Difference between revisions of "Patent" - New World Encyclopedia

From New World Encyclopedia
(Claimed)
Line 1: Line 1:
 
[[Category:Politics and social sciences]]
 
[[Category:Politics and social sciences]]
 
[[Category:Law]]
 
[[Category:Law]]
{{Claimed}}
+
{{Claimed}}{{Started}}
A '''patent''' is a set of [[exclusive right]]s granted by a [[state]] to a patentee (the [[inventor]] or assignee) for a [[Term of patent|fixed period of time]] in exchange for the regulated, public disclosure of certain details of a device, method, process or composition of matter (substance) (known as an [[invention]]) which is [[novelty (patent)|new]], [[inventive step and non-obviousness|inventive]], and [[utility (patent)|useful]] or [[industrial applicability|industrially applicable]].
 
  
The exclusive right granted to a patentee in most countries is the right to '''prevent''' or '''exclude''' others from making, using, selling, offering to sell or importing the [[claim (patent)|claim]]ed invention.  The rights given to the patentee do not include the right to make, use, or sell the invention themselves. The patentee may have to comply with other laws and regulations to make use of the claimed invention. So, for example, a [[pharmacology|pharmaceutical]] company may obtain a patent on a new [[medication|drug]] but will be unable to market the drug without regulatory approval, or an inventor may patent an improvement to a particular type of [[laser]], but be unable to make or sell the new design without a license from the owner of an earlier broader patent covering lasers of that type.  
+
A '''patent''' is a set of [[exclusive right]]s granted by a [[state]] to a patentee for a [[term of patent|fixed period of time]] in exchange for a disclosure of an [[invention]].  
  
The term "patent" originates from the [[Latin]] word ''patere'' which means "to lay open" (i.e. make available for public inspection) and the term ''[[letters patent]]'', which originally denoted [[royal decree]]s granting exclusive rights to certain individuals or [[business]]es.
+
The procedure for granting patents, the requirements placed on the patentee and the extent of the exclusive rights vary widely between countries according to national laws and international agreements. Typically, however, a patent application must include one or more [[claim (patent)|claim]]s defining the invention which must be [[novelty (patent)|new]], [[inventive step and non-obviousness|inventive]], and [[utility (patent)|useful]] or [[industrial applicability|industrially applicable]]. The exclusive right granted to a patentee in most countries is the right to prevent or exclude others from making, using, selling, offering to sell or importing the invention.  
  
== Legal effect==  
+
== Definition ==
[[Image:Ejector_seat_with_patents_crooped.jpg|thumb|300px|The plate of the Martin [[ejector seat]] of the military aircraft, stating, that the design is covered by multiple patents in Britain, South Africa, Canada and "others". [[Dubendorf|Dübendorf]] Museum of Military Aviation.]]
+
The term "patent" usually refers to a right granted to anyone who invents or discovers any new and useful process, machine, article of manufacture, or composition of matter, or any new and useful improvement thereof. The additional qualification "utility patents" is used in countries such as the United States to distinguish them from other types of patents but should not be confused with [[utility model]]s granted by other countries. Examples of particular species of patents for inventions include [[biological patent]]s, [[business method patent]]s, [[chemical patent]]s and [[software patent]]s.
A patent provides the [[right]] to ''exclude others'' from making, using, selling, offering for sale, or importing the patented [[invention]] for the [[Term of patent|term]] of the patent, usually 20 years from the filing date.  A patent is, in effect, a limited property right that the government offers to inventors in exchange for their agreement to share the details of their inventions with the public.  Like any other property right, it may be sold, licensed, mortgaged, assigned or transferred, given away, or simply abandoned.
 
  
In order to obtain a patent, an applicant must provide a written description of his or her invention in [[sufficiency of disclosure|sufficient detail]] for a person skilled in the art to make and use the invention.  This written description is provided in what is known as the [[patent specification]], which often is accompanied by figures that show how the invention is made and how it operatesIn addition, at the end of the specification, the applicant must provide the patent office with one or more [[Claim (patent)|claims]] that distinctly point out what the applicant regards as his or her invention.  A claim, unlike the body of the specification, is a description designed to provide the public with notice of precisely what the patent owner has a right to exclude others from making, using, or selling.  Claims are often analogized to a deed or other instrument that, in the context of real property, sets the metes and bounds of an owner's right to exclude.  The claims define what a patent covers or does not cover.  A single patent may contain numerous claims, each of which is regarded as a distinct invention.
+
Some other types of intellectual property rights are referred to as "patents" in some jurisdictions: [[industrial design rights]] are called "design patents" in some jurisdictions (they protect the visual design of objects that are not purely utilitarian), [[plant breeders' rights]] are sometimes called "plant patents," and utility models or ''[[Gebrauchsmuster]]'' are sometimes called "petty patents." This article relates primarily to the patent for an invention, although so-called petty patents and utility models may also be granted for inventionsLand grants were sometimes called "[[letters patent]]," which was a government notice to the public of a grant of an exclusive right to ownership and possession.
  
In order for a patent to be granted, that is to take legal effect, the patent application must meet the requirements of the national law related to [[patentability]].   
+
== Law ==
 +
=== Effects ===
 +
A patent is not a right to practice or use the invention. Rather, a patent provides the [[right]] to ''exclude others'' from making, using, selling, offering for sale, or importing the patented [[invention]] for the [[Term of patent|term]] of the patent, usually 20 years from the filing date.  A patent is, in effect, a limited property right that the government offers to inventors in exchange for their agreement to share the details of their inventions with the public.  Like any other property right, it may be sold, licensed, mortgaged, assigned or transferred, given away, or simply abandoned.   
  
A patent is an exclusionary right. It gives the patent owner the right to exclude others from infringing the patent.  That does not, however, necessarily give the owner of the patent the right to exploit the patent.  For example, many inventions are improvements of prior inventions which may still be covered by someone else's patent.  If an inventor takes an existing patented [[mouse trap]] design, adds a new feature to make an improved mouse trap, and obtains a patent on the improvement, he or she can only legally build his or her improved mouse trap with permission from the patent holder of the original mouse trap, assuming the original patent is still in forceOn the other hand, the owner of the improved mouse trap can exclude the original patent owner from using the improvement.
+
The rights conveyed by a patent vary country-by-country. For example, in the United States, a patent covers research, except "purely philosophical" inquiry. A U.S. patent is infringed by any "making" of the invention, even a making that goes toward development of a new invention &mdash; which may itself become subject of a patent.  In contrast, Australian law permits others to build on top of a patented invention, by carving out exceptions from infringement for those who conduct [[research]] (e.g. for academic purposes) on the invention.<ref>{{cite web |title=What is a Patent? |work=Patents |publisher=[[IP Australia]] |year=2006 |url=http://www.ipaustralia.gov.au/patents/what_index.shtml |accessdate=2007-08-12}}</ref>  
  
Patents can generally only be enforced through [[litigation|civil lawsuit]]s (for example, for a US patent, by an action for patent infringement in a United States federal court), although some territories (such as [[France]] and [[Austria]]) have criminal penalties for wanton infringement.<ref>[[DLA Piper Rudnick Gray Cary]] (2005) ''Patent Litigation across Europe'', handout available as per [http://cecollect.com/ve/ZZf3096aBBft91T940 this link].</ref>
+
A patent is an exclusionary right.  It gives the patent owner the right to exclude others from [[Patent infringement|infringing the patent]].  That does not, however, necessarily give the owner of the patent the right to exploit the patent.  For example, many inventions are improvements of prior inventions which may still be covered by someone else's patent.  If an inventor takes an existing patented [[mouse trap]] design, adds a new feature to make an improved mouse trap, and obtains a patent on the improvement, he or she can only legally build his or her improved mouse trap with permission from the patent holder of the original mouse trap, assuming the original patent is still in force.  On the other hand, the owner of the improved mouse trap can exclude the original patent owner from using the improvement.
<ref>There are moves to criminalize patent infringement in the European Union.  {{cite press release|title=UK patent attorneys welcome clamp down on fake goods but oppose move to criminalize patent infringement|publisher=[[Chartered Institute of Patent Attorneys|CIPA]]|date=[[2006-06-22]]|url = http://www.cipa.org.uk/pages/whatsnew/article?6701D3CC-74FD-4B1C-BB73-7C6918A423B4 |accessdate=2006-07-19}}</ref> Typically, the patent owner will seek monetary compensation for past infringement, and will seek an [[injunction]] prohibiting the defendant from engaging in future acts of infringement.  In order to prove infringement, the patent owner must establish that the accused infringer practices all of the requirements of at least one of the claims of the patent (noting that in many jurisdictions the protection may not be limited to what is literally stated in the claims, for example due to the "[[doctrine of equivalents]]").
+
 
