Encyclopedia, Difference between revisions of "Antoine Augustin Cournot" - New World

From New World Encyclopedia
Line 6: Line 6:
 
[[Image:Antoine Augustin Cournot.jpeg|thumb|Antoine Augustin Cournot]]
 
[[Image:Antoine Augustin Cournot.jpeg|thumb|Antoine Augustin Cournot]]
  
'''Antoine Augustin Cournot''' (August, 28 1801 &ndash March 31, 1877) was a [[French people|French]] [[philosopher]] and [[mathematician]].  
+
'''Antoine Augustin Cournot''' (August 28, 1801 – March 31, 1877) was a [[French people|French]] [[philosopher]] and [[mathematician]].  
  
 
==Biography==
 
==Biography==
'''Antoine Augustin Cournot''' was born in the small town of Gray (Haute-Saône) in [[France]]. He was educated in the schools of Gray until he was fifteen. At nineteen he enrolled in a mathematical preparatory course at a school in Besançon, and subsequently won entry into the École Normale Supérieure in Paris in 1821. In 1822, Cournot transferred to the [[Sorbonne]], obtaining a lecentiate in [[mathematics]] in 1823.
+
'''Antoine Augustin Cournot''' was born on August 28, 1801 in the small town of Gray (Haute-Saône) in [[France]]. He was educated in the schools of Gray until he was fifteen. At nineteen he enrolled in a mathematical preparatory course at a school in Besançon, and subsequently won entry into the École Normale Supérieure in Paris in 1821. In 1822, Cournot transferred to the [[Sorbonne]], obtaining a lecentiate in [[mathematics]] in 1823.
  
 
In Paris, he attended seminars at the Academie des Sciences and the salon of the economist Joseph Droz. Among his main intellectual influences were [[Pierre-Simon Laplace]], [[Joseph-Louis Lagrange]], and Hachette, a former disciple of Marie-Antoine [[Condorcet]], who started him on the principles of ''mathematique sociale'', i.e. the idea that the [[social sciences]], like the natural [[science]]s, could be dealt with mathematically. Cournot counted the young mathematician Lejeune [[Dirichlet]] as a close friend.
 
In Paris, he attended seminars at the Academie des Sciences and the salon of the economist Joseph Droz. Among his main intellectual influences were [[Pierre-Simon Laplace]], [[Joseph-Louis Lagrange]], and Hachette, a former disciple of Marie-Antoine [[Condorcet]], who started him on the principles of ''mathematique sociale'', i.e. the idea that the [[social sciences]], like the natural [[science]]s, could be dealt with mathematically. Cournot counted the young mathematician Lejeune [[Dirichlet]] as a close friend.
Line 21: Line 21:
 
Cournot began with some preliminary remarks on the role of [[mathematics]] applied to the [[social sciences]]. He believed that [[economics|economists]] must utilize the tools of mathematics only to establish probable limits and to express less stable facts in more absolute terms. He further held that the practical uses of mathematics in economics do not necessarily involve strict numerical precision, and that his purpose in using mathematics is merely to guide his reasoning and illustrate his argument rather than lead to any numerical calculations.
 
Cournot began with some preliminary remarks on the role of [[mathematics]] applied to the [[social sciences]]. He believed that [[economics|economists]] must utilize the tools of mathematics only to establish probable limits and to express less stable facts in more absolute terms. He further held that the practical uses of mathematics in economics do not necessarily involve strict numerical precision, and that his purpose in using mathematics is merely to guide his reasoning and illustrate his argument rather than lead to any numerical calculations.
  
It was in 1838 that Cournot published his economics masterpiece, the ''Recherches sur les principes mathématiques de la théorie des richesses'' translated as ''Researches on the Mathematical Principles of the Theory of Wealth'' (1838, 1938). In this book he presented his concepts of [[monopoly]], [[oligopoly]], and perfect [[competition]].  
+
It was in 1838 that Cournot published his economics masterpiece, the ''Recherches sur les principes mathématiques de la théorie des richesses'' translated as ''Researches on the Mathematical Principles of the Theory of Wealth'' (1838, 1938). In this book he presented his concepts of [[Antoine Augustin Cournot#Monopoly|monopoly]], [[oligopoly]] (in Cournot's case "[[Antoine Augustin Cournot#Duopoly|duopoly]]"), and [[Antoine Augustin Cournot#Perfect Competition|perfect competition]].  
  
