Hicks, John Richard

From New World Encyclopedia
({{Contracted}})
 
(15 intermediate revisions by 7 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{Claimed}}{{Started}}{{Contracted}}
+
{{Submitted}}{{Images OK}}{{Approved}}{{Paid}}{{Copyedited}}
[[Category:Politics and social sciences]]
+
[[Category:Economists]]
[[Category:Biography]]
+
{{epname|Hicks, John Richard}}
[[Category:Economics]]
+
'''Sir John Richard Hicks''' (April 8, 1904 – May 20, 1989) was a [[Great Britain|British]] [[economics|economist]], one of the most influential economists of the twentieth century. He contributed to the field of economics with his [[IS/LM model]], which summarized the [[Keynes]]ian view of [[macroeconomics]] in graphical form. He also introduced the idea of elasticity of substitution, which showed that [[labor]]-saving technical progress does not reduce labor's share of income. In his book, ''Value and Capital'', one of the first works on general [[equilibrium theory]], Hicks showed that [[value]] could be understood without having to quantify [[utility]]. He also contributed to [[welfare economics]], developing a way to compare the impact of different policies, regarding the one that produced sufficient gain to compensate for any losses and still provide benefit to be worthy of implementation.
{{epname}}
+
{{toc}}
'''Sir John Richard Hicks''' (born April 8, 1904 – died May 20, 1989) was a [[Great Britain|British]] [[economics|economist]], one of the most influential economists of the twentieth century. He contributed to the field of economics with his [[IS/LM model]], which summarized the [[Keynes]]ian view of [[macroeconomics]], and his statement of [[consumer theory|consumer demand theory]] in [[microeconomics]]. In 1972, Hicks was awarded the [[Nobel Prize]] in Economics for his contributions to general economic [[equilibrium theory]] and [[welfare theory]].  
+
Hicks was not a follower of a particular school of economics, but rather took an eclectic approach, reviving and further developing the best of each school. Thus, his work was an attempt to better understand all types of economic forces and to be better able to establish an economically stable human society, benefiting all people. In 1972, Hicks was awarded the [[Nobel Prize]] in Economics, together with [[Kenneth J. Arrow]], for his contributions to general economic equilibrium theory and [[welfare theory]].  
  
 
==Life==
 
==Life==
  
John Richard Hicks was born in Leamington Spa, Warwickshire, [[England]], the son of a [[journalism|journalist]]. He was educated at [[Clifton College]] (1917-22) and later received a [[mathematics|mathematical]] scholarship to study at [[Balliol College]], at the [[University of Oxford]]. He enrolled at Oxford in 1923.  
+
'''John Richard Hicks''' was born in Leamington Spa, Warwickshire, [[England]], the son of a [[journalism|journalist]]. He was educated at [[Clifton College]] (1917-1922) and later received a [[mathematics|mathematical]] scholarship to study at [[Balliol College]], at the [[University of Oxford]], where he enrolled in 1923.  
  
Although initially specializing in [[mathematics]], Hicks was not content with mathematics and had a strong interest for [[literature]] and [[history]]. He transferred in 1923 to the newly opened School of Philosophy, Politics and Economics. He however did not have adequate qualification in any of the subjects that he had studied, and had graduated with a second-class degree.   
+
Although initially specializing in [[mathematics]], Hicks was not content and had a strong interest in [[literature]] and [[history]]. He transferred in 1923 to the newly opened School of Philosophy, Politics and Economics. However, he did not have adequate qualification in any of the subjects that he studied, and graduated with a second-class degree.   
  
[[economics|Economists]], in 1920s, were very scarce, so Hicks picked up a temporary lectureship at the [[London School of Economics]] and managed to get continued. He started as a [[labor economics|labor economist]], doing descriptive work on [[industry|industrial]] relations, but gradually moved over to the analytical side. He discovered that his mathematics, by that time almost forgotten, could be revived, and was sufficient to cope with what anyone used in economics.
+
In the 1920s, [[economics|economists]] were very scarce and so Hicks picked up a temporary lectureship at the [[London School of Economics]], which was then continued. He started as a [[labor economics|labor economist]], doing descriptive work on [[industrial relations]], but gradually moved over to the analytical side. He discovered that his knowledge of mathematics, by that time almost forgotten, could be revived, and was sufficient to cope with what anyone used in economics.
  
In 1935, Hicks married his fellow economist, Ursula Webb, and transferred to the [[Cambridge University]] where he became lecturer in economics. During his three years in Cambridge, Hicks completed his ''Value and Capital'', which was based on the work he had done in London. He was also a fellow of Gonville and Caius College, at Cambridge, from 1935 to 1938.
+
In 1935, Hicks married fellow economist, Ursula Webb. At that time he transferred to [[Cambridge University]] where he became a lecturer in economics. During his three years in Cambridge, Hicks completed his significant book, ''Value and Capital'', which was based on the work he had done in [[London]]. He was also a fellow of Gonville and Caius College, at Cambridge, from 1935 to 1938.
  