 +
Some countries have "working provisions" which require that the invention be exploited in the jurisdiction it covers. Consequences of not working an invention vary from one country to another, ranging from revocation of the patent rights to the awarding of a compulsory license awarded by the courts to a party wishing to exploit a patented invention. The patentee has the opportunity to challenge the revocation or license, but is usually required to provide evidene that the reasonable requirements of the public have been met by the working of invention.
 +
 
 +
=== Enforcement ===
 +
[[Image:Ejector seat with patents crooped.jpg|thumb|right|The plate of the Martin [[ejector seat]] of the military aircraft, stating that the design is covered by multiple patents in Britain, South Africa, Canada and "others." [[Dubendorf|Dübendorf]] Museum of Military Aviation.]]
 +
Patents can generally only be enforced through [[litigation|civil lawsuit]]s (for example, for a US patent, by an action for patent infringement in a United States federal court), although some territories (such as [[France]] and [[Austria]]) have criminal penalties for wanton infringement.<ref>[[DLA Piper Rudnick Gray Cary]] (2005) ''Patent Litigation across Europe'', handout available as per [http://cecollect.com/ve/ZZf3096aBBft91T940 this link].</ref> Typically, the patent owner will seek monetary compensation for past infringement, and will seek an [[injunction]] prohibiting the defendant from engaging in future acts of infringement.  In order to prove infringement, the patent owner must establish that the accused infringer practices all of the requirements of at least one of the claims of the patent (noting that in many jurisdictions the scope of the patent may not be limited to what is literally stated in the claims, for example due to the "[[doctrine of equivalents]]").
  
 
An important limitation on the ability of a patent owner to successfully assert his or her patent in civil litigation is the accused infringer's right to challenge the validity of that patent.  Civil courts hearing patent cases can and often do declare patents invalid.  The grounds on which a patent can be found invalid are set out in the relevant patent legislation and vary between countries.  Often, the grounds are a sub-set of the requirements for [[patentability]] in the relevant country.
 
An important limitation on the ability of a patent owner to successfully assert his or her patent in civil litigation is the accused infringer's right to challenge the validity of that patent.  Civil courts hearing patent cases can and often do declare patents invalid.  The grounds on which a patent can be found invalid are set out in the relevant patent legislation and vary between countries.  Often, the grounds are a sub-set of the requirements for [[patentability]] in the relevant country.
 +
[[Image:2000patent.PNG|thumb|left|Patents in force in 2000]]
 +
The vast majority of patent rights, however, are not determined through litigation, but are resolved privately through patent licensing.  Patent [[license|licensing agreements]] are effectively [[contract]]s in which the patent owner (the licensor) agrees not to sue the licensee for infringement of the licensor's patent rights, usually in return for a royalty or other payment.  It is not uncommon for companies engaged in complex technical fields to enter into dozens of license agreements associated with the production of a single product.  Moreover, it is equally common for competitors in such fields to license patents to each other under [[cross-licensing]] agreements in order to gain access to each other's patents.  A cross license agreement could be highly desirable to the mouse trap developers discussed above, for example, because it would permit both parties to profit off each other's inventions.
  
The vast majority of patent rights, however, are not determined through litigation, but are resolved privately through patent licensing.  Patent [[license|licensing agreements]] are effectively [[contract]]s in which the patent owner (the licensor) agrees not to sue the licensee for infringement of the licensor's patent rights, usually in return for a royalty or other payment.  It is not uncommon for companies engaged in complex technical fields to enter into dozens of license agreements associated with the production of a single product.  Moreover, it is equally common for competitors in such fields to license patents to each other under [[cross-licensing]] agreements in order to gain access to each other's patents.  A cross license agreement could be highly desirable to the mouse trap developers discussed above, for example, because it would permit both parties to profit off each other's inventions.
+
The [[United Nations Statistics Division]] reports that USA was the top market for patents in force in 2000 closely followed by the EU and Japan.
  
===Patent ownership===
+
=== Ownership ===
  
In most countries, both natural persons and corporate entities may apply for a patent.  The entity or entities then become the owners of the patent when and if it issues.
+
In most countries, both natural persons and corporate entities may apply for a patent.  The entity or entities then become the owners of the patent when and if it issues. However, it is nearly always required that the inventor or inventors be named and an indication be given on the public record as to how the owner or owners acquired their rights to the invention from the inventor or inventors.
  
In the United States, however, only the natural persons (i.e. the inventors) may apply for a patent. If a patent issues, then each person listed as an inventor owns the patent separately from the other.  For example, if two inventors are listed on a patent, then each one may grant licenses to the patent independently of the other.
+
In the United States, however, only the natural person(s) (i.e. the inventor/s) may apply for a patent. If a patent issues, then each person listed as an inventor owns the patent separately from the other.  For example, if two inventors are listed on a patent, then each one may grant licenses to the patent independently of the other, absent an agreement to the contrary.
  
It is common in the United States for inventors to [[assignment (law)|assign]] their ownership rights to a corporate entity. <ref>{{cite web | title=Assignee (Company) Name |url=http://www.uspto.gov/web/patents/patog/week39/OG/help/help.htm#Assignee%20(Company)%20Name  |work=Help Page |publisher= U.S. Copyright and Trademark Office (USPTO) | accessdate=2007-07-25 }}</ref>  Inventors that work for a corporation, for example, often are required to assign their ownership rights to their corporation as a condition of their employment. Independent inventors often assign their ownership rights to a single entity so that only one entity has the right to grant a license.   
+
It is common in the United States for inventors to [[assignment (law)|assign]] their ownership rights to a corporate entity.<ref>{{cite web | title=Assignee (Company) Name |url=http://www.uspto.gov/web/patents/patog/week39/OG/help/help.htm#Assignee%20(Company)%20Name  |work=Help Page |publisher= U.S. Copyright and Trademark Office (USPTO) | accessdate=2007-07-25 }}</ref>  Inventors that work for a corporation, for example, often are required to assign their ownership rights to their corporation as a condition of their employment. Independent inventors often assign their ownership rights to a single entity so that only one entity has the right to grant a license.   
  
The ability to assign ownership rights increases the liquidity of a patent as property.  Inventors can obtain patents and then sell them to third parties.  The third parties then own the patents as if they had originally made the inventions themselves.
+
The ability to assign ownership rights increases the [[market liquidity|liquidity]] of a patent as property.  Inventors can obtain patents and then sell them to third parties.  The third parties then own the patents as if they had originally made the inventions themselves.
  
 
=== Governing laws ===
 
=== Governing laws ===
{{Patent law}}
+
 
 
The grant and enforcement of patents are governed by national laws, and also by international treaties, where those treaties have been given effect in national laws.  Patents are, therefore, territorial in nature.
 
The grant and enforcement of patents are governed by national laws, and also by international treaties, where those treaties have been given effect in national laws.  Patents are, therefore, territorial in nature.
  
Commonly, a nation forms a Patent Office with responsibility for operating that nation's patent system, within the relevant patent laws.  The Patent Office generally has responsibility for the grant of patents, with infringement being the remit of national courts.
+
Commonly, a nation forms a [[patent office]] with responsibility for operating that nation's patent system, within the relevant patent laws.  The patent office generally has responsibility for the grant of patents, with infringement being the remit of national courts.
  