 
In demonstrating the equilibrium of his oligopoly game, Cournot introduced a form of "best-reply dynamics," in which each firm selects the quantity that maximizes its [[profit]] in response to the total industry output of the previous period. Through this, he introduced the ideas of [[function]]s and [[probability theory|probability]] into economic analysis.
 
In demonstrating the equilibrium of his oligopoly game, Cournot introduced a form of "best-reply dynamics," in which each firm selects the quantity that maximizes its [[profit]] in response to the total industry output of the previous period. Through this, he introduced the ideas of [[function]]s and [[probability theory|probability]] into economic analysis.
Line 27: Line 27:
 
===The "Recherches"===
 
===The "Recherches"===
  
In the first three chapters of ''Recherches'', Cournot runs through the definition of wealth, absolute vs. relative [[price]]s and the law of one price.  
+
In the beginning of ''Recherches'', Cournot runs through the definition of wealth, absolute vs. relative [[price]]s and the law of one price.  
  
Then, in Chapter 4, he unveils his first formula for the rule of [[supply]] and [[demand]] as a function of price. He wrote it in general form as
+
Then, he unveils his first formula for the rule of [[supply]] and [[demand]] as a function of price. He wrote it in general form as
  
 
:'''[ D =  f ( p) ],'''  
 
:'''[ D =  f ( p) ],'''  
Line 44: Line 44:
 
<blockquote>''the utility of the article, the nature of the services it can render or the enjoyments it can procure, on the habits and customs of the people, on the average wealth, and on the scale on which wealth is distributed.'' (1838, p. 47).</blockquote>
 
<blockquote>''the utility of the article, the nature of the services it can render or the enjoyments it can procure, on the habits and customs of the people, on the average wealth, and on the scale on which wealth is distributed.'' (1838, p. 47).</blockquote>
  
In Chapter 5, Cournot jumps immediately into an analysis of monopoly. Here, the concept of a profit-maximizing producer is introduced. Cournot introduces the '''cost function….. f ( D ),''' where D is demand or quantity, and discusses decreasing, constant, and increasing costs to scale. He shows mathematically how a producer will choose to produce at a quantity (denoted by the first derivative of cost function  f’ [ . ] ) and, hence, where marginal revenue f' [ D ( p ) ] is equal to marginal cost y ( p ), where marginal cost is thus the extra (or the increase in total) cost required to produce 1 extra unit of output (or the reduction in total cost from producing 1 unit less):
+
====Monopoly====
 +
Next, Cournot jumps immediately into an analysis of [[monopoly]]. Here, the concept of a profit-maximizing producer is introduced. Cournot introduces the '''cost function….. f ( D ),''' where D is demand or quantity, and discusses decreasing, constant, and increasing costs to scale. He shows mathematically how a producer will choose to produce at a quantity (denoted by the first derivative of cost function  f’ [ . ] ) and, hence, where marginal revenue f' [ D ( p ) ] is equal to marginal cost y ( p ), where marginal cost is thus the extra (or the increase in total) cost required to produce 1 extra unit of output (or the reduction in total cost from producing 1 unit less):
  
 
:'''f ' [ D ( p) ] = y ( p).'''
 
:'''f ' [ D ( p) ] = y ( p).'''
  
====Cournot’s duopoly model====
+
====Duopoly====
  
Cournot presented his famous "duopoly" model with the following features:  
+
Cournot presented his famous model of a "duopoly" (a simpler form of [[oligopoly]] where only two producers dominate a [[market]]), with the following features:  
  
 
*There is more than one firm and all firms produce a homogeneous product   
 
*There is more than one firm and all firms produce a homogeneous product   
Line 59: Line 60:
 
*There is strategic behavior by the firms.  
 
*There is strategic behavior by the firms.  
  
[[Price]] is a commonly known decreasing function of total output. All firms know the total number of firms in the [[market]], and take the output of the others as given. Each firm has a cost function. Normally the cost functions are treated as common knowledge. The cost functions may be the same or different among firms. The market price is set at a level such that demand equals the total quantity produced by both firms. Each firm takes the quantity set by its competitors as a given, evaluates its residual demand, and then behaves as a monopoly.
+
[[Price]] is a commonly known decreasing function of total output. All firms know the total number of firms in the [[market]], and take the output of the others as given. Each firm has a cost function. Normally the cost functions are treated as common knowledge. The cost functions may be the same or different among firms. The market price is set at a level such that demand equals the total quantity produced by both firms. Each firm takes the quantity set by its competitors as a given, evaluates its residual demand, and then behaves as a [[monopoly]].
  