In 1938, Hicks became professor at the [[University of Manchester]]. It was there that he started to focus mainly on [[welfare economics], and its application to social accounting. In 1946 he returned to [[Oxford University|Oxford]], first as a research fellow of [[Nuffield College, Oxford|Nuffield College]] (1946-52), then as Drummond Professor of [[Political Economy]] (1952-65), and finally as a research fellow of [[All Souls College]] (1965-71).
+
In 1938, Hicks became professor at the [[University of Manchester]]. It was there that he started to focus mainly on [[welfare economics]], and its application to social accounting. In 1946, he returned to Oxford, first as a research fellow of [[Nuffield College, Oxford|Nuffield College]] (1946-1952), then as Drummond Professor of [[Political Economy]] (1952-1965), and finally as a research fellow of [[All Souls College]] (1965-1971).
  
Hicks became a fellow of the British Academy in 1942; a foreign member of the Royal [[Sweden|Swedish]] Academy in 1948, of the Accademia dei Lincei, [[Italy]], in 1952, and of the [[United States|American]] Academy in 1958. He was knighted in 1964. He received honorary doctor degree from several British Universities - Glasgow, Manchester, Leicester, East Anglia and Warwick - as well as of the Technical University of Lisbon, [[Portugal]].  
+
Hicks became a fellow of the British Academy in 1942; a foreign member of the Royal Swedish Academy in 1948, of the Accademia dei Lincei, [[Italy]], in 1952, and of the American Academy in 1958. He was knighted in 1964. He received honorary doctor degrees from several British Universities—Glasgow, Manchester, Leicester, East Anglia, and Warwick—as well as of the Technical University of Lisbon, [[Portugal]].  
  
 
In 1972, Hicks received the [[Nobel Prize]] in Economics, together with [[Kenneth J. Arrow]], for his work on general economic equilibrium theory and welfare theory.  
 
In 1972, Hicks received the [[Nobel Prize]] in Economics, together with [[Kenneth J. Arrow]], for his work on general economic equilibrium theory and welfare theory.  
Line 27: Line 27:
  
 
===Microeconomics===
 
===Microeconomics===
Hick's early work was as a [[labor economics|labor economist]] culminated in ''The Theory of Wages'' (1932), still considered standard in the field. In that book he gave his own interpretation of the [[marginal productivity theory]], attempting to revoke interest in it once again. In the book, he also introduced his famous "''elasticity of substitution''" “the elasticity of the ratio of two inputs to a production (or utility) function with respect to the ratio of their marginal products (or utilities)” (see [http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Elasticity_of_substitution Wikipedia]).
+
Hicks' early work was as a [[labor economics|labor economist]] culminated in ''The Theory of Wages'' (1932), still considered a standard in the field. In that book he gave his own interpretation of [[marginal productivity theory]], attempting to reinvoke interest in it. In the book he also introduced his famous "elasticity of substitution" which is defined as “the elasticity of the ratio of two inputs to a production (or utility) function with respect to the ratio of their marginal products (or utilities).Using this, Hicks was able to show that, contrary to [[Karl Marx]]'s analysis, [[labor]]-saving technical progress does not necessarily reduce labor's share of national income.  
  
In the mid-1930s, Hicks worked on the way to unite various theories of imperfect competition, introducing the concept of "conjectural variations". He also attempted to resurrect the [[Lausanne School of economics]] by introducing some important concepts from it to the English-speaking world. In 1934 he tried to do the same with the review of [[Gunnar Myrdal]]'s work, which drew attention to the [[Stockholm School]].  
+
In the mid-1930s, Hicks worked on a way to unite various theories of imperfect [[competition]], introducing the concept of "conjectural variations." He also attempted to resurrect the [[Lausanne School of economics]] developed by [[Léon Walras]] and [[Vilfredo Pareto]]. The central feature of the Lausanne School was its development of [[general equilibrium theory]], and he attempted to introduce this to the English-speaking world. In 1934, he tried to do the same with his review of [[Gunnar Myrdal]]'s work, which drew attention to the [[Stockholm School of economics]].  
  
