Encyclopedia, Difference between revisions of "Knut Wicksell" - New World

From New World Encyclopedia
(Started)
Line 3: Line 3:
 
[[Category:Economics]]
 
[[Category:Economics]]
 
[[Category:Biography]]
 
[[Category:Biography]]
 +
{{epname}}
 +
[[Image:Wicksell2.jpg|right|thumb|200px|Knut Wicksell, Swedish economist]]
 +
''' Johan Gustaf Knut Wicksell''' (December 20, 1851 – May 3, 1926) was a [[Sweden|Swedish]] [[economics|economist]], often regarded as the father of [[Stockholm school of economics]]. Elements of his public policy were taken by the Swedish government, becoming part of their program of [[welfare state]]. He tried to synthesis the three theoretical schools of economy - the [[Lausanne school]], the [[Austrian school]], and the [[Ricardians]]. He is also renown for his pioneering work in [[monetary theory]].
  
{{epname}}
+
==Life==
 +
 
 +
'''Knut Wicksell''' was born in Stockholm, [[Sweden]], the son of a relatively successful businessman and real estate broker. He lost both his parents at a relatively young age - his mother died when he was only six years old, and his father when he was fifteen. His father's considerable estate allowed Wicksell to enroll at the [[University of Uppsala]] in 1869 to study [[mathematics]] and [[physics]]. He received his first degree in two years, but continued in graduate studies until 1885 when he received his doctorate in mathematics. In the following years, however, his interests began to shift toward the [[social sciences]], and in particular, [[economics]].
  
 +
In 1887, Wicksell received a scholarship from the Victor Lorén Foundation to study economics in [[Germany]] and [[Austria]]. There he attended lectures by the economist [[Carl Menger]] in [[Vienna]], and also studied at the universities of [[Strassburg]], [[Berlin]] and [[Paris]]. After the return to Stockholm, he continued to draw attention with his radical lectures and papers, but was unable to secure permanent employment.
  
[[Image:Wicksell2.jpg|right|thumb|200px|Knut Wicksell, Swedish economist]]
+
Wicksell took in 1887 a common-law wife, Anna Bugge, with whom he had two sons. He soon found it difficult to support his family on his irregular positions and publications. He received his doctorate in [[economics]] from University of Uppsala in 1896, but still could not get a professorship job. Economics in Sweden at the time was taught as part of the [[law]] school and Wicksell was unable to gain a chair as a professor because of a lack of a law degree. He returned to the University of Uppsala where he completed a four-year study in two years, and subsequently became an associate professor at that university in 1899.
  
''' Johan Gustaf Knut Wicksell''' (December 20, 1851 in [[Stockholm]] – May 3, 1926 in [[Stocksund]]) was a [[Sweden|Swedish]] [[economist]].
+
In 1900, Wicksell became a full professor at [[Lund University]], where his career blossomed. He published numerous works and taught classes in [[tax]] law and [[economics]]. After a lecture in 1908 satirizing the [[Immaculate Conception]], Wicksell was briefly imprisoned for two months, serving the sentence in 1910.
  
==Biography==
+
In 1916, Wicksell retired from his post at Lund and took a position at Stockholm, advising the government on financial and banking issues. In Stockholm, Wicksell continued to supervise doctoral dissertations in economics, of many future great economists of the so-called "[[Stockholm School]]," such as [[Bertil Ohlin]] and [[Gunnar Myrdal]].  
Wicksell was born in Stockholm, Sweden on December 20, 1851. His father was a relatively successful businessman and real estate broker. He lost both his parents at a relatively young age – his mother died when he was only six years old, and his father died when he was fifteen. His father's considerable estate allowed the now fatherless child to enroll at the [[University of Uppsala]] in 1869 to study [[mathematics]] and [[physics]]. He received his first degree in two years, but continued in graduate studies until 1885 when he received his doctorate in mathematics. In 1887, Wicksell received a scholarship to study on the continent where he heard lectures by the economist [[Carl Menger]] in [[Vienna]]. In the following years, his interests began to shift toward the social sciences, and in particular, economics.
 