 
Cournot sets up a mathematical model with two rival producers of a homogeneous product. Each producer is conscious that his rival's quantity decision will also impact the price he faces, and thus his [[profit]]s, but each firm decides independently how much to produce and put on the market. However, the market price of the commodity is determined by the inverse demand function applied to the sum of what both firms put on the market. Consequently, each producer chooses a quantity that maximizes his profits subject to the quantity reactions of his rival.  
 
Cournot sets up a mathematical model with two rival producers of a homogeneous product. Each producer is conscious that his rival's quantity decision will also impact the price he faces, and thus his [[profit]]s, but each firm decides independently how much to produce and put on the market. However, the market price of the commodity is determined by the inverse demand function applied to the sum of what both firms put on the market. Consequently, each producer chooses a quantity that maximizes his profits subject to the quantity reactions of his rival.  
Line 67: Line 68:
 
Comparing solutions, Cournot notes that under duopoly, the price is lower and the total quantity produced greater than under [[monopoly]]. He runs with this insight, showing that as the number of producers increases, the quantity becomes greater and the price lower.
 
Comparing solutions, Cournot notes that under duopoly, the price is lower and the total quantity produced greater than under [[monopoly]]. He runs with this insight, showing that as the number of producers increases, the quantity becomes greater and the price lower.
  
In Chapter 8, he introduces the case of unlimited [[competition]], i.e. where the quantity of producers is so great that the entry or departure of a individual producer has a negligible effect on the total quantity produced. He goes on to derive the prices and quantities in this "perfectly competitive" situation, in particular showing that, at the solution, price is equal to the marginal cost y ( p ) as defined above.
+
====Perfect Competition====
 +
Cournot introduces the case of unlimited [[competition]], i.e. where the quantity of producers is so great that the entry or departure of a individual producer has a negligible effect on the total quantity produced. He goes on to derive the prices and quantities in this "perfectly competitive" situation, in particular showing that, at the solution, price is equal to the marginal cost y ( p ) as defined above.
  
 
The outcome is found by applying Cournot's concept of [[game theory]]. The firms in the model do not collude  to achieve monopoly, but still achieve greater profits than they would in a competitive market. A nice feature of the model is that as more firms are added, the price goes to the competitive price.   
 
The outcome is found by applying Cournot's concept of [[game theory]]. The firms in the model do not collude  to achieve monopoly, but still achieve greater profits than they would in a competitive market. A nice feature of the model is that as more firms are added, the price goes to the competitive price.   
  
In the remainder of his book, Cournot takes up what he calls the "communication of markets," or [[trade]] of a single good between regions. He analyzes two isolated countries and one homogeneous product. He shows that the impact of opening trade between the two countries leads to the equalization of prices, with the lower cost producer exporting to the higher cost country.
+
====Communication of markets====
 
+
In the remainder of his book, Cournot takes up what he calls the "communication of markets," or [[trade]] of a single good between regions. He analyzes two isolated countries and one homogeneous product. He shows that the impact of opening trade between the two countries leads to the equalization of prices, with the lower cost producer exporting to the higher cost country. Cournot tries to prove that there are conditions where the opening of trade will lead to a decline in the quantity of the product and lower revenue.  
Cournot tries to prove that there are conditions where the opening of trade will lead to a decline in the quantity of the good and lower revenue.  
 
  
 
Finally, Cournot also acknowledged that the solutions obtained via his "partial equilibrium" theory are incomplete. He recognized the need to take multiple markets into account and trying to solve for the general equilibrium, but "this would surpass the powers of mathematical analysis" (Cournot, 1838, p.127).
 
Finally, Cournot also acknowledged that the solutions obtained via his "partial equilibrium" theory are incomplete. He recognized the need to take multiple markets into account and trying to solve for the general equilibrium, but "this would surpass the powers of mathematical analysis" (Cournot, 1838, p.127).
Line 84: Line 85:
 
In 1843, Cournot made his first serious attempt at improving [[probability theory]] in his ''Exposition''. He differentiated between three types of probabilities: objective, subjective, and philosophical. The former two follow their standard [[ontology|ontological]] and [[epistemology|epistemological]] definitions. The third category refers to probabilities "which depends mainly on the idea that we have of the simplicity of the laws of nature." (Cournot 1843, p. 440).
 