His magnum opus was ''Value and Capital'', published in 1939. The book built upon [[ordinal utility]] and mainstreamed the now-standard distinction between the [[substitution effect]] and the [[income effect]] for an individual in [[Consumer theory|demand theory]] for the 2-good case. It generalized analysis to the case of one good and a [[composite good]], that is, all other goods. It aggregated individuals and businesses through demand and supply across the economy. It anticipated the [[aggregation problem]], most acutely for the stock of capital goods.  
+
His magnum opus was ''Value and Capital'', published in 1939. This book built upon [[ordinal utility]] and mainstreamed the now-standard distinction in demand theory between the [[substitution effect]] and the [[income effect]] for an individual for the case of two [[consumer good]]s. It generalized analysis to the case of one consumer good and a [[composite good]], that is, all other goods. It also aggregated individuals and [[business]]es through demand and supply across the economy, anticipating the [[aggregation problem]] most acutely for the stock of capital goods.  
  
The book also introduced [[general equilibrium theory]] to an English-speaking audience, refined the theory for dynamic analysis, and for the first time attempted a rigorous statement of stability conditions for general equilibrium. In the course of analysis Hicks formalized [[comparative statics]]. In the same year, he also developed the famous "compensation" criteria called [[Kaldor-Hicks efficiency]] for welfare comparisons of alternative public policies or economic states.  
+
[[Image:Kaldor-Hicks-en.svg|thumb|left|Pareto improvements are a small subset of Kaldor-Hicks improvements.]]
 +
Hicks' book introduced [[general equilibrium theory]] to an English-speaking audience, refined the theory for dynamic analysis, and for the first time attempted a rigorous statement of stability conditions for general equilibrium. In the course of analysis Hicks formalized [[comparative statics]]. In the same year, he also developed the famous "compensation" criteria, called the [[Kaldor-Hicks efficiency]], for welfare comparisons of alternative public policies or economic states. In essence, Hicks suggested the criterion that would judge an outcome to be preferable if those who gain by the measure would still gain if they had to compensate those who would lose. Based on this compensation criterion, policies could be compared and the one leading to the greatest net benefit would be implemented.
  
The book ''Value and Capital'' had tremendous impact. Much of modern microeconomics, as well as general equilibrium theory, have its roots in this book.
+
Under [[Pareto efficiency]] (developed by [[Vilfredo Pareto]]), an outcome is more efficient if at least one person is made better off and nobody is made worse off. This seems a reasonable way to determine whether an outcome is efficient or not. However, some believe that in practice it is almost impossible to make any large change such as an economic policy change without making at least one person worse off. Under ideal conditions, exchanges are Pareto efficient since individuals would not voluntarily entered into them unless they were mutually beneficial. Using Kaldor-Hicks efficiency, an outcome is more efficient if those that are made better off could "in theory" compensate those that are made worse off and lead to a Pareto optimal outcome. Thus, a more efficient outcome can in fact leave some people worse off. The criterion is used because it is argued that it is justifiable for [[society]] as a whole to be better off, even though it involves making some worse off if this means a greater gain for others.
  
 
===Macroeconomics===
 
===Macroeconomics===
His most familiar contribution in [[macroeconomics]] was the [[IS/LM model|Hicks-Hansen IS-LM model]], which formalized the theory of [[John Maynard Keynes]]. The model describes the economy as a balance between three commodities: [[money]], [[consumption]] and [[investment]]. The model eventually became the starting point of the Neo-Keynesian synthesis, in economical systems in the post-war period. The Neo-Keynesian system dominated economy in the mid-20th century, coming under criticism in early 1970s, when the high inflation and growing unemployment seemed to be incompatible with the predictions of the system. In one of his later works, published in 1980, Hicks criticized his own model, asserting it had omitted some crucial components of Keynes's arguments, especially those related to [[uncertainty]].
+
Hicks' most familiar contribution to [[macroeconomics]] was the [[IS/LM model|Hicks-Hansen IS-LM model]], which formalized the theory of [[John Maynard Keynes]]. The model describes the [[economy]] as a balance between three commodities: [[money]], [[consumption]], and [[investment]]. It can be presented as a graph of two intersecting lines in the first quadrant.
 +
[[Image:Islm.svg|thumb|200 px|The '''IS''' curve moves to the right, causing higher interest rates and expansion in the "real" economy (real GDP).]]
  
Among his other contributions to macroeconomics is the concept of "liquidity trap" – which happens in stagnant economy, when the nominal interest rate is close or equal to zero, and when people start to keep their savings only in short-term bank accounts, expecting the recession. He also developed the concept of "temporary equilibrium", enlarged the "Linear Theory" and elaborated on the [[John von Neumann|von Neumann]] turnpike.
+
The horizontal axis represents [[national income]] or [[real vs. nominal in economics|real]] [[gross domestic product]] and is labelled '''''Y'''.'' The vertical axis represents the real [[interest]] rate, '''''i'''.''
  