  
As a lecturer at Uppsala, Wicksell had attracted attention for his opinions about labor. At one lecture, he condemned drunkenness and prostitution as alienating, degrading, and impoverishing. Although he was sometimes identified as a [[socialist]], his solution to the above problem was decidedly [[Thomas Malthus|Malthusian]] in advocating birth control – a theory he would defend to the end of his life. Although he had attracted some attention for his fiery ideas, his first work in economics, ''Value, Capital and Rent,'' published in 1892, was largely unnoticed. In 1896, he published ''Studies in the theory of Public Finance'', applying the ideas of [[marginalism]] to [[progressive tax]]ation, [[public good]]s, and other aspects of public policy, attracting considerably more interest.
+
Wicksell died in 1926 in Stockholm, while writing a final work on the [[theory of interest]].
  
Wicksell had taken a common-law wife, [[Anna Bugge]], in 1887, although he found it difficult to support his family on his irregular positions and publications. Economics in Sweden at the time was taught as part of the law school and Wicksell was unable to gain a chair as a professor until he was awarded a law degree. He returned to the University of Uppsala where he completed a four-year law degree in two years, and subsequently became an associate professor at that university in 1899. The next year, he became a full professor at [[Lund University]], where he would endeavor in his most influential work.
+
==Work==
  
After a lecture in 1908 satirizing the [[Immaculate Conception]], Wicksell was briefly imprisoned for two months. Eight years later, in 1916, Wicksell retired from his post at Lund and took a position at Stockholm advising the government on financial and banking issues. In Stockholm, Wicksell associated himself with other future great economists of the so-called "[[Stockholm School]]," such as [[Bertil Ohlin]] and [[Gunnar Myrdal]]. He also taught a young [[Dag Hammarskjöld]], the future [[Secretary-General of the United Nations]].
+
As a lecturer at Uppsala, Wicksell had attracted attention for his opinions about [[labor]]. At one lecture, he drew correlation between worker’s [[alienation]] and [[poverty]] with social ills such as drunkenness and [[prostitution]]. Although he was sometimes identified as a [[socialism|socialist]], his solution to the above problems was decidedly [[Thomas Malthus|Malthusian]] in advocating [[birth control]] – a theory he would defend to the end of his life.  
  
Wicksell died in 1926 while writing a final work on the [[theory of interest]]. Elements of his public policy were taken strongly to heart by the Swedish government, including his vision of a limited [[welfare state]]. Wicksell's contributions to economics have been described by some economists, including [[History of economic thought|historian-of-economics]] [[Mark Blaug]], as fundamental to modern [[macroeconomics]].
+
Although he had attracted some attention for his fiery ideas, his first work in [[economics]], ''Value, Capital and Rent,'' published in 1892, was largely unnoticed. In 1896, he published ''Studies in the theory of Public Finance'', applying the ideas of [[marginalism]] to [[progressive tax]]ation, [[public good]]s, and other aspects of [[public policy]], attracting considerably more interest.
  
==Theoretical contributions==
 
 
Wicksell was enamored with the theory of [[Léon Walras]] (the [[Lausanne school]]), [[Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk]] (the [[Austrian school]]), and [[David Ricardo]], and sought a synthesis of the three theoretical visions of the economy. Wicksell's work on creating a synthetic economic theory earned him a reputation as an "economist's economist." For instance, although the [[marginal productivity theory]] - the idea that payments to [[factors of production]] equilibrate to their marginal productivity - had been laid out by others such as [[John Bates Clark]], Wicksell presented a far simpler and more robust demonstration of the principle, and much of the present conception of that theory stems from Wicksell's model.
 
Wicksell was enamored with the theory of [[Léon Walras]] (the [[Lausanne school]]), [[Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk]] (the [[Austrian school]]), and [[David Ricardo]], and sought a synthesis of the three theoretical visions of the economy. Wicksell's work on creating a synthetic economic theory earned him a reputation as an "economist's economist." For instance, although the [[marginal productivity theory]] - the idea that payments to [[factors of production]] equilibrate to their marginal productivity - had been laid out by others such as [[John Bates Clark]], Wicksell presented a far simpler and more robust demonstration of the principle, and much of the present conception of that theory stems from Wicksell's model.
  
Extending from Ricardo's investigation of income distribution, Wicksell concluded that even a totally unfettered economy was not destined to equalize wealth as a number of Wicksell's predecessors had predicted. Instead, Wicksell posited, wealth created by growth would be distributed to those who had wealth in the first place. From this, and from theories of [[marginalism]], Wicksell defended a place for government intervention to improve national welfare.
+
Extending from Ricardo's investigation of income distribution, Wicksell concluded that even a totally unfettered economy was not destined to equalize wealth, as a number of his predecessors had predicted. Instead, Wicksell claimed, wealth created by growth would be distributed to those who had wealth in the first place. From this, and from theories of [[marginalism]], Wicksell defended a place for government intervention to improve national welfare.
  