In 1843, Cournot made his first serious attempt at improving [[probability theory]] in his ''Exposition''. He differentiated between three types of probabilities: objective, subjective, and philosophical. The former two follow their standard [[ontology|ontological]] and [[epistemology|epistemological]] definitions. The third category refers to probabilities "which depends mainly on the idea that we have of the simplicity of the laws of nature." (Cournot 1843, p. 440).
  
==Cournot’s legacy==
+
==Legacy==
  
 
Cournot was primarily a [[mathematics|mathematician]], but did have some influence over [[economics]]. His theories on [[monopoly|monopolies]] and "duopolies" are still famous. In 1838 the book ''Researches on the Mathematical Principals of the Theory of Wealth'' was published, in which he used the application of the formulae and symbols of mathematics in economic analysis.  
 
Cournot was primarily a [[mathematics|mathematician]], but did have some influence over [[economics]]. His theories on [[monopoly|monopolies]] and "duopolies" are still famous. In 1838 the book ''Researches on the Mathematical Principals of the Theory of Wealth'' was published, in which he used the application of the formulae and symbols of mathematics in economic analysis.  

Revision as of 20:20, 21 August 2006

File:Antoine Augustin Cournot.jpeg
Antoine Augustin Cournot

Antoine Augustin Cournot (August 28, 1801 – March 31, 1877) was a French philosopher and mathematician.

Biography

Antoine Augustin Cournot was born on August 28, 1801 in the small town of Gray (Haute-Saône) in France. He was educated in the schools of Gray until he was fifteen. At nineteen he enrolled in a mathematical preparatory course at a school in Besançon, and subsequently won entry into the École Normale Supérieure in Paris in 1821. In 1822, Cournot transferred to the Sorbonne, obtaining a lecentiate in mathematics in 1823.

In Paris, he attended seminars at the Academie des Sciences and the salon of the economist Joseph Droz. Among his main intellectual influences were Pierre-Simon Laplace, Joseph-Louis Lagrange, and Hachette, a former disciple of Marie-Antoine Condorcet, who started him on the principles of mathematique sociale, i.e. the idea that the social sciences, like the natural sciences, could be dealt with mathematically. Cournot counted the young mathematician Lejeune Dirichlet as a close friend.

From 1823, Cournot was employed as a literary advisor to Marshal Gouvoin Saint Cyr and as a tutor to his son. In 1829, Cournot acquired a doctorate in sciences, focusing on mechanics and astronomy.

In 1834, Cournot found a permanent appointment as professor of analysis and mechanics at Lyons. A year later, Siméon-Denis Poisson secured him a rectorship at the Academy of Grenoble. Although his duties were mostly administrative, Cournot excelled at them. In 1838, (again, at the instigation of the loyal Poisson), Cournot was called to Paris as Inspecteur Général des Études. In that same year, he was made a Knight of the Légion d'honneur (he was elevated to an Officer in 1845). By the time Cournot died in 1877, he was nearly blind.

Work

Cournot began with some preliminary remarks on the role of mathematics applied to the social sciences. He believed that economists must utilize the tools of mathematics only to establish probable limits and to express less stable facts in more absolute terms. He further held that the practical uses of mathematics in economics do not necessarily involve strict numerical precision, and that his purpose in using mathematics is merely to guide his reasoning and illustrate his argument rather than lead to any numerical calculations.

It was in 1838 that Cournot published his economics masterpiece, the Recherches sur les principes mathématiques de la théorie des richesses translated as Researches on the Mathematical Principles of the Theory of Wealth (1838, 1938). In this book he presented his concepts of monopoly, oligopoly (in Cournot's case "duopoly"), and perfect competition.

In demonstrating the equilibrium of his oligopoly game, Cournot introduced a form of "best-reply dynamics," in which each firm selects the quantity that maximizes its profit in response to the total industry output of the previous period. Through this, he introduced the ideas of functions and probability into economic analysis.

The "Recherches"

In the beginning of Recherches, Cournot runs through the definition of wealth, absolute vs. relative prices and the law of one price.