In 1970s Hicks worked to resurrect the [[Austrian school]], attempting to formalize the Austrian theory of capital which included both fixed and circulating capital.
+
The '''IS''' schedule is drawn as a downward-[[slope|sloping]] curve. The initials '''IS''' stand for "'''I'''nvestment/'''S'''aving equilibrium," but since 1937 they have been used to represent the locus of all equilibria where total spending (Consumer spending + planned private Investment + Government purchases + net exports) equals an economy's total output (equivalent to income, Y, or GDP). The level of real [[Gross domestic product|GDP]] ('''Y''') is determined along this line for each [[interest rate]].
 +
 
 +
The '''LM''' schedule is an upward-sloping curve representing the role of finance and money. The initials '''LM''' stand for "'''L'''iquidity preference/'''M'''oney supply equilibrium" but is easier to understand as the equilibrium of the demand to hold money as an asset and the supply of [[money]] by banks and the [[central bank]]. The interest rate is determined along this line for each level of real GDP.
 +
 
 +
The Hicks-Hansen model illustrates graphically [[Keynes]]' conclusion that an economy can be in equilibrium with less than 100 percent employment. This model eventually became the starting point of the Neo-Keynesian synthesis in economic systems which dominated in the mid-twentieth century. It later came under criticism in the early 1970s, when high [[inflation]] and growing [[unemployment]] seemed to be incompatible with the predictions of the system. In one of his later works, published in 1980, Hicks criticized his own model, asserting it had omitted some crucial components of Keynes' arguments, especially those related to [[uncertainty]].
 +
 
 +
Among his other contributions to macroeconomics is the concept of "liquidity trap"—which happens in a stagnant economy, when the nominal [[interest rate]] is close or equal to zero, and when people start to keep their savings only in short-term bank accounts, expecting a recession. He also developed the concept of "temporary equilibrium," enlarged the "Linear Theory" and elaborated on the [[John von Neumann|von Neumann]] turnpike.
 +
 
 +
In the 1970s, Hicks worked to resurrect the [[Austrian school of economics]], attempting to formalize the Austrian theory of [[capital]] which included both fixed and circulating capital.
  
 
==Legacy==
 
==Legacy==
  
John Richard Hicks was one of the most important and influential economists of the twentieth century. He broke up with Marshallian tradition that dominated Anglo-Saxon world in the 1930s, in what is commonly known as “Paretian revival”, and reintroduced the theories of Walrasian, Austrian, and Swedish schools. His work, together with other great economist thinkers such as [[Paul Samuelson]], [[Oskar Lange]], [[Abba Lerner]], [[Maurice Allais]], and [[Harold Hotellin]], helped consolidate the Marginalist revolution, which started some fifty years before.
+
John Richard Hicks was one of the most important and influential economists of the twentieth century. He broke with [[Alfred Marshall|Marshallian]] tradition that dominated the English-speaking world in the 1930s, in what is commonly known as “Paretian revival,and reintroduced the theories of [[Leon Walras]], the [[Austrian school]], and the Swedish school based on the work of [[Gunnar Myrdal]] and [[Bertil Ohlin]]. His work, together with other great economic thinkers such as [[Paul Samuelson]], [[Oskar Lange]], [[Abba Lerner]], [[Maurice Allais]], and [[Harold Hotellin]], helped consolidate the Marginalist revolution, which started some 50 years before.
  
Although his work was deep enough, and his influence strong enough to form a school of thought, Hicks never gathered any greater number of followers. The reason for this is probably that his approach was critical and eclectic, building upon every school that had something to offer. He however inspired generations of thinkers, especially in the tradition of Neo-Walrasianism, such as [[Michio Morishima]], [[Frank H. Hahn]], and [[Takashi Negishi]].
+
In many ways, Hicks' work is the standard of how economics should be done: without partisanship for favored theories but learning from all, constantly searching for new ideas and staying attached to none, and his own most severe critic.
 +
 
 +
Although his work was deep enough, and his influence strong enough to form a school of thought, Hicks never gathered any great number of followers. The reason for this is probably that his approach was critical and eclectic, building upon every school that had something to offer. He did, however, inspire generations of thinkers, especially in the neo-Walrasian tradition, including [[Michio Morishima]], [[Frank H. Hahn]], and [[Takashi Negishi]].
  
 
==Publications==
 
==Publications==
  
 
* Hicks, John R. 1932. ''The Theory of Wages''. London: Macmillan.
 