There is a trend towards global harmonization of patent laws, with the [[World Trade Organization|WTO]] being particularly active in this area.  The [[Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights|TRIPs Agreement]] has been largely successful in providing a forum for nations to agree on an aligned set of patent laws.  Conformity with the TRIPs agreement is a requirement of admission to the WTO and so compliance is seen by many nations as important.  This has also led to many developing nations, which may historically have developed different laws to aid their development, enforcing patents laws in line with global practice.
+
There is a trend towards global harmonization of patent laws, with the [[World Trade Organization]] (WTO) being particularly active in this area.  The [[Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights|TRIPs Agreement]] has been largely successful in providing a forum for nations to agree on an aligned set of patent laws.  Conformity with the TRIPs agreement is a requirement of admission to the WTO and so compliance is seen by many nations as important.  This has also led to many developing nations, which may historically have developed different laws to aid their development, enforcing patents laws in line with global practice.
  
A highly notable international convention related to patents is the [[Paris Convention for the Protection of Industrial Property]] which was initially agreed in [[1883]].  The Paris Convention sets out a range of basic rules relating to patents, and although the convention does not have direct legal effect, the principles of the convention are incorporated into all notable current patent systems.  The most significant aspect of the convention is the provision of the right to claim [[priority right|priority]]: filing an application in any one member state of the Paris Convention preserves the right for one year to file in any other member state, and receive the benefit of the original filing date.  Because the right to a patent is intensely date-driven, this right is fundamental to modern patent usage.
+
A key international convention relating to patents is the [[Paris Convention for the Protection of Industrial Property]] which was initially agreed in 1883.  The Paris Convention sets out a range of basic rules relating to patents, and although the convention does not have direct legal effect in all national jurisdictions, the principles of the convention are incorporated into all notable current patent systems.  The most significant aspect of the convention is the provision of the right to claim [[priority right|priority]]: filing an application in any one member state of the Paris Convention preserves the right for one year to file in any other member state, and receive the benefit of the original filing date.  Because the right to a patent is intensely date-driven, this right is fundamental to modern patent usage.
  
The authority for patent statutes in different countries varies. In the United States, the [[United States Constitution|Constitution]] empowers [[United States Congress|Congress]] to make laws to "promote the Progress of Science and useful Arts..." The laws Congress passed are codified in title 35 of the [[United States Code]] and created the [[United States Patent and Trademark Office|Patent and Trademark Office|]][http://www.law.cornell.edu/uscode/html/uscode35/usc_sup_01_35.html]. In the UK, substantive patent law is contained in the Patents Act 1977 as amended.<ref>United Kingdom law requiring no explicit authority due to the [[Supremacy of Parliament]].</ref>
+
The authority for patent statutes in different countries varies. In the United States, the [[United States Constitution|Constitution]] empowers [[United States Congress|Congress]] to make laws to "promote the Progress of Science and useful Arts..." The laws Congress passed are codified in title 35 of the [[United States Code]] and created the [[United States Patent and Trademark Office]].<ref> [http://www.law.cornell.edu/uscode/html/uscode35/usc_sup_01_35.html U.S. Code collection, Title 35—Patents] </ref> In the UK, substantive patent law is contained in the Patents Act 1977 as amended.<ref>United Kingdom law requiring no explicit authority due to the [[Supremacy of Parliament]].</ref>
  
In addition, there are international treaty procedures, such as the procedures under the [[European Patent Convention]] (EPC) (administered by the [[European Patent Organisation|European Patent Office]] (EPO)), and the [[Patent Cooperation Treaty]] (PCT) (administered by [[WIPO]] and covering approximately 133 countries worldwide), that centralise some portion of the filing and examination procedure. Similar arrangements exist among the member states of ARIPO, OAPI, the analogous traties among African and Asian countries.
+
In addition, there are international treaty procedures, such as the procedures under the [[European Patent Convention]] (EPC) [administered by the [[European Patent Organisation]] (EPOrg)], and the [[Patent Cooperation Treaty]] (PCT) (administered by [[WIPO]] and covering 137 countries), that centralise some portion of the filing and examination procedure. Similar arrangements exist among the member states of [[African Regional Intellectual Property Organization|ARIPO]], [[Organisation Africaine de la Propriété Intellectuelle|OAPI]], the analogous treaties among African countries.
  
As explained in more detail in [[European patent law]], the EPC covers approximately 30 European states, including all [[European Union]] states except [[Malta]].  The EPO examines and grants "European patents" which, subject to minor formal requirements, then acquire the same status and force as national patents under the national laws of such EPC contracting states as the applicant designates. <ref> {{EPC Article|2|2}} </ref> <ref> Singer/Stauder, ''The European Patent Convention, A Commentary'', Munich, 2003</ref>  The EPC remits almost all substantive issues of European Patents, post-grant, to national law.
+
=== Application and prosecution ===
  
The PCT does not provide a central, international, granting authority, but rather allows a number of the common procedural steps required to obtain a patent to be carried out for a single application.  The PCT system is therefore an efficient route to obtaining a patent in a large number of countries as many of the steps need only be performed once.  A PCT application also delays many of the highly expensive stages of [[patent prosecution|prosecuting]] a patent.
+
:''For more details on this topic, see [[Patent application]] and [[Patent prosecution]].''
  
== Economic rationale==
+
A patent is obtained by filing a written [[Patent application|application]] at the relevant patent office.  The application contains a description of how to make and use the invention and, under some legislations, if not self evident, the usefulness of the invention.  The patent application may or must also comprise "claims."  Claims define the invention and embodiments for which that the applicant wants patent rights to.
{{details|Economics and patents}}
 
  
There are four primary justifications for granting patents: disclosure, innovation, production investment, and designing around {{citation needed}}.
+
In more details, to obtain a patent, an applicant must provide a written description of his or her invention in [[sufficiency of disclosure|sufficient detail]] for a person skilled in the art (i.e., the relevant area of technology) to make and use the invention.  This written description is provided in what is known as the [[Patent application#Patent specification|patent specification]], which often is accompanied by illustrating drawings.  Some countries, such as the United States, further require that the specification disclose the "best mode" of the invention (i.e., the most effective way, to the best of the inventor's knowledge, to make or practice the invention).<ref>{{cite web | title=What are the steps in getting a patent? |url=http://www.wolfgreenfield.com/media/news/news.9.pdf |work=Questions and Answers on Patents |publisher= Wolf, Greenfield & Sacks, P.C. | accessdate=2007-06-05 }}</ref>  In addition, at the end of the specification, the applicant must provide one or more [[Claim (patent)|claims]] that define what the applicant regards as his or her invention.  A claim, unlike the body of the specification, is a description designed to provide the public with notice of precisely what the patent owner has a right to exclude others from making, using, or selling.  Claims are often analogized to a deed or other instrument that, in the context of real property, sets the metes and bounds of an owner's right to exclude.  The claims define what a patent covers.  A single patent may contain numerous claims, each of which is regarded as a distinct invention.
  
First, in accordance with the original definition of the term "patent," it is argued that patents facilitate and encourage disclosure of [[innovation]]s into the [[public domain]] for the [[common good]]. If [[inventor]]s did not have the legal protection of patents, they may prefer or tend to keep their inventions secret. Awarding patents generally makes the details of new technology publicly available, for exploitation by anyone after patent protection ends, or for further improvement by other inventors. Furthermore, when a [[term of patent|patent's term]] has expired, the public record ensures that the patentee's idea is not lost to humanity.
+
For a patent to be granted, that is to take legal effect, the patent application must meet the legal requirements related to [[patentability]].
  
Second, it is broadly believed that patents provide incentives for economically efficient [[research and development]] (R&D). Many large modern [[corporation]]s have annual R&D budgets of hundreds of millions or even billions of dollars. Without patent protection, R&D spending would be significantly less or eliminated altogether, limiting the possibility of technological advances or breakthroughs. Corporations would be much more conservative about the R&D investments they made, as third parties would be [[free rider problem|free to exploit]] any developments. This second justification is closely related to the basic idea underlying traditional [[property (ownership right)|property rights]]: why build a house if another person could freely occupy it?
+
Once a [[patent application]] has been filed, most patent offices examine that application for compliance with the [[Patentability|requirements]] of the relevant patent law. If the application does not comply with all of the requirements, the objections are usually communicated to the applicant or his or her [[patent attorney|patent agent or attorney]], who can then respond to those objections to attempt to overcome them and obtain the grant of a patent.
  