Then, he unveils his first formula for the rule of supply and demand as a function of price. He wrote it in general form as

[ D = f ( p) ],

where D stands for demand (also quantity) and p stands for price.

He assumes that the function (f), is continuous and takes it as an empirical proposition that the demand function is downward-sloping (the loi de débit, "law of demand") and proceeds to draw it in price-quantity space. He also introduces the idea of "elasticity," but does not write it down in a mathematical formula. It is important to note that Cournot's "demand function" is not a demand schedule in the modern sense.

His curve, [ D = f ( p ) ], merely summarizes the empirical relationship between price and quantity sold, rather than the conceptual relationship between price and the quantity sought by buyers. Cournot refuses to derive demand from any "utility"-based theories of individual behavior. As he noted:

accessory ideas of utility, scarcity, and suitability to the needs and enjoyments of mankind...are variable and by nature indeterminate, and consequently ill suited for the foundation of a scientific theory. (Cournot, 1838, p.10)

Cournot was satisfied with merely acknowledging that the functional form of f ( . ) depends on

the utility of the article, the nature of the services it can render or the enjoyments it can procure, on the habits and customs of the people, on the average wealth, and on the scale on which wealth is distributed. (1838, p. 47).

Monopoly

Next, Cournot jumps immediately into an analysis of monopoly. Here, the concept of a profit-maximizing producer is introduced. Cournot introduces the cost function….. f ( D ), where D is demand or quantity, and discusses decreasing, constant, and increasing costs to scale. He shows mathematically how a producer will choose to produce at a quantity (denoted by the first derivative of cost function f’ [ . ] ) and, hence, where marginal revenue f' [ D ( p ) ] is equal to marginal cost y ( p ), where marginal cost is thus the extra (or the increase in total) cost required to produce 1 extra unit of output (or the reduction in total cost from producing 1 unit less):

f ' [ D ( p) ] = y ( p).

Duopoly

Cournot presented his famous model of a "duopoly" (a simpler form of oligopoly where only two producers dominate a market), with the following features:

  • There is more than one firm and all firms produce a homogeneous product
  • Firms do not cooperate
  • Firms have market power
  • There are barriers to entry
  • Firms compete in quantities, and choose quantities simultaneously
  • There is strategic behavior by the firms.

Price is a commonly known decreasing function of total output. All firms know the total number of firms in the market, and take the output of the others as given. Each firm has a cost function. Normally the cost functions are treated as common knowledge. The cost functions may be the same or different among firms. The market price is set at a level such that demand equals the total quantity produced by both firms. Each firm takes the quantity set by its competitors as a given, evaluates its residual demand, and then behaves as a monopoly.

Cournot sets up a mathematical model with two rival producers of a homogeneous product. Each producer is conscious that his rival's quantity decision will also impact the price he faces, and thus his profits, but each firm decides independently how much to produce and put on the market. However, the market price of the commodity is determined by the inverse demand function applied to the sum of what both firms put on the market. Consequently, each producer chooses a quantity that maximizes his profits subject to the quantity reactions of his rival.

Cournot mathematically derives a deterministic solution, as the quantities chosen by the rival producers are in accordance with each other's anticipated reactions. He shows how this equilibrium can be drawn as the intersection of two "reaction curves."

Comparing solutions, Cournot notes that under duopoly, the price is lower and the total quantity produced greater than under monopoly. He runs with this insight, showing that as the number of producers increases, the quantity becomes greater and the price lower.

Perfect Competition

Cournot introduces the case of unlimited competition, i.e. where the quantity of producers is so great that the entry or departure of a individual producer has a negligible effect on the total quantity produced. He goes on to derive the prices and quantities in this "perfectly competitive" situation, in particular showing that, at the solution, price is equal to the marginal cost y ( p ) as defined above.

The outcome is found by applying Cournot's concept of game theory. The firms in the model do not collude to achieve monopoly, but still achieve greater profits than they would in a competitive market. A nice feature of the model is that as more firms are added, the price goes to the competitive price.

Communication of markets

In the remainder of his book, Cournot takes up what he calls the "communication of markets," or trade of a single good between regions. He analyzes two isolated countries and one homogeneous product. He shows that the impact of opening trade between the two countries leads to the equalization of prices, with the lower cost producer exporting to the higher cost country. Cournot tries to prove that there are conditions where the opening of trade will lead to a decline in the quantity of the product and lower revenue.