* Hicks, John R. 1932. ''The Theory of Wages''. London: Macmillan.
* Hicks, John R. 1939. The Foundations of Welfare Economics. ''Economic Journal, 69'', 696-712.
+
* Hicks, John R. 1939. "The Foundations of Welfare Economics." ''Economic Journal'', 69, 696-712.
* Hicks, John R. 1940. The Valuation of Social Income. ''Economica, 7'', 105-24.
+
* Hicks, John R. [1939] 2001. ''Value and Capital''. Oxford University Press. ISBN 0198282699
* Hicks, John R. 1941. The Rehabilitation of Consumers' Surplus. ''Review of Economic Studies, 8'', 108-16.
+
* Hicks, John R. 1940. "The Valuation of Social Income." ''Economica,'' 7, 105-24.
* Hicks, John R. 1959. ''Essays in World Economics'', Oxford: Clarendon.  
+
* Hicks, John R. 1941. "The Rehabilitation of Consumers' Surplus." ''Review of Economic Studies,'' 8, 108-16.
 +
* Hicks, John R. [1942] 1971. ''The Social Framework: An Introduction to Economics''. Oxford University Press. ISBN 0198281730
 +
* Hicks, John R. [1950] 1979. ''A Contribution to the Theory of the Trade Cycle''. Oxford University Press. ISBN 0198284160
 +
* Hicks, John R. [1956] 1986. ''A Revision of Demand Theory''. Oxford University Press. ISBN 0198285507
 +
* Hicks, John R. 1959. ''Essays in World Economics''. Oxford: Clarendon.  
 
* Hicks, John R. 1965. ''Capital and Growth''. Oxford: Clarendon.  
 
* Hicks, John R. 1965. ''Capital and Growth''. Oxford: Clarendon.  
* Hicks, John R. 1971 (original published in 1942). ''The Social Framework: An Introduction to Economics''. Oxford University Press. ISBN 0198281730
+
* Hicks, John R. [1969] 2001. ''A Theory of Economic History''. Oxford University Press. ISBN 0198811632
* Hicks, John R. 1975. The Scope and Status of Welfare Economics. ''Oxford Economics Papers, 27''(3), 307-26.  
+
* Hicks, John R. 1975. "The Scope and Status of Welfare Economics." ''Oxford Economics Papers,'' Vol. 27, No. 3, 307-26.  
 
* Hicks, John R. 1977. ''Economic Perspectives''. Oxford University Press. ISBN 0198284071
 
* Hicks, John R. 1977. ''Economic Perspectives''. Oxford University Press. ISBN 0198284071
* Hicks, John R. 1979 (original published in 1950). ''A Contribution to the Theory of the Trade Cycle''. Oxford University Press. ISBN 0198284160
+
* Hicks, John R. 1980.  "IS-LM: An Explanation." ''Journal of Post Keynesian Economics'', Vol. 3, No. 2, 139-54
* Hicks, John R. 1980.  IS-LM: An Explanation. ''Journal of Post Keynesian Economics'', 3(2), 139-54
 
 
* Hicks, John R. 1981. ''Wealth and Welfare: Vol I. of Collected Essays in Economic Theory''. Harvard University Press. ISBN 0674137418
 
* Hicks, John R. 1981. ''Wealth and Welfare: Vol I. of Collected Essays in Economic Theory''. Harvard University Press. ISBN 0674137418
 
* Hicks, John R. 1982. ''Money, Interest and Wages: Vol. II of Collected Essays in Economic Theory''. Harvard University Press. ISBN 0674584252
 
* Hicks, John R. 1982. ''Money, Interest and Wages: Vol. II of Collected Essays in Economic Theory''. Harvard University Press. ISBN 0674584252
 
* Hicks, John R. 1983. ''Classics and Moderns: Vol. III of Collected Essays in Economic Theory''. Harvard University Press. ISBN 0674137434.
 
* Hicks, John R. 1983. ''Classics and Moderns: Vol. III of Collected Essays in Economic Theory''. Harvard University Press. ISBN 0674137434.
* Hicks, John R. 1986 (original published in 1956). ''A Revision of Demand Theory'', Oxford University Press. ISBN 0198285507
 
* Hicks, John R. 2001 (original published in 1969). ''A Theory of Economic History''. Oxford University Press. ISBN 0198811632
 
* Hicks, John R. 2001 (original published in 1939). ''Value and Capital''. Oxford University Press. ISBN 0198282699
 
  
 
==References==
 
==References==
 
+
* Bliss, Christopher. 1987. "Hicks, John Richard." in ''The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics''. edited by Milgate, Murray, and Peter Newman John Eatwell. Vol. 2. 641-46. Macmillan.  
* ''Autobiography''. NobelPrize.org, on <http://nobelprize.org>. Retrieved on June 16, 2007, <http://nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economics/laureates/1972/hicks-autobio.html>
+
* [http://nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economics/laureates/1972/hicks-autobio.html Autobiography of John Richard Hicks]. NobelPrize.org. Retrieved on June 16, 2007.
* Bliss, Christopher. 1987. Hicks, John Richard. In Murray Milgate & Peter Newman John Eatwell (eds.) ''The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics'', vol. 2, pp. 641-46. Macmillan.  
 
