. He transferred in 1923 to the newly opened School of Philosophy, Politics and Economics. However, he did not have adequate qualification in any of the subjects that he studied, and graduated with a second-class degree.

In the 1920s, economists were very scarce and so Hicks picked up a temporary lectureship at the London School of Economics, which was then continued. He started as a labor economist, doing descriptive work on industrial relations, but gradually moved over to the analytical side. He discovered that his mathematics, by that time almost forgotten, could be revived, and was sufficient to cope with what anyone used in economics.

In 1935, Hicks married fellow economist, Ursula Webb. At that time he transferred to Cambridge University where he became a lecturer in economics. During his three years in Cambridge, Hicks completed his Value and Capital, which was based on the work he had done in London. He was also a fellow of Gonville and Caius College, at Cambridge, from 1935 to 1938.

In 1938, Hicks became professor at the University of Manchester. It was there that he started to focus mainly on [[welfare economics], and its application to social accounting. In 1946 he returned to Oxford, first as a research fellow of Nuffield College (1946-1952), then as Drummond Professor of Political Economy (1952-1965), and finally as a research fellow of All Souls College (1965-1971).

Hicks became a fellow of the British Academy in 1942; a foreign member of the Royal Swedish Academy in 1948, of the Accademia dei Lincei, Italy, in 1952, and of the American Academy in 1958. He was knighted in 1964. He received honorary doctor degrees from several British Universities - Glasgow, Manchester, Leicester, East Anglia, and Warwick - as well as of the Technical University of Lisbon, Portugal.

In 1972, Hicks received the Nobel Prize in Economics, together with Kenneth J. Arrow, for his work on general economic equilibrium theory and welfare theory.

John Hicks died on May 20, 1989 in Blockley, Gloucestershire, Great Britain.

Work

Microeconomics

Hicks' early work was as a labor economist culminated in The Theory of Wages (1932), still considered a standard in the field. In that book he gave his own interpretation of marginal productivity theory, attempting to reinvoke interest in it. In the book he also introduced his famous "elasticity of substitution" which is defined as “the elasticity of the ratio of two inputs to a production (or utility) function with respect to the ratio of their marginal products (or utilities).”

In the mid-1930s, Hicks worked on a way to unite various theories of imperfect competition, introducing the concept of "conjectural variations." He also attempted to resurrect the Lausanne School of economics developed by Léon Walras and Vilfredo Pareto. The central feature of the Lausanne School was its development of general equilibrium theory which he attempted to introduce to the English-speaking world. In 1934 he tried to do the same with his review of Gunnar Myrdal's work, which drew attention to the Stockholm School of economics.

His magnum opus was Value and Capital, published in 1939. This book built upon ordinal utility and mainstreamed the now-standard distinction between the substitution effect and the income effect for an individual in demand theory for the case of two consumer goods. It generalized analysis to the case of one consumer good and a composite good, that is, all other goods. It also aggregated individuals and businesses through demand and supply across the economy, anticipating the aggregation problem, most acutely for the stock of capital goods.

Hicks' book introduced general equilibrium theory to an English-speaking audience, refined the theory for dynamic analysis, and for the first time attempted a rigorous statement of stability conditions for general equilibrium. In the course of analysis Hicks formalized comparative statics. In the same year, he also developed the famous "compensation" criteria called Kaldor-Hicks efficiency for welfare comparisons of alternative public policies or economic states.

The book Value and Capital had tremendous impact. Much of modern microeconomics, as well as general equilibrium theory, has its roots in this book.

Macroeconomics

Hicks' most familiar contribution in macroeconomics was the Hicks-Hansen IS-LM model, which formalized the theory of John Maynard Keynes. The model describes the economy as a balance between three commodities: money, consumption, and investment. This model eventually became the starting point of the Neo-Keynesian synthesis in economic systems which dominated in the mid-twentieth century. It later came under criticism in the early 1970s, when high inflation and growing unemployment seemed to be incompatible with the predictions of the system. In one of his later works, published in 1980, Hicks criticized his own model, asserting it had omitted some crucial components of Keynes' arguments, especially those related to uncertainty.

Among his other contributions to macroeconomics is the concept of "liquidity trap" – which happens in a stagnant economy, when the nominal interest rate is close or equal to zero, and when people start to keep their savings only in short-term bank accounts, expecting a recession. He also developed the concept of "temporary equilibrium," enlarged the "Linear Theory" and elaborated on the von Neumann turnpike.