Finally, Cournot also acknowledged that the solutions obtained via his "partial equilibrium" theory are incomplete. He recognized the need to take multiple markets into account and trying to solve for the general equilibrium, but "this would surpass the powers of mathematical analysis" (Cournot, 1838, p.127).

Critique of the “Recherches”

Cournot's "Recherches" received hardly any response (or when there was a response, it was highly critical) when it came out in 1838. The denizens of the French Liberal School, who dominated the economics profession in France at the time, took no notice of it, leaving Cournot crushed and bitter.

Cournot and probability

In 1843, Cournot made his first serious attempt at improving probability theory in his Exposition. He differentiated between three types of probabilities: objective, subjective, and philosophical. The former two follow their standard ontological and epistemological definitions. The third category refers to probabilities "which depends mainly on the idea that we have of the simplicity of the laws of nature." (Cournot 1843, p. 440).

Legacy

Cournot was primarily a mathematician, but did have some influence over economics. His theories on monopolies and "duopolies" are still famous. In 1838 the book Researches on the Mathematical Principals of the Theory of Wealth was published, in which he used the application of the formulae and symbols of mathematics in economic analysis.

Many economists have come to believe this book to be the point of departure for modern economic analysis, since Cournot introduced the ideas of mathematical functions and probability into economic analysis.

He derived the first formula for the rule of supply and demand as a function of price and in fact was the first to draw supply and demand curves on a graph, anticipating the work of Alfred Marshall by roughly thirty years. In fact, Marshall himself claimed to have read Cournot's work as far back as 1868, and extensively acknowledged Cournot's influence in his 1890 textbook, particularly in his discussion of the theory of the firm.

Today, Cournot’s work is widely recognized in econometrics. He was also a teacher of political economy and mathematics to Auguste Walras, the father of Léon Walras. Cournot and Auguste Walras persuaded Léon Walras to enter the field of political economics. Léon Walras, who studied Cournot's work, claimed that his own equilibrium theory was but the multi-market generalization of Cournot's "partial equilibrium" theory.

References
ISBN links support NWE through referral fees

  • Cournot, A.A., Mémoire sur les applications du calcul des chances à la statistique judiciaire, Journal des mathématiques pures et appliquées, 12. T. 3. 1838, p. 257-334
  • Cournot, A.A., Recherches sur les principes mathématiques de la théorie des richesses (Researches on the Mathematical Principles of the Theory of Wealth) was published in 1838 and reedited in 1938 with an introduction by Georges Lutfalla.
  • Cournot, A.A., Principes de la théorie des richesses,1863
  • Cournot, A.A., Revue sommaire des doctrines économiques, 1877
  • Cournot, A.A., Traité élémentaire de la théorie des fonctions et du calcul infinitésimal, 1841
  • Cournot, A.A., Exposition de la théorie des chances et des probabilités, 1843
  • Cournot, A.A., De l'origine et des limites de la correspondence entre l'agèbre et la géométrie, 1847
  • Cournot, A.A., Essai sur les fondements de nos connaissances et sur les caractères de la critique philosophique, 1851 - Vol. I, Vol. II
  • Cournot, A.A., Traité de l'enchainement des idées fondamentales dans les sciences et dans l'histoire, 1861
  • Cournot, A.A., Principes de la théorie des richesses, 1863
  • Cournot, A.A., Les institutions d'instruction publiques en France, 1864
  • Cournot, A.A., Considérations sur la marche des ideées et des événements dans les temps modernes, 2 vols, 1872
  • Cournot, A.A., Materialisme, vitalisme, rationalisme: Études des données de las science en philosophie, 1875
  • Cournot, A.A., Revue sommaire des doctrines économiques, 1877


External links

For an interesting early 20th century evaluation see


Credits

New World Encyclopedia writers and editors rewrote and completed the Wikipedia article in accordance with New World Encyclopedia standards. This article abides by terms of the Creative Commons CC-by-sa 3.0 License (CC-by-sa), which may be used and disseminated with proper attribution. Credit is due under the terms of this license that can reference both the New World Encyclopedia contributors and the selfless volunteer contributors of the Wikimedia Foundation. To cite this article click here for a list of acceptable citing formats.The history of earlier contributions by wikipedians is accessible to researchers here:

The history of this article since it was imported to New World Encyclopedia:

Note: Some restrictions may apply to use of individual images which are separately licensed.