 
* Wood, John. ''Sir John Hicks: Critical Assessments'' (Second Series). Routledge. ISBN 0415367077
 
* Wood, John. ''Sir John Hicks: Critical Assessments'' (Second Series). Routledge. ISBN 0415367077
  
 
==External links==
 
==External links==
 +
All links retrieved August 3, 2022.
 +
* [http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/bios/Hicks.html Biography of John R. Hicks (1904-1989)] – The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics.
 +
  
* [http://nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economics/laureates/1972/hicks-autobio.html Autobiography] – Hicks’s autobiography from 1992
 
* [http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/multacc/hicksacc.htm Hicks's Trade Cycle] – On Hicks’s work
 
* [http://www.bized.co.uk/virtual/economy/library/economists/hicksth.htm Hicks’s work] – On some of Hicks’s theories
 
* [http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/keynes/hickshansen.htm The Hicks-Hansen IS-LM Model] – On the model
 
* [http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/hicks.htm John Richard Hicks] - Biography
 
* [http://www.britannica.com/eb/article-9040364/Sir-John-R-Hicks John Richard Hicks] – Biography on Encyclopedia Britannica
 
* [http://nobelprize.org/economics/laureates/1972/hicks-lecture.html The Mainspring of Economic Growth] – Hicks’s Nobel Prize lecture from 1973
 
* [http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/margrev/distrib.htm The Neoclassical Theory of Distribution] – On the context of Hisks’s work
 
* [http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/keynes/islmcont.htm The Neo-Keynesian World] – Neo-Keynesian theories
 
* [http://nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economics/laureates/1972/press.html Press Release] of Nobel award (1972)
 
  
 +
{{Nobel laureates in economics 1969-1975}}
 
{{Credits|John_Hicks|125804703|}}
 
{{Credits|John_Hicks|125804703|}}

Latest revision as of 07:42, 3 August 2022

Sir John Richard Hicks (April 8, 1904 – May 20, 1989) was a British economist, one of the most influential economists of the twentieth century. He contributed to the field of economics with his IS/LM model, which summarized the Keynesian view of macroeconomics in graphical form. He also introduced the idea of elasticity of substitution, which showed that labor-saving technical progress does not reduce labor's share of income. In his book, Value and Capital, one of the first works on general equilibrium theory, Hicks showed that value could be understood without having to quantify utility. He also contributed to welfare economics, developing a way to compare the impact of different policies, regarding the one that produced sufficient gain to compensate for any losses and still provide benefit to be worthy of implementation.

Hicks was not a follower of a particular school of economics, but rather took an eclectic approach, reviving and further developing the best of each school. Thus, his work was an attempt to better understand all types of economic forces and to be better able to establish an economically stable human society, benefiting all people. In 1972, Hicks was awarded the Nobel Prize in Economics, together with Kenneth J. Arrow, for his contributions to general economic equilibrium theory and welfare theory.

Life

John Richard Hicks was born in Leamington Spa, Warwickshire, England, the son of a journalist. He was educated at Clifton College (1917-1922) and later received a mathematical scholarship to study at Balliol College, at the University of Oxford, where he enrolled in 1923.

Although initially specializing in mathematics, Hicks was not content and had a strong interest in literature and history. He transferred in 1923 to the newly opened School of Philosophy, Politics and Economics. However, he did not have adequate qualification in any of the subjects that he studied, and graduated with a second-class degree.

In the 1920s, economists were very scarce and so Hicks picked up a temporary lectureship at the London School of Economics, which was then continued. He started as a labor economist, doing descriptive work on industrial relations, but gradually moved over to the analytical side. He discovered that his knowledge of mathematics, by that time almost forgotten, could be revived, and was sufficient to cope with what anyone used in economics.

In 1935, Hicks married fellow economist, Ursula Webb. At that time he transferred to Cambridge University where he became a lecturer in economics. During his three years in Cambridge, Hicks completed his significant book, Value and Capital, which was based on the work he had done in London. He was also a fellow of Gonville and Caius College, at Cambridge, from 1935 to 1938.

In 1938, Hicks became professor at the University of Manchester. It was there that he started to focus mainly on welfare economics, and its application to social accounting. In 1946, he returned to Oxford, first as a research fellow of Nuffield College (1946-1952), then as Drummond Professor of Political Economy (1952-1965), and finally as a research fellow of All Souls College (1965-1971).

Hicks became a fellow of the British Academy in 1942; a foreign member of the Royal Swedish Academy in 1948, of the Accademia dei Lincei, Italy, in 1952, and of the American Academy in 1958. He was knighted in 1964. He received honorary doctor degrees from several British Universities—Glasgow, Manchester, Leicester, East Anglia, and Warwick—as well as of the Technical University of Lisbon, Portugal.