Third, in many industries (especially those with high fixed costs and either low marginal costs or low reverse engineering costs - computer processors, software, and pharmaceuticals being prototypical examples), once an invention exists, the cost of commercialization (testing, tooling up a factory, developing a market, etc.) is far more than the initial conception cost(For example, the "rule of thumb" for computer companies in the 1980's was that post-R&D costs were 7-to-1 {{citation needed}}).  Unless there is some way to prevent copies from competing at the marginal cost of production, companies will not make that productization investment.
+
In most countries, there is no requirement that the inventor build a prototype or otherwise reduce his or her invention to actual practice in order to obtain a patentThe description of the invention, however, must be sufficiently complete so that another person with ordinary skill in the art of the invention can make and use the invention without undue experimentation.
  
Fourth, many believe that patent rights create an incentive for companies to develop workarounds to patented inventions, thereby creating improved or alternative technologies that might not otherwise have been developed.
+
Once granted the patent is subject in most countries to [[maintenance fee (patent)|renewal fees]], generally due each year,<ref>the US being a notable exception; see the [[Maintenance fee (patent)]] article for more details</ref> to keep the patent in force.
  
One interesting side effect of modern day patent usage is that the small-time inventor can use the exclusive right status to become a licensor.  This allows the inventor to accumulate capital quickly from licensing the invention and may allow rapid innovation to occur because he/she may choose to not manage a manufacturing buildup for the invention.  Thus the inventor's time and energy can be spent on pure innovation, allowing others to concentrate on manufacturability.
+
== Economics ==
 
+
{{citations missing|date=June 2007}}
== Criticism ==
+
{{details|Economics and patents}}
 
 
There are arguments in opposition to patent rights. Granting a patent confers a "negative right" upon a patent owner, because he or she may legally exclude competitors from using or exploiting the invention, even if the competitor subsequently (either subsequent to the date of invention, or to the [[priority date]], depending upon the relevant patent law - see [[First to file and first to invent]]) independently develops the same invention.  Also, it is argued that monopolies create inefficiency. If the grant of a patent is the grant of a monopoly, the patent system may stifle [[competition]] and result in higher prices, lower quality, and shortages.
 
 
 
A more subtle, but theoretical, problem with patent rights was developed by law professors [[Michael Heller (law professor)|Michael Heller]] and [[Rebecca Eisenberg]] in a 1998 ''Science'' article.<ref>Heller, M.A., & Eisenberg, R.S. (1998).  Can Patents Deter Innovation?  The Anticommons in Biomedical Research.  Science, 280(1 May 1998), '''280''', 698-701.</ref> Building from Heller's theory of the [[tragedy of the anticommons]], the professors postulated that intellectual property rights may become so widely fragmented that, effectively, no one can take advantage of them as to do so would require an agreement between the owners of all of the fragments.
 
  
All patents are published and so there is a tension between including sufficient detail in the patent application to secure patent protection and the wish to protect "trade secrets."  It has been argued that the sufficiency requirements of patents are not rigorous enough and that patents are sometimes granted without any knowledge being imparted to society, this tends to be particular to software patents, wherein the source code is not revealed.<ref> [http://www.bustpatents.com www.bustpatents.com], retrieved on June 29, 2006</ref> It has also been suggested that market incentives alone would be sufficient incentive to innovate even in the absence of patents.
+
=== Rationale ===
 +
There are four primary incentives embodied in the patent system: the incentive to invent in the first place; the incentive to disclose the invention once made; the incentive to invest the sums necessary to experiment, to produce, and finally get the invention on the market; and the incentive to design around and improve upon earlier patents.<ref>Howard T. Markey (chief judge of the United States Court of Customs and Patent Appeals and later of the Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit), ''Special Problems in Patent Cases'', 66 F.R.D. 529, 1975.</ref>
  
In the last 10 years, patent offices in both the U.S. and Europe have begun granting [[software patent]]s. Programmers and others complain that these patents inhibit software innovation in a rapidly changing field where a particular technique may be obsolete in a few short years.<ref>[http://lpf.ai.mit.edu lpf.ai.mit.edu], retrieved on June 29, 2006</ref>
+
First, patents provide incentives for economically efficient [[research and development]] (R&D). Many large modern [[corporation]]s have annual R&D budgets of hundreds of millions or even billions of dollars. Without patents, R&D spending would be significantly less or eliminated altogether, limiting the possibility of technological advances or breakthroughs. Corporations would be much more conservative about the R&D investments they made, as third parties would be [[free rider problem|free to exploit]] any developments. This second justification is closely related to the basic idea underlying traditional [[property (ownership right)|property rights]]: why build a house if another person could freely occupy it?
  
Historical evidence can be found both in favour of patent systems and against them. The mid-19th century dyestuffs industry faltered in Britain where patent protection was available, and flourished in Germany despite the absence of such protections.  In contrast, patent protection has enabled inventors to protect their innovative products from larger companies and receive reward for their advances. For example, the [[Dyson (appliances)|Dyson]] bagless vacuum cleaner has led to a significant shift in the vacuum cleaner market and the inventor has benefitted from patent protection.
+
Second, in accordance with the original definition of the term "patent," patents facilitate and encourage disclosure of [[innovation]]s into the [[public domain]] for the [[common good]]. If [[inventor]]s did not have the legal protection of patents, in many cases, they would prefer or tend to keep their inventions secret. Awarding patents generally makes the details of new technology publicly available, for exploitation by anyone after the patent expires, or for further improvement by other inventors. Furthermore, when a [[term of patent|patent's term]] has expired, the public record ensures that the patentee's idea is not lost to humanity.
  
In response to perceived problems with the grant of patents, and the evolving nature of technology and industry, there is on-going debate about, and reform of, patent systems around the worldThe [[Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights|TRIPs]] agreement, developed by the [[World Trade Organization|WTO]] has led to the alignment of many patent systems with regard to certain controversial issues, such as what can be protected by patents and the issue of [[Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights#Access to essential medicines|compulsory licences]] in cases of national needThere is also an active community who oppose patents and who lobby for the abolishment of patent systems.
+
Third, in many industries (especially those with high fixed costs and either low marginal costs or low reverse engineering costs &mdash; computer processors, software, and pharmaceuticals being prototypical examples), once an invention exists, the cost of commercialization (testing, tooling up a factory, developing a market, etc.) is far more than the initial conception cost(For example, the internal "rule of thumb" at several computer companies in the 1980s was that post-R&D costs were 7-to-1)Unless there is some way to prevent copies from competing at the marginal cost of production, companies will not make that productization investment.
  
== History of patents ==
+
Fourth, patent rights create an incentive for companies to develop workarounds to patented inventions, thereby creating improved or alternative technologies that might not otherwise have been developed.
{{details|History of patent law}}
 
[[Image:USpatents18002004.JPG|thumb|right|U.S. Patents granted, 1800&ndash;2004.[http://www.uspto.gov/web/offices/ac/ido/oeip/taf/h_counts.htm]]]
 
  
Although there is evidence suggesting that something like patents was used among some ancient Greek cities, patents in the modern sense originated in Italy in [[1474]].  At that time the [[Republic of Venice]] issued a decree by which new and inventive devices, once they had been put into practice, had to be communicated to the Republic in order to obtain legal protection against potential infringers. England followed with the [[Statute of Monopolies 1623|Statute of Monopolies]] in [[1623]] under King [[James I of England|James I]], which declared that patents could only be granted for "projects of new innvention." During the reign of [[Queen Anne]] (1702-1714), the lawyers of the English Court developed the requirement that a written description of the invention must be submitted.<ref> [http://www.patent.gov.uk/about-history-copy.htm http://www.patent.gov.uk/about-history-copy.htm], retrieved on December 7, 2006</ref> These developments, which were in place during the Colonial period, formed the basis for modern English and United States patent law.
+
One interesting side effect of modern day patent usage is that the small-time inventor can use the exclusive right status to become a licensorThis allows the inventor to accumulate capital quickly from licensing the invention and may allow rapid innovation to occur because he or she may choose to not manage a manufacturing buildup for the invention.  Thus the inventor's time and energy can be spent on pure innovation, allowing others to concentrate on manufacturability.
  