 
Wicksell's most influential contribution was his theory of interest, published in his 1898 work, ''Interest and Prices''. He made a key distinction between the natural rate of interest and the money rate of interest. The money rate of interest, to Wicksell, was merely the interest rate seen in the [[capital market]]; the ''natural'' rate of interest was the interest rate that was neutral to prices in the [[real market]], or rather, the interest rate at which [[supply and demand]] in the real market was at equilibrium - as though there were no need for capital markets. This connected to the theory of the [[Austrian School]], which theorized that an [[economic boom]] happened when the ''natural'' rate of interest was higher than the market rate.
 
Wicksell's most influential contribution was his theory of interest, published in his 1898 work, ''Interest and Prices''. He made a key distinction between the natural rate of interest and the money rate of interest. The money rate of interest, to Wicksell, was merely the interest rate seen in the [[capital market]]; the ''natural'' rate of interest was the interest rate that was neutral to prices in the [[real market]], or rather, the interest rate at which [[supply and demand]] in the real market was at equilibrium - as though there were no need for capital markets. This connected to the theory of the [[Austrian School]], which theorized that an [[economic boom]] happened when the ''natural'' rate of interest was higher than the market rate.
Line 31: Line 35:
 
This contribution, called the "[[cumulative process]]," implied that if the natural rate of interest was ''not'' equal to the market rate, demand for investment and quantity of savings would not be equal. If the market rate is beneath the natural rate, an economic expansion occurs, and prices, ''[[ceteris paribus]]'', will rise.
 
This contribution, called the "[[cumulative process]]," implied that if the natural rate of interest was ''not'' equal to the market rate, demand for investment and quantity of savings would not be equal. If the market rate is beneath the natural rate, an economic expansion occurs, and prices, ''[[ceteris paribus]]'', will rise.
  
This idea would be expanded upon by the [[Austrian school]], which used it to form a theory of the [[business cycle]] based on central bank policy - changes in the level of money in the economy would shift the market rate of exchange in some way relative to the natural rate, and thus trigger a change in economic growth. The cumulative process was the leading theory of the business cycle until [[John Maynard Keynes]]' ''[[The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money]]''. Wicksell's theory would be a strong influence in Keynes's ideas of growth and recession, and also in [[Joseph Schumpeter]]'s "[[creative destruction]]" theory of the business cycle.
+
This idea would be expanded upon by the [[Austrian school]], which used it to form a theory of the [[business cycle]] based on central bank policy - changes in the level of money in the economy would shift the market rate of exchange in some way relative to the natural rate, and thus trigger a change in economic growth. The cumulative process was the leading theory of the business cycle until [[John Maynard Keynes]]' ''The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money''. Wicksell's theory would be a strong influence in Keynes's ideas of growth and recession, and also in [[Joseph Schumpeter]]'s "[[creative destruction]]" theory of the business cycle.
  
Wicksell's main intellectual rival was the [[United States|American]] economist [[Irving Fisher]], who espoused a more succinct explanation of the [[quantity theory of money]], resting it almost exclusively on [[long run]] prices. Wicksell's theory was considerably more complicated, beginning with interest rates in a system of changes in the real economy. Although both economists concluded from their theories that at the heart of the business cycle (and economic crisis) was government monetary policy, their disagreement would not be solved in their lifetimes, and indeed, it was inherited by the policy debates between the [[Keynesians]] and [[monetarists]] beginning a half-century later.
+
==Legacy==
  
===Economists influenced by Knut Wicksell===
+
Wicksell is regarded the father figure of the Stockholm school, which took many of Wicksell’s insights and developed them into its own version of macroeconomics. This version, in a way, resembled later Keynesian economics. Among the Swedish economists who continued to expound on Wicksell were Bertil Ohlin, Gunnar Myrdal, and Dag Hammarskjöld, later secretary general of the United Nations.
* [[John Maynard Keynes]]
 
* [[Friedrich Hayek]]
 
* [[Dennis Robertson]]
 
* [[Gunnar Myrdal]]
 
* [[Ludwig von Mises]]
 