In 1972, Hicks received the Nobel Prize in Economics, together with Kenneth J. Arrow, for his work on general economic equilibrium theory and welfare theory.

John Hicks died on May 20, 1989 in Blockley, Gloucestershire, Great Britain.

Work

Microeconomics

Hicks' early work was as a labor economist culminated in The Theory of Wages (1932), still considered a standard in the field. In that book he gave his own interpretation of marginal productivity theory, attempting to reinvoke interest in it. In the book he also introduced his famous "elasticity of substitution" which is defined as “the elasticity of the ratio of two inputs to a production (or utility) function with respect to the ratio of their marginal products (or utilities).” Using this, Hicks was able to show that, contrary to Karl Marx's analysis, labor-saving technical progress does not necessarily reduce labor's share of national income.

In the mid-1930s, Hicks worked on a way to unite various theories of imperfect competition, introducing the concept of "conjectural variations." He also attempted to resurrect the Lausanne School of economics developed by Léon Walras and Vilfredo Pareto. The central feature of the Lausanne School was its development of general equilibrium theory, and he attempted to introduce this to the English-speaking world. In 1934, he tried to do the same with his review of Gunnar Myrdal's work, which drew attention to the Stockholm School of economics.

His magnum opus was Value and Capital, published in 1939. This book built upon ordinal utility and mainstreamed the now-standard distinction in demand theory between the substitution effect and the income effect for an individual for the case of two consumer goods. It generalized analysis to the case of one consumer good and a composite good, that is, all other goods. It also aggregated individuals and businesses through demand and supply across the economy, anticipating the aggregation problem most acutely for the stock of capital goods.

Pareto improvements are a small subset of Kaldor-Hicks improvements.

Hicks' book introduced general equilibrium theory to an English-speaking audience, refined the theory for dynamic analysis, and for the first time attempted a rigorous statement of stability conditions for general equilibrium. In the course of analysis Hicks formalized comparative statics. In the same year, he also developed the famous "compensation" criteria, called the Kaldor-Hicks efficiency, for welfare comparisons of alternative public policies or economic states. In essence, Hicks suggested the criterion that would judge an outcome to be preferable if those who gain by the measure would still gain if they had to compensate those who would lose. Based on this compensation criterion, policies could be compared and the one leading to the greatest net benefit would be implemented.

Under Pareto efficiency (developed by Vilfredo Pareto), an outcome is more efficient if at least one person is made better off and nobody is made worse off. This seems a reasonable way to determine whether an outcome is efficient or not. However, some believe that in practice it is almost impossible to make any large change such as an economic policy change without making at least one person worse off. Under ideal conditions, exchanges are Pareto efficient since individuals would not voluntarily entered into them unless they were mutually beneficial. Using Kaldor-Hicks efficiency, an outcome is more efficient if those that are made better off could "in theory" compensate those that are made worse off and lead to a Pareto optimal outcome. Thus, a more efficient outcome can in fact leave some people worse off. The criterion is used because it is argued that it is justifiable for society as a whole to be better off, even though it involves making some worse off if this means a greater gain for others.

Macroeconomics

Hicks' most familiar contribution to macroeconomics was the Hicks-Hansen IS-LM model, which formalized the theory of John Maynard Keynes. The model describes the economy as a balance between three commodities: money, consumption, and investment. It can be presented as a graph of two intersecting lines in the first quadrant.

The IS curve moves to the right, causing higher interest rates and expansion in the "real" economy (real GDP).

The horizontal axis represents national income or real gross domestic product and is labelled Y. The vertical axis represents the real interest rate, i.

The IS schedule is drawn as a downward-sloping curve. The initials IS stand for "Investment/Saving equilibrium," but since 1937 they have been used to represent the locus of all equilibria where total spending (Consumer spending + planned private Investment + Government purchases + net exports) equals an economy's total output (equivalent to income, Y, or GDP). The level of real GDP (Y) is determined along this line for each interest rate.

The LM schedule is an upward-sloping curve representing the role of finance and money. The initials LM stand for "Liquidity preference/Money supply equilibrium" but is easier to understand as the equilibrium of the demand to hold money as an asset and the supply of money by banks and the central bank. The interest rate is determined along this line for each level of real GDP.

The Hicks-Hansen model illustrates graphically Keynes' conclusion that an economy can be in equilibrium with less than 100 percent employment. This model eventually became the starting point of the Neo-Keynesian synthesis in economic systems which dominated in the mid-twentieth century. It later came under criticism in the early 1970s, when high inflation and growing unemployment seemed to be incompatible with the predictions of the system. In one of his later works, published in 1980, Hicks criticized his own model, asserting it had omitted some crucial components of Keynes' arguments, especially those related to uncertainty.