In the United States, during the colonial period and [[Articles of Confederation]] years (1778-1789), several states adopted patent systems of their own.  The first Congress adopted a [[US Patent Act (1790)|Patent Act]], in 1790, and the first patent was issued under this Act on [http://patft.uspto.gov/netacgi/nph-Parser?Sect1=PTO2&Sect2=HITOFF&u=%2Fnetahtml%2FPTO%2Fsearch-adv.htm&r=1&p=1&f=G&l=50&d=PALL&S1=1790$.PD.&OS=ISD/$/$/1790&RS=ISD/1790$$ July 31, 1790] (and the subject matter of that patent was for the making of [[potash]]) .
+
=== Criticism over patents ===
 +
While each of the four incentives is achieved by the patent system in some contexts, the patent system has countervailing costs, and those costs fall more heavily in some contexts than others.  There are many critics and criticisms of patents and this has resulted in the formation of a large number of groups who oppose patents in general, or specific types of patents, and who lobby for their abolishment.
  
== Obtaining a patent ==
+
Patents have always been criticized for being granted on already known inventions.  In 1938, for example, [[Buckminster Fuller| R. Buckminster Fuller]], inventor of the [[geodesic dome]] wrote:<ref>[[Nine Chains to the Moon]], Chapter 36, “Throwing in the Patent Sponge,” p 277</ref>
  
:''For more details on this topic, see [[Patent application]] and [[Patent prosecution]].''
+
:''“At present (1938), the (US patent) files, are so extraordinarily complex and the items so multitudinous that a veritable army of governmental servants is required to attend them and sort them into some order of distinguishable categories to which reference may be made when corresponding with patent applicants for the purposes of examiner citation of “prior art” disclosure.  This complexity makes it inevitable that the human-equation involved in government servants relative to carelessness or mechanical limitations should occasion the granting of multitudes of “probably” invalid patent claims.''
  
A patent is obtained by filing a written [[Patent application|application]] at the relevant patent office.  That application will contain a specification detailing the invention and the protection claimed, together with forms relating to the procedural aspects of obtaining a patent.  In most countries, including the United States, there is no requirement that the inventor actually build a prototype or otherwise reduce his or her invention to practice in order to obtain a patent.
+
Patents have also been criticized for conferring a "negative right" upon a patent owner, permitting them to exclude competitors from using or exploiting the invention, even if the competitor subsequently develops the same invention independently. This may be subsequent to the date of invention, or to the [[priority right|priority date]], depending upon the relevant patent law (see [[First to file and first to invent]]). {{cn}}
  
Once a [[patent application]] has been filed, a patent office examines that application for compliance with the [[Patentability|requirements]] of the relevant patent law.  If the application does not comply with all of the requirements, the objections are communicated to the Applicant (or his representative), who can then respond to those objections to attempt to overcome them to obtain the grant of a patent.
+
Patents may act to hinder innovation as well. A holding company, perjoratively known as a "[[patent troll]]," owns a portfolio of patents, and sues others for infringement of these patents while doing little to develop the technology itself. {{cn}}
  
Once granted the patent is subject in most countries to [[maintenance fee (patent)|renewal fees]], generally due each year,<ref>the US being a notable exception; see the [[Maintenance fee (patent)]] article for more details</ref> to keep the patent in force.
+
Another theoretical problem with patent rights was proposed by law professors [[Michael Heller (law professor)|Michael Heller]] and Rebecca Sue Eisenberg in a 1998 ''Science'' article.<ref>Heller, M.A., & Eisenberg, R.S. (1998).  Can Patents Deter Innovation?  The Anticommons in Biomedical Research.  Science, 280(1 May 1998), '''280''', 698-701.</ref> Building from Heller's theory of the [[tragedy of the anticommons]], the professors postulated that intellectual property rights may become so widely fragmented that, effectively, no one can take advantage of them as to do so would require an agreement between the owners of all of the fragments.  
  
== References ==
+
Since at least the early 1980s, patent offices around the world have accepted that computer programs can lie within the realm of [[patentable subject matter]], although the regulations for when a computer program is a patentable invention differ markedly between countries. It is argued that the resulting [[software patent]]s inhibit innovation in contrast to the underlying purpose of patents.
<!--This article uses the Cite.php citation mechanism. If you would like more information on how to add references to this article, please see http://meta.wikimedia.org/wiki/Cite/Cite.php —>
 
<div class="references-small">
 
<references/>
 
</div>
 
  
==See also==
+
In response to perceived problems with the grant of patents, and the evolving nature of technology and industry, there is on-going debate about, and reform of, patent systems around the world.  The [[Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights|TRIPs]] agreement, developed by the [[World Trade Organization|WTO]] has led to the alignment of many patent systems with regard to certain controversial issues, such as what can be protected by patents and the issue of [[Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights#Access to essential medicines|compulsory licences]] in cases of national need.
  
{{wikiquote}}
+
== Etymology ==
 +
The term "patent" originates from the [[Latin]] word ''patere'' which means "to lay open" (i.e., make available for public inspection) and the term ''[[letters patent]]'', which originally denoted [[royal decree]]s granting exclusive rights to certain individuals or [[business]]es.
  
See [[List of patent legal concepts]] for articles on various legal aspects of patents, including special types of patents and patent applications.
+
== History ==
 +
{{details|History of patent law}}
 +
[[Image:USpatents18002004.JPG|thumb|right|U.S. Patents granted, 1800&ndash;2004.<ref>[http://www.uspto.gov/web/offices/ac/ido/oeip/taf/h_counts.htm U.S. Patent Activity 1790 to the Present]</ref>]]
  
=== Organizations and patent offices ===
+
There is evidence suggesting that something like patents was used among some ancient Greek cities. The creator of a new recipe was granted an exclusive right to make the food for one year, and a similar practice existed in some Roman cities.{{Fact|date=April 2007}} Patents in the modern sense originated in Italy in 1474.<ref>{{de icon}} Helmut Schippel: Die Anfänge des Erfinderschutzes in Venedig, in: Uta Lindgren (Hrsg.): Europäische Technik im Mittelalter. 800 bis 1400. Tradition und Innovation, 4. Aufl., Berlin 2001, S.539-550 ISBN 3-7861-1748-9</ref> At that time the [[Republic of Venice]] issued a decree by which new and inventive devices, once they had been put into practice, had to be communicated to the Republic in order to obtain the right to prevent others from using them.<ref>{{cite web | url=http://www.wolfgang-pfaller.de/venedig.htm | title=Wolfgang-Pfaller.de: Patentgesetz von Venedig |language=German / Italian}}</ref>
  
:''For more details on this topic, see [[Intellectual property organization]]''
+
England followed with the [[Statute of Monopolies 1623|Statute of Monopolies]] in 1623 under King [[James I of England|James I]], which declared that patents could only be granted for "projects of new invention."  During the reign of [[Queen Anne]] (1702&ndash;1714), the lawyers of the English Court developed the requirement that a written description of the invention must be submitted.<ref>{{cite web |title=History of Copyright |publisher=[[UK Intellectual Property Office]] |year=2006 |url=http://www.patent.gov.uk/about-history-copy.htm |accessdate=2007-08-12}}</ref>  These developments, which were in place during the Colonial period, formed the basis for modern English and United States patent law.
:''For a list of patent offices, see [[Patent office]]''
 
  
=== Treaties, conventions and other legal texts and frameworks ===
+
In the United States, during the colonial period and [[Articles of Confederation]] years (1778&ndash;1789), several states adopted patent systems of their own.  The first Congress adopted a [[US Patent Act (1790)|Patent Act]], in 1790, and the first patent was issued under this Act on [http://patft.uspto.gov/netacgi/nph-Parser?Sect1=PTO2&Sect2=HITOFF&u=%2Fnetahtml%2FPTO%2Fsearch-adv.htm&r=1&p=1&f=G&l=50&d=PALL&S1=1790$.PD.&OS=ISD/$/$/1790&RS=ISD/1790$ July 31, 1790] (and the subject matter of that patent was for the making of [[potash]]).
  