* [[Karl Gustav Cassel]]
 
* [[Erik Lindahl]]
 
* [[Eli Heckscher]]
 
* [[Bertil Ohlin]]
 
  
===Schools of thought influenced by Knut Wicksell===
+
Elements of Wicksell’s public policy were taken strongly to heart by the Swedish government, including his vision of a limited [[welfare state]]. Wicksell's contributions to economics have been described by some economists as fundamental to modern [[macroeconomics]].
*[[Keynesian]]
+
 
*[[Neo-Keynesian Economics]]
+
Wicksell's main intellectual rival was the [[United States|American]] economist [[Irving Fisher]], who espoused a more succinct explanation of the [[quantity theory of money]]. Although both economists concluded from their theories that at the heart of the business cycle (and economic crisis) was government monetary policy, their disagreement would not be solved in their lifetimes, and indeed, it was inherited by the policy debates between the [[Keynesians]] and [[monetarists]] beginning a half-century later.
*[[Neoclassical economics]]
+
 
*[[Monetarism]]
+
==Publications==
*[[Austrian School]]
+
 
*[[Stockholm School of Economics]]
+
* Wicksell, Knut. 1896. Finanztheoretische Untersuchungen debst Darstellung und Kritik
 +
des Steuersystems Schwedens. Jena: Gustav Fischer
 +
* Wicksell, Knut. 1936 (original published in 1898). Interest and Prices. Augustus M Kelley Pubs. ISBN 0678000867
 +
* Wicksell, Knut. 1967. Lectures on Political Economy. Augustus M Kelley Pubs. ISBN 0678065209
 +
* Wicksell, Knut. 1969. Selected Papers on Economic Theory. Augustus M Kelley Pubs. ISBN 0678004935
 +
* Wicksell, Knut. 1970 (original published in 1892). Value, Capital and Rent. A. M. Kelley. ISBN 0678006520
 +
* Wicksell, Knut. (original published in 1896). ''Studies in the theory of Public Finance''.
  
 
==References==
 
==References==
*[http://www.cpm.ehime-u.ac.jp/AkamacHomePage/Akamac_E-text_Links/wicksell.html Akamac entry]
+
 
*[http://www.dallasfed.org/research/ei/ei0401.html Article on Knut Wicksell from the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas]
+
* Blaug, Mark. 1992. Knut Wicksell (1851-1926). Pioneers in economics, 28. Aldershot: Elgar. ISBN 1852784911
*[http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/bios/Wicksell.html Concise encyclopedia of economics entry]
+
* Formaini, Robert L. n.d. Knut Wicksell: The Birth of Modern Monetary Policy. Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, 9(1). Retrieved on July 21, 2007, <http://www.dallasfed.org/research/ei/ei0401.html>
 +
* Garlund, Torsten W., and Nancy Adler. 1958. The life of Knut Wicksell. Acta Universitatis Stockholmiensis, new ser., 2. Stockholm: Almqvist & Wiksell.
 +
* Strøm, Steinar, and Bjorn Thalberg. 1979. The Theoretical contributions of Knut Wicksell. London: Macmillan. ISBN 0333253450
 +
* Uhr, Carl G. 1960. Economic doctrines of Knut Wicksell. Berkeley: University of California Press.
 +
* Wood, John C. 1994. Knut Wicksell: critical assessments. London: New York. ISBN 0415108861
  
 
== External links ==
 
== External links ==
* {{gutenberg author| id=Knut+Wicksell | name=Knut Wicksell}}
 
  
 +
*[http://www.dallasfed.org/research/ei/ei0401.html Knut Wicksell] - Article on Knut Wicksell from the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas
 +
*[http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/bios/Wicksell.html Knut Wicksell] - Biography in Concise Encyclopedia of Economics
 +
*[http://www.nbs.sk/BIATEC/BIA04_03/15_18.PDF Knut Wicksell] – Article by Anetta Čaplánová
 +
*[http://mason.gmu.edu/~rwagner/Knut%20Wicksell%20Cato%20Encyclopedia.pdf Knut Wicksell] – Article by Richard E. Wagner
 +
*[http://concise.britannica.com/ebc/article-9076919/Knut-Wicksell Knut Wicksell] – Biography in Encyclopedia Britannica Concise
 +
*[http://mason.gmu.edu/~rwagner/wicksell.pdf Knut Wicksell and Contemporary Political Economy] – Article by Richard E. Wagner
  