Among his other contributions to macroeconomics is the concept of "liquidity trap"—which happens in a stagnant economy, when the nominal interest rate is close or equal to zero, and when people start to keep their savings only in short-term bank accounts, expecting a recession. He also developed the concept of "temporary equilibrium," enlarged the "Linear Theory" and elaborated on the von Neumann turnpike.

In the 1970s, Hicks worked to resurrect the Austrian school of economics, attempting to formalize the Austrian theory of capital which included both fixed and circulating capital.

Legacy

John Richard Hicks was one of the most important and influential economists of the twentieth century. He broke with Marshallian tradition that dominated the English-speaking world in the 1930s, in what is commonly known as “Paretian revival,” and reintroduced the theories of Leon Walras, the Austrian school, and the Swedish school based on the work of Gunnar Myrdal and Bertil Ohlin. His work, together with other great economic thinkers such as Paul Samuelson, Oskar Lange, Abba Lerner, Maurice Allais, and Harold Hotellin, helped consolidate the Marginalist revolution, which started some 50 years before.

In many ways, Hicks' work is the standard of how economics should be done: without partisanship for favored theories but learning from all, constantly searching for new ideas and staying attached to none, and his own most severe critic.

Although his work was deep enough, and his influence strong enough to form a school of thought, Hicks never gathered any great number of followers. The reason for this is probably that his approach was critical and eclectic, building upon every school that had something to offer. He did, however, inspire generations of thinkers, especially in the neo-Walrasian tradition, including Michio Morishima, Frank H. Hahn, and Takashi Negishi.

Publications

  • Hicks, John R. 1932. The Theory of Wages. London: Macmillan.
  • Hicks, John R. 1939. "The Foundations of Welfare Economics." Economic Journal, 69, 696-712.
  • Hicks, John R. [1939] 2001. Value and Capital. Oxford University Press. ISBN 0198282699
  • Hicks, John R. 1940. "The Valuation of Social Income." Economica, 7, 105-24.
  • Hicks, John R. 1941. "The Rehabilitation of Consumers' Surplus." Review of Economic Studies, 8, 108-16.
  • Hicks, John R. [1942] 1971. The Social Framework: An Introduction to Economics. Oxford University Press. ISBN 0198281730
  • Hicks, John R. [1950] 1979. A Contribution to the Theory of the Trade Cycle. Oxford University Press. ISBN 0198284160
  • Hicks, John R. [1956] 1986. A Revision of Demand Theory. Oxford University Press. ISBN 0198285507
  • Hicks, John R. 1959. Essays in World Economics. Oxford: Clarendon.
  • Hicks, John R. 1965. Capital and Growth. Oxford: Clarendon.
  • Hicks, John R. [1969] 2001. A Theory of Economic History. Oxford University Press. ISBN 0198811632
  • Hicks, John R. 1975. "The Scope and Status of Welfare Economics." Oxford Economics Papers, Vol. 27, No. 3, 307-26.
  • Hicks, John R. 1977. Economic Perspectives. Oxford University Press. ISBN 0198284071
  • Hicks, John R. 1980. "IS-LM: An Explanation." Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, Vol. 3, No. 2, 139-54
  • Hicks, John R. 1981. Wealth and Welfare: Vol I. of Collected Essays in Economic Theory. Harvard University Press. ISBN 0674137418
  • Hicks, John R. 1982. Money, Interest and Wages: Vol. II of Collected Essays in Economic Theory. Harvard University Press. ISBN 0674584252
  • Hicks, John R. 1983. Classics and Moderns: Vol. III of Collected Essays in Economic Theory. Harvard University Press. ISBN 0674137434.

References
ISBN links support NWE through referral fees

  • Bliss, Christopher. 1987. "Hicks, John Richard." in The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics. edited by Milgate, Murray, and Peter Newman John Eatwell. Vol. 2. 641-46. Macmillan.
  • Autobiography of John Richard Hicks. NobelPrize.org. Retrieved on June 16, 2007.
  • Wood, John. Sir John Hicks: Critical Assessments (Second Series). Routledge. ISBN 0415367077

External links

All links retrieved August 3, 2022.


Credits

New World Encyclopedia writers and editors rewrote and completed the Wikipedia article in accordance with New World Encyclopedia standards. This article abides by terms of the Creative Commons CC-by-sa 3.0 License (CC-by-sa), which may be used and disseminated with proper attribution. Credit is due under the terms of this license that can reference both the New World Encyclopedia contributors and the selfless volunteer contributors of the Wikimedia Foundation. To cite this article click here for a list of acceptable citing formats.The history of earlier contributions by wikipedians is accessible to researchers here:

The history of this article since it was imported to New World Encyclopedia:

Note: Some restrictions may apply to use of individual images which are separately licensed.