*[[Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights]] (TRIPs Agreement)
 
*[[American Inventors Protection Act]] (AIPA)
 
*[[Budapest Treaty]]
 
*[[Community Patent]] (''proposed'')
 
*''[[Directive on the patentability of computer-implemented inventions|EU Directive on the Patentability of Computer-Implemented Inventions]]'' (''proposed, then rejected'')
 
*[[Directive on the patentability of biotechnological inventions|EU Directive on the Patentability of Biotechnological Inventions]]
 
*[[European Patent Convention]] (EPC)
 
*[[European patent law]]
 
*[[European Patent Litigation Agreement]] (EPLA) (''proposed'')
 
*[[Japanese patent law]]
 
*[[London Agreement (2000)|London Agreement]] (''concluded but not in force yet'')
 
*[[Paris Convention for the Protection of Industrial Property]]
 
*[[Patent Reform Act of 2005|U.S. Patent Reform Act of 2005]]
 
*[[Patent Cooperation Treaty]] (PCT)
 
*[[Patent Law Treaty]] (PLT)
 
*[[Substantive Patent Law Treaty]] (SPLT) (''proposed'')
 
*[[Statute of Monopolies 1623]]
 
*[[Convention on the Unification of Certain Points of Substantive Law on Patents for Invention|Strasbourg Convention]]
 
*[[United States patent law]]
 
  
=== Other ===
 
  
*[[Chartered Institute of Patent Attorneys]] (CIPA)
+
==References==
*''[[epoline]]''
 
*''[[esp@cenet]]''
 
*[[Glossary of legal terms in technology]]
 
*[[Industrial design rights]]
 
*[[Industrial property]]
 
*[[INPADOC]]
 
*[[Intellectual property]]
 
*[[International Patent Classification]] (IPC)
 
*[[List of patent case law]]
 
*[[List of people associated with patent law]]
 
*[[List of top United States patent recipients]]
 
*[[Patent attorney]]
 
*[[Patent clerk]]
 
*[[Patent troll]]
 
*[[Patent pirate]]
 
*[[Patent portfolio]]
 
*[[United States Patents Quarterly]]
 
*[[X-Patent]]
 
*[[Patent attorney#Notable blogs|Patent Blogs]]
 
  
== External links ==
+
{{reflist}}
{{External links|November 2006}}
 
For a list of
 
* '''patent offices''' and their websites, see [[patent office]] or [http://www.wipo.int/directory/en/urls.jsp this list] maintained by WIPO
 
* '''patent organizations''', see [[intellectual property organization]]
 
* web sites providing '''search and download facilities''' relating to patents and prior art, see [[prior art]].
 
  
=== Various other resources ===
+
==External links==
* [http://www.patentinformationsearch.com/ Classifed us useful patents]
 
* [http://www.ipwatchdog.com/patent.html Introduction to US Patent Law] by Eugene R. Quinn, Jr. (Patent Attorney & Law Professor)
 
* [http://patentlawpractice.wikispaces.com/ PatentLawPractice IP and Patent Resources] - A wiki containing "A Comprehensive, Dynamically Updated List of Intellectual Property Resources"
 
* [http://groups.yahoo.com/group/PatentLawPractice/ PatentLawPractice] - Email discussion group for patent practitioners
 
* [http://www.longlivedata.com/patentwiki/ PatentWiki patent busting] - Controversial patent forum
 
* [http://www.patentfizz.com PatentFizz] - Bringing the Community to the Patent World - Attach a comment to an issued United States Patent for the whole world to see
 
* [http://www.bl.uk/services/reading/bipcentre.html The British Library - Business and Intellectual Property Centre] Holds over 50 million patents from over 40 countries
 
* [http://www.surfip.gov.sg SurfIP] Free and unified patents, trademarks and design searches, over 20 different countries
 
* [http://www.ipnewsflash.com IP Newsflash] - patent caselaw and news regarding patents
 
* [http://www.uspto.gov/patft/index.html USPTO] - Search US patents
 
* [http://wikipatents.com/ WikiPatents.com] - Community patent review. Search and comment on US patents
 
* [http://www.ipmenu.com IPMenu] - IP information directory with search capabilities
 
* [http://www.intellectualplanet.com/en/ Intellectual Planet] - Collection of latest news, wiki and forum on Intellectual properties
 
* [http://www.patentmaps.com Patentmaps.com - Patent Mapping Reports] - Collection of over 1000+ patent mapping reports
 
* [http://www.fedcirc.us FedCirc.us] - Thorough and timely reviews and analysis of patent decisions from the Federal Circuit and Supreme Court
 
* [http://www.tms.org/pubs/journals/JOM/matters/matters-9609.html JOM Patent Glossary]
 
* [http://www.patentmyideaonline.com Patent My Idea Online.com] Articles and resources for new inventors
 
* [http://historico.oepm.es?idioma=en Virtual Museum of Patents and Trademarks] Provided by the Spanish Patent and Trademark Office
 
  
=== Humorous and historical patent resources ===
+
*[http://www.wipo.int/directory/en/urls.jsp List of Patent Offices] maintained by WIPO
  
* [http://www.patent.freeserve.co.uk/ ''Patently Absurd'' British Patents]
 
* [http://www.library.umaine.edu/patents/historical.htm Information on Historical Patents]
 
* [http://www.patentlysilly.com Patently Silly]
 
* [http://ipfunny.blogs.com IP Funny Blog]
 
* [[Patent Bending]] TV series
 
  
[[bar:Patentrecht]]
 
  
  
{{Credit1|Patent|93633617|}}
+
{{Credits|Patent|157431415|}}

Revision as of 20:16, 12 September 2007


A patent is a set of exclusive rights granted by a state to a patentee for a fixed period of time in exchange for a disclosure of an invention.

The procedure for granting patents, the requirements placed on the patentee and the extent of the exclusive rights vary widely between countries according to national laws and international agreements. Typically, however, a patent application must include one or more claims defining the invention which must be new, inventive, and useful or industrially applicable. The exclusive right granted to a patentee in most countries is the right to prevent or exclude others from making, using, selling, offering to sell or importing the invention.

Definition

The term "patent" usually refers to a right granted to anyone who invents or discovers any new and useful process, machine, article of manufacture, or composition of matter, or any new and useful improvement thereof. The additional qualification "utility patents" is used in countries such as the United States to distinguish them from other types of patents but should not be confused with utility models granted by other countries. Examples of particular species of patents for inventions include biological patents, business method patents, chemical patents and software patents.

Some other types of intellectual property rights are referred to as "patents" in some jurisdictions: industrial design rights are called "design patents" in some jurisdictions (they protect the visual design of objects that are not purely utilitarian), plant breeders' rights are sometimes called "plant patents," and utility models or Gebrauchsmuster are sometimes called "petty patents." This article relates primarily to the patent for an invention, although so-called petty patents and utility models may also be granted for inventions. Land grants were sometimes called "letters patent," which was a government notice to the public of a grant of an exclusive right to ownership and possession.

Law

Effects

A patent is not a right to practice or use the invention. Rather, a patent provides the right to exclude others from making, using, selling, offering for sale, or importing the patented invention for the term of the patent, usually 20 years from the filing date. A patent is, in effect, a limited property right that the government offers to inventors in exchange for their agreement to share the details of their inventions with the public. Like any other property right, it may be sold, licensed, mortgaged, assigned or transferred, given away, or simply abandoned.