 
{{Credits|Knut_Wicksell|114297830|}}
 
{{Credits|Knut_Wicksell|114297830|}}

Revision as of 10:27, 21 July 2007

Knut Wicksell, Swedish economist

Johan Gustaf Knut Wicksell (December 20, 1851 – May 3, 1926) was a Swedish economist, often regarded as the father of Stockholm school of economics. Elements of his public policy were taken by the Swedish government, becoming part of their program of welfare state. He tried to synthesis the three theoretical schools of economy - the Lausanne school, the Austrian school, and the Ricardians. He is also renown for his pioneering work in monetary theory.

Life

Knut Wicksell was born in Stockholm, Sweden, the son of a relatively successful businessman and real estate broker. He lost both his parents at a relatively young age - his mother died when he was only six years old, and his father when he was fifteen. His father's considerable estate allowed Wicksell to enroll at the University of Uppsala in 1869 to study mathematics and physics. He received his first degree in two years, but continued in graduate studies until 1885 when he received his doctorate in mathematics. In the following years, however, his interests began to shift toward the social sciences, and in particular, economics.

In 1887, Wicksell received a scholarship from the Victor Lorén Foundation to study economics in Germany and Austria. There he attended lectures by the economist Carl Menger in Vienna, and also studied at the universities of Strassburg, Berlin and Paris. After the return to Stockholm, he continued to draw attention with his radical lectures and papers, but was unable to secure permanent employment.

Wicksell took in 1887 a common-law wife, Anna Bugge, with whom he had two sons. He soon found it difficult to support his family on his irregular positions and publications. He received his doctorate in economics from University of Uppsala in 1896, but still could not get a professorship job. Economics in Sweden at the time was taught as part of the law school and Wicksell was unable to gain a chair as a professor because of a lack of a law degree. He returned to the University of Uppsala where he completed a four-year study in two years, and subsequently became an associate professor at that university in 1899.

In 1900, Wicksell became a full professor at Lund University, where his career blossomed. He published numerous works and taught classes in tax law and economics. After a lecture in 1908 satirizing the Immaculate Conception, Wicksell was briefly imprisoned for two months, serving the sentence in 1910.

In 1916, Wicksell retired from his post at Lund and took a position at Stockholm, advising the government on financial and banking issues. In Stockholm, Wicksell continued to supervise doctoral dissertations in economics, of many future great economists of the so-called "Stockholm School," such as Bertil Ohlin and Gunnar Myrdal.

Wicksell died in 1926 in Stockholm, while writing a final work on the theory of interest.

Work

As a lecturer at Uppsala, Wicksell had attracted attention for his opinions about labor. At one lecture, he drew correlation between worker’s alienation and poverty with social ills such as drunkenness and prostitution. Although he was sometimes identified as a socialist, his solution to the above problems was decidedly Malthusian in advocating birth control – a theory he would defend to the end of his life.

Although he had attracted some attention for his fiery ideas, his first work in economics, Value, Capital and Rent, published in 1892, was largely unnoticed. In 1896, he published Studies in the theory of Public Finance, applying the ideas of marginalism to progressive taxation, public goods, and other aspects of public policy, attracting considerably more interest.

Wicksell was enamored with the theory of Léon Walras (the Lausanne school), Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk (the Austrian school), and David Ricardo, and sought a synthesis of the three theoretical visions of the economy. Wicksell's work on creating a synthetic economic theory earned him a reputation as an "economist's economist." For instance, although the marginal productivity theory - the idea that payments to factors of production equilibrate to their marginal productivity - had been laid out by others such as John Bates Clark, Wicksell presented a far simpler and more robust demonstration of the principle, and much of the present conception of that theory stems from Wicksell's model.

Extending from Ricardo's investigation of income distribution, Wicksell concluded that even a totally unfettered economy was not destined to equalize wealth, as a number of his predecessors had predicted. Instead, Wicksell claimed, wealth created by growth would be distributed to those who had wealth in the first place. From this, and from theories of marginalism, Wicksell defended a place for government intervention to improve national welfare.

Wicksell's most influential contribution was his theory of interest, published in his 1898 work, Interest and Prices. He made a key distinction between the natural rate of interest and the money rate of interest. The money rate of interest, to Wicksell, was merely the interest rate seen in the capital market; the natural rate of interest was the interest rate that was neutral to prices in the real market, or rather, the interest rate at which supply and demand in the real market was at equilibrium - as though there were no need for capital markets. This connected to the theory of the Austrian School, which theorized that an economic boom happened when the natural rate of interest was higher than the market rate.