In the 1970s Hicks worked to resurrect the Austrian school of economics, attempting to formalize the Austrian theory of capital which included both fixed and circulating capital.

Legacy

John Richard Hicks was one of the most important and influential economists of the twentieth century. He broke with Marshallian tradition that dominated the English-speaking world in the 1930s, in what is commonly known as “Paretian revival,” and reintroduced the theories of Leon Walras, the Austrian school, and the Swedish school based on the work of Gunnar Myrdal and Bertil Ohlin. His work, together with other great economic thinkers such as Paul Samuelson, Oskar Lange, Abba Lerner, Maurice Allais, and Harold Hotellin, helped consolidate the Marginalist revolution, which started some fifty years before.

Although his work was deep enough, and his influence strong enough to form a school of thought, Hicks never gathered any great number of followers. The reason for this is probably that his approach was critical and eclectic, building upon every school that had something to offer. He however inspired generations of thinkers, especially in the neo-Walrasian tradition, including Michio Morishima, Frank H. Hahn, and Takashi Negishi.

Publications

  • Hicks, John R. 1932. The Theory of Wages. London: Macmillan.
  • Hicks, John R. 1939. "The Foundations of Welfare Economics." Economic Journal, 69, 696-712.
  • Hicks, John R. [1939] 2001. Value and Capital. Oxford University Press. ISBN 0198282699
  • Hicks, John R. 1940. "The Valuation of Social Income." Economica, 7, 105-24.
  • Hicks, John R. 1941. "The Rehabilitation of Consumers' Surplus." Review of Economic Studies, 8, 108-16.
  • Hicks, John R. [1942] 1971. The Social Framework: An Introduction to Economics. Oxford University Press. ISBN 0198281730
  • Hicks, John R. [1950] 1979. A Contribution to the Theory of the Trade Cycle. Oxford University Press. ISBN 0198284160
  • Hicks, John R. [1956] 1986. A Revision of Demand Theory. Oxford University Press. ISBN 0198285507
  • Hicks, John R. 1959. Essays in World Economics. Oxford: Clarendon.
  • Hicks, John R. 1965. Capital and Growth. Oxford: Clarendon.
  • Hicks, John R. [1969] 2001. A Theory of Economic History. Oxford University Press. ISBN 0198811632
  • Hicks, John R. 1975. "The Scope and Status of Welfare Economics." Oxford Economics Papers, Vol. 27, No. 3, 307-26.
  • Hicks, John R. 1977. Economic Perspectives. Oxford University Press. ISBN 0198284071
  • Hicks, John R. 1980. "IS-LM: An Explanation." Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, Vol. 3, No. 2, 139-54
  • Hicks, John R. 1981. Wealth and Welfare: Vol I. of Collected Essays in Economic Theory. Harvard University Press. ISBN 0674137418
  • Hicks, John R. 1982. Money, Interest and Wages: Vol. II of Collected Essays in Economic Theory. Harvard University Press. ISBN 0674584252
  • Hicks, John R. 1983. Classics and Moderns: Vol. III of Collected Essays in Economic Theory. Harvard University Press. ISBN 0674137434.

References
ISBN links support NWE through referral fees

  • Autobiography of John Richard Hicks. NobelPrize.org. Retrieved on June 16, 2007.
  • Bliss, Christopher. 1987. Hicks, John Richard. in Milgate, Murray and Peter Newman John Eatwell. (eds.) The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, Vol. 2, pp. 641-46. Macmillan.
  • Wood, John. Sir John Hicks: Critical Assessments (Second Series). Routledge. ISBN 0415367077

External links

Credits

New World Encyclopedia writers and editors rewrote and completed the Wikipedia article in accordance with New World Encyclopedia standards. This article abides by terms of the Creative Commons CC-by-sa 3.0 License (CC-by-sa), which may be used and disseminated with proper attribution. Credit is due under the terms of this license that can reference both the New World Encyclopedia contributors and the selfless volunteer contributors of the Wikimedia Foundation. To cite this article click here for a list of acceptable citing formats.The history of earlier contributions by wikipedians is accessible to researchers here:

The history of this article since it was imported to New World Encyclopedia:

Note: Some restrictions may apply to use of individual images which are separately licensed.