The rights conveyed by a patent vary country-by-country. For example, in the United States, a patent covers research, except "purely philosophical" inquiry. A U.S. patent is infringed by any "making" of the invention, even a making that goes toward development of a new invention — which may itself become subject of a patent. In contrast, Australian law permits others to build on top of a patented invention, by carving out exceptions from infringement for those who conduct research (e.g. for academic purposes) on the invention.[1]

A patent is an exclusionary right. It gives the patent owner the right to exclude others from infringing the patent. That does not, however, necessarily give the owner of the patent the right to exploit the patent. For example, many inventions are improvements of prior inventions which may still be covered by someone else's patent. If an inventor takes an existing patented mouse trap design, adds a new feature to make an improved mouse trap, and obtains a patent on the improvement, he or she can only legally build his or her improved mouse trap with permission from the patent holder of the original mouse trap, assuming the original patent is still in force. On the other hand, the owner of the improved mouse trap can exclude the original patent owner from using the improvement.

Some countries have "working provisions" which require that the invention be exploited in the jurisdiction it covers. Consequences of not working an invention vary from one country to another, ranging from revocation of the patent rights to the awarding of a compulsory license awarded by the courts to a party wishing to exploit a patented invention. The patentee has the opportunity to challenge the revocation or license, but is usually required to provide evidene that the reasonable requirements of the public have been met by the working of invention.

Enforcement

The plate of the Martin ejector seat of the military aircraft, stating that the design is covered by multiple patents in Britain, South Africa, Canada and "others." Dübendorf Museum of Military Aviation.

Patents can generally only be enforced through civil lawsuits (for example, for a US patent, by an action for patent infringement in a United States federal court), although some territories (such as France and Austria) have criminal penalties for wanton infringement.[2] Typically, the patent owner will seek monetary compensation for past infringement, and will seek an injunction prohibiting the defendant from engaging in future acts of infringement. In order to prove infringement, the patent owner must establish that the accused infringer practices all of the requirements of at least one of the claims of the patent (noting that in many jurisdictions the scope of the patent may not be limited to what is literally stated in the claims, for example due to the "doctrine of equivalents").

An important limitation on the ability of a patent owner to successfully assert his or her patent in civil litigation is the accused infringer's right to challenge the validity of that patent. Civil courts hearing patent cases can and often do declare patents invalid. The grounds on which a patent can be found invalid are set out in the relevant patent legislation and vary between countries. Often, the grounds are a sub-set of the requirements for patentability in the relevant country.

Patents in force in 2000

The vast majority of patent rights, however, are not determined through litigation, but are resolved privately through patent licensing. Patent licensing agreements are effectively contracts in which the patent owner (the licensor) agrees not to sue the licensee for infringement of the licensor's patent rights, usually in return for a royalty or other payment. It is not uncommon for companies engaged in complex technical fields to enter into dozens of license agreements associated with the production of a single product. Moreover, it is equally common for competitors in such fields to license patents to each other under cross-licensing agreements in order to gain access to each other's patents. A cross license agreement could be highly desirable to the mouse trap developers discussed above, for example, because it would permit both parties to profit off each other's inventions.

The United Nations Statistics Division reports that USA was the top market for patents in force in 2000 closely followed by the EU and Japan.

Ownership

In most countries, both natural persons and corporate entities may apply for a patent. The entity or entities then become the owners of the patent when and if it issues. However, it is nearly always required that the inventor or inventors be named and an indication be given on the public record as to how the owner or owners acquired their rights to the invention from the inventor or inventors.

In the United States, however, only the natural person(s) (i.e. the inventor/s) may apply for a patent. If a patent issues, then each person listed as an inventor owns the patent separately from the other. For example, if two inventors are listed on a patent, then each one may grant licenses to the patent independently of the other, absent an agreement to the contrary.

It is common in the United States for inventors to assign their ownership rights to a corporate entity.[3] Inventors that work for a corporation, for example, often are required to assign their ownership rights to their corporation as a condition of their employment. Independent inventors often assign their ownership rights to a single entity so that only one entity has the right to grant a license.

The ability to assign ownership rights increases the liquidity of a patent as property. Inventors can obtain patents and then sell them to third parties. The third parties then own the patents as if they had originally made the inventions themselves.

Governing laws

The grant and enforcement of patents are governed by national laws, and also by international treaties, where those treaties have been given effect in national laws. Patents are, therefore, territorial in nature.

Commonly, a nation forms a patent office with responsibility for operating that nation's patent system, within the relevant patent laws. The patent office generally has responsibility for the grant of patents, with infringement being the remit of national courts.

There is a trend towards global harmonization of patent laws, with the World Trade Organization (WTO) being particularly active in this area. The TRIPs Agreement has been largely successful in providing a forum for nations to agree on an aligned set of patent laws. Conformity with the TRIPs agreement is a requirement of admission to the WTO and so compliance is seen by many nations as important. This has also led to many developing nations, which may historically have developed different laws to aid their development, enforcing patents laws in line with global practice.

A key international convention relating to patents is the Paris Convention for the Protection of Industrial Property which was initially agreed in 1883. The Paris Convention sets out a range of basic rules relating to patents, and although the convention does not have direct legal effect in all national jurisdictions, the principles of the convention are incorporated into all notable current patent systems. The most significant aspect of the convention is the provision of the right to claim priority: filing an application in any one member state of the Paris Convention preserves the right for one year to file in any other member state, and receive the benefit of the original filing date. Because the right to a patent is intensely date-driven, this right is fundamental to modern patent usage.

The authority for patent statutes in different countries varies. In the United States, the Constitution empowers Congress to make laws to "promote the Progress of Science and useful Arts..." The laws Congress passed are codified in title 35 of the United States Code and created the United States Patent and Trademark Office.[4] In the UK, substantive patent law is contained in the Patents Act 1977 as amended.[5]

In addition, there are international treaty procedures, such as the procedures under the European Patent Convention (EPC) [administered by the European Patent Organisation (EPOrg)], and the Patent Cooperation Treaty (PCT) (administered by WIPO and covering 137 countries), that centralise some portion of the filing and examination procedure. Similar arrangements exist among the member states of ARIPO, OAPI, the analogous treaties among African countries.

Application and prosecution

For more details on this topic, see Patent application and Patent prosecution.

A patent is obtained by filing a written application at the relevant patent office. The application contains a description of how to make and use the invention and, under some legislations, if not self evident, the usefulness of the invention. The patent application may or must also comprise "claims." Claims define the invention and embodiments for which that the applicant wants patent rights to.

In more details, to obtain a patent, an applicant must provide a written description of his or her invention in sufficient detail for a person skilled in the art (i.e., the relevant area of technology) to make and use the invention. This written description is provided in what is known as the patent specification, which often is accompanied by illustrating drawings. Some countries, such as the United States, further require that the specification disclose the "best mode" of the invention (i.e., the most effective way, to the best of the inventor's knowledge, to make or practice the invention).[6] In addition, at the end of the specification, the applicant must provide one or more claims that define what the applicant regards as his or her invention. A claim, unlike the body of the specification, is a description designed to provide the public with notice of precisely what the patent owner has a right to exclude others from making, using, or selling. Claims are often analogized to a deed or other instrument that, in the context of real property, sets the metes and bounds of an owner's right to exclude. The claims define what a patent covers. A single patent may contain numerous claims, each of which is regarded as a distinct invention.

For a patent to be granted, that is to take legal effect, the patent application must meet the legal requirements related to patentability.

Once a patent application has been filed, most patent offices examine that application for compliance with the requirements of the relevant patent law. If the application does not comply with all of the requirements, the objections are usually communicated to the applicant or his or her patent agent or attorney, who can then respond to those objections to attempt to overcome them and obtain the grant of a patent.

In most countries, there is no requirement that the inventor build a prototype or otherwise reduce his or her invention to actual practice in order to obtain a patent. The description of the invention, however, must be sufficiently complete so that another person with ordinary skill in the art of the invention can make and use the invention without undue experimentation.

Once granted the patent is subject in most countries to renewal fees, generally due each year,[7] to keep the patent in force.