This contribution, called the "cumulative process," implied that if the natural rate of interest was not equal to the market rate, demand for investment and quantity of savings would not be equal. If the market rate is beneath the natural rate, an economic expansion occurs, and prices, ceteris paribus, will rise.

This idea would be expanded upon by the Austrian school, which used it to form a theory of the business cycle based on central bank policy - changes in the level of money in the economy would shift the market rate of exchange in some way relative to the natural rate, and thus trigger a change in economic growth. The cumulative process was the leading theory of the business cycle until John Maynard Keynes' The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money. Wicksell's theory would be a strong influence in Keynes's ideas of growth and recession, and also in Joseph Schumpeter's "creative destruction" theory of the business cycle.

Legacy

Wicksell is regarded the father figure of the Stockholm school, which took many of Wicksell’s insights and developed them into its own version of macroeconomics. This version, in a way, resembled later Keynesian economics. Among the Swedish economists who continued to expound on Wicksell were Bertil Ohlin, Gunnar Myrdal, and Dag Hammarskjöld, later secretary general of the United Nations.

Elements of Wicksell’s public policy were taken strongly to heart by the Swedish government, including his vision of a limited welfare state. Wicksell's contributions to economics have been described by some economists as fundamental to modern macroeconomics.

Wicksell's main intellectual rival was the American economist Irving Fisher, who espoused a more succinct explanation of the quantity theory of money. Although both economists concluded from their theories that at the heart of the business cycle (and economic crisis) was government monetary policy, their disagreement would not be solved in their lifetimes, and indeed, it was inherited by the policy debates between the Keynesians and monetarists beginning a half-century later.

Publications

  • Wicksell, Knut. 1896. Finanztheoretische Untersuchungen debst Darstellung und Kritik

des Steuersystems Schwedens. Jena: Gustav Fischer

  • Wicksell, Knut. 1936 (original published in 1898). Interest and Prices. Augustus M Kelley Pubs. ISBN 0678000867
  • Wicksell, Knut. 1967. Lectures on Political Economy. Augustus M Kelley Pubs. ISBN 0678065209
  • Wicksell, Knut. 1969. Selected Papers on Economic Theory. Augustus M Kelley Pubs. ISBN 0678004935
  • Wicksell, Knut. 1970 (original published in 1892). Value, Capital and Rent. A. M. Kelley. ISBN 0678006520
  • Wicksell, Knut. (original published in 1896). Studies in the theory of Public Finance.

References
ISBN links support NWE through referral fees

  • Blaug, Mark. 1992. Knut Wicksell (1851-1926). Pioneers in economics, 28. Aldershot: Elgar. ISBN 1852784911
  • Formaini, Robert L. n.d. Knut Wicksell: The Birth of Modern Monetary Policy. Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, 9(1). Retrieved on July 21, 2007, <http://www.dallasfed.org/research/ei/ei0401.html>
  • Garlund, Torsten W., and Nancy Adler. 1958. The life of Knut Wicksell. Acta Universitatis Stockholmiensis, new ser., 2. Stockholm: Almqvist & Wiksell.
  • Strøm, Steinar, and Bjorn Thalberg. 1979. The Theoretical contributions of Knut Wicksell. London: Macmillan. ISBN 0333253450
  • Uhr, Carl G. 1960. Economic doctrines of Knut Wicksell. Berkeley: University of California Press.
  • Wood, John C. 1994. Knut Wicksell: critical assessments. London: New York. ISBN 0415108861

External links

Credits

New World Encyclopedia writers and editors rewrote and completed the Wikipedia article in accordance with New World Encyclopedia standards. This article abides by terms of the Creative Commons CC-by-sa 3.0 License (CC-by-sa), which may be used and disseminated with proper attribution. Credit is due under the terms of this license that can reference both the New World Encyclopedia contributors and the selfless volunteer contributors of the Wikimedia Foundation. To cite this article click here for a list of acceptable citing formats.The history of earlier contributions by wikipedians is accessible to researchers here:

The history of this article since it was imported to New World Encyclopedia:

Note: Some restrictions may apply to use of individual images which are separately licensed.