Economics


Rationale

There are four primary incentives embodied in the patent system: the incentive to invent in the first place; the incentive to disclose the invention once made; the incentive to invest the sums necessary to experiment, to produce, and finally get the invention on the market; and the incentive to design around and improve upon earlier patents.[8]

First, patents provide incentives for economically efficient research and development (R&D). Many large modern corporations have annual R&D budgets of hundreds of millions or even billions of dollars. Without patents, R&D spending would be significantly less or eliminated altogether, limiting the possibility of technological advances or breakthroughs. Corporations would be much more conservative about the R&D investments they made, as third parties would be free to exploit any developments. This second justification is closely related to the basic idea underlying traditional property rights: why build a house if another person could freely occupy it?

Second, in accordance with the original definition of the term "patent," patents facilitate and encourage disclosure of innovations into the public domain for the common good. If inventors did not have the legal protection of patents, in many cases, they would prefer or tend to keep their inventions secret. Awarding patents generally makes the details of new technology publicly available, for exploitation by anyone after the patent expires, or for further improvement by other inventors. Furthermore, when a patent's term has expired, the public record ensures that the patentee's idea is not lost to humanity.

Third, in many industries (especially those with high fixed costs and either low marginal costs or low reverse engineering costs — computer processors, software, and pharmaceuticals being prototypical examples), once an invention exists, the cost of commercialization (testing, tooling up a factory, developing a market, etc.) is far more than the initial conception cost. (For example, the internal "rule of thumb" at several computer companies in the 1980s was that post-R&D costs were 7-to-1). Unless there is some way to prevent copies from competing at the marginal cost of production, companies will not make that productization investment.

Fourth, patent rights create an incentive for companies to develop workarounds to patented inventions, thereby creating improved or alternative technologies that might not otherwise have been developed.

One interesting side effect of modern day patent usage is that the small-time inventor can use the exclusive right status to become a licensor. This allows the inventor to accumulate capital quickly from licensing the invention and may allow rapid innovation to occur because he or she may choose to not manage a manufacturing buildup for the invention. Thus the inventor's time and energy can be spent on pure innovation, allowing others to concentrate on manufacturability.

Criticism over patents

While each of the four incentives is achieved by the patent system in some contexts, the patent system has countervailing costs, and those costs fall more heavily in some contexts than others. There are many critics and criticisms of patents and this has resulted in the formation of a large number of groups who oppose patents in general, or specific types of patents, and who lobby for their abolishment.

Patents have always been criticized for being granted on already known inventions. In 1938, for example, R. Buckminster Fuller, inventor of the geodesic dome wrote:[9]

“At present (1938), the (US patent) files, are so extraordinarily complex and the items so multitudinous that a veritable army of governmental servants is required to attend them and sort them into some order of distinguishable categories to which reference may be made when corresponding with patent applicants for the purposes of examiner citation of “prior art” disclosure. This complexity makes it inevitable that the human-equation involved in government servants relative to carelessness or mechanical limitations should occasion the granting of multitudes of “probably” invalid patent claims.”

Patents have also been criticized for conferring a "negative right" upon a patent owner, permitting them to exclude competitors from using or exploiting the invention, even if the competitor subsequently develops the same invention independently. This may be subsequent to the date of invention, or to the priority date, depending upon the relevant patent law (see First to file and first to invent). [citation needed]

Patents may act to hinder innovation as well. A holding company, perjoratively known as a "patent troll," owns a portfolio of patents, and sues others for infringement of these patents while doing little to develop the technology itself. [citation needed]

Another theoretical problem with patent rights was proposed by law professors Michael Heller and Rebecca Sue Eisenberg in a 1998 Science article.[10] Building from Heller's theory of the tragedy of the anticommons, the professors postulated that intellectual property rights may become so widely fragmented that, effectively, no one can take advantage of them as to do so would require an agreement between the owners of all of the fragments.

Since at least the early 1980s, patent offices around the world have accepted that computer programs can lie within the realm of patentable subject matter, although the regulations for when a computer program is a patentable invention differ markedly between countries. It is argued that the resulting software patents inhibit innovation in contrast to the underlying purpose of patents.

In response to perceived problems with the grant of patents, and the evolving nature of technology and industry, there is on-going debate about, and reform of, patent systems around the world. The TRIPs agreement, developed by the WTO has led to the alignment of many patent systems with regard to certain controversial issues, such as what can be protected by patents and the issue of compulsory licences in cases of national need.

Etymology

The term "patent" originates from the Latin word patere which means "to lay open" (i.e., make available for public inspection) and the term letters patent, which originally denoted royal decrees granting exclusive rights to certain individuals or businesses.

History

File:USpatents18002004.JPG
U.S. Patents granted, 1800–2004.[11]

There is evidence suggesting that something like patents was used among some ancient Greek cities. The creator of a new recipe was granted an exclusive right to make the food for one year, and a similar practice existed in some Roman cities.[citation needed] Patents in the modern sense originated in Italy in 1474.[12] At that time the Republic of Venice issued a decree by which new and inventive devices, once they had been put into practice, had to be communicated to the Republic in order to obtain the right to prevent others from using them.[13]

England followed with the Statute of Monopolies in 1623 under King James I, which declared that patents could only be granted for "projects of new invention." During the reign of Queen Anne (1702–1714), the lawyers of the English Court developed the requirement that a written description of the invention must be submitted.[14] These developments, which were in place during the Colonial period, formed the basis for modern English and United States patent law.

In the United States, during the colonial period and Articles of Confederation years (1778–1789), several states adopted patent systems of their own. The first Congress adopted a Patent Act, in 1790, and the first patent was issued under this Act on July 31, 1790 (and the subject matter of that patent was for the making of potash).


References
ISBN links support NWE through referral fees

  1. What is a Patent?. Patents. IP Australia (2006). Retrieved 2007-08-12.
  2. DLA Piper Rudnick Gray Cary (2005) Patent Litigation across Europe, handout available as per this link.
  3. Assignee (Company) Name. Help Page. U.S. Copyright and Trademark Office (USPTO). Retrieved 2007-07-25.
  4. U.S. Code collection, Title 35—Patents
  5. United Kingdom law requiring no explicit authority due to the Supremacy of Parliament.
  6. What are the steps in getting a patent?. Questions and Answers on Patents. Wolf, Greenfield & Sacks, P.C.. Retrieved 2007-06-05.
  7. the US being a notable exception; see the Maintenance fee (patent) article for more details
  8. Howard T. Markey (chief judge of the United States Court of Customs and Patent Appeals and later of the Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit), Special Problems in Patent Cases, 66 F.R.D. 529, 1975.
  9. Nine Chains to the Moon, Chapter 36, “Throwing in the Patent Sponge,” p 277
  10. Heller, M.A., & Eisenberg, R.S. (1998). Can Patents Deter Innovation? The Anticommons in Biomedical Research. Science, 280(1 May 1998), 280, 698-701.
  11. U.S. Patent Activity 1790 to the Present
  12. (German) Helmut Schippel: Die Anfänge des Erfinderschutzes in Venedig, in: Uta Lindgren (Hrsg.): Europäische Technik im Mittelalter. 800 bis 1400. Tradition und Innovation, 4. Aufl., Berlin 2001, S.539-550 ISBN 3-7861-1748-9
  13. Wolfgang-Pfaller.de: Patentgesetz von Venedig (in German / Italian).
  14. History of Copyright. UK Intellectual Property Office (2006). Retrieved 2007-08-12.

External links


Credits

New World Encyclopedia writers and editors rewrote and completed the Wikipedia article in accordance with New World Encyclopedia standards. This article abides by terms of the Creative Commons CC-by-sa 3.0 License (CC-by-sa), which may be used and disseminated with proper attribution. Credit is due under the terms of this license that can reference both the New World Encyclopedia contributors and the selfless volunteer contributors of the Wikimedia Foundation. To cite this article click here for a list of acceptable citing formats.The history of earlier contributions by wikipedians is accessible to researchers here:

The history of this article since it was imported to New World Encyclopedia:

Note: Some restrictions may apply to use of individual images which are separately licensed.