Jones, Richard (economist)

From New World Encyclopedia
 
(12 intermediate revisions by 6 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{Claimed}}{{Started}}{{Contracted}}
+
{{Copyedited}}{{Images OK}}{{Submitted}}{{Approved}}{{Paid}}
 +
 
 
[[Category:Economists]]
 
[[Category:Economists]]
 +
[[Category:Biography]]
 
{{epname|Jones, Richard (economist)}}
 
{{epname|Jones, Richard (economist)}}
  
'''Richard Jones''' (1790 - January 26, 1855) was a [[Great Britain|British]] [[economics|economist]] and a [[minister (Christianity)|clergyman]], famous for his criticism of [[David Ricardo]] and his insistence on the [[historical relativism]] of [[political economy]]. He worked as a commissioner on the [[Tithe Commutation Act of 1836]]. The maps of the area developed during the survey in preparation for the Act, had great historical value and were used as references by [[genealogy|genealogists]] and other [[history|historical]] researchers.
+
[[Image:Richard Jones00.jpg|thumb|200 px|Richard Jones]]
 +
 
 +
'''Richard Jones''' (1790 – January 26, 1855) was a [[Great Britain|British]] [[economics|economist]] and a [[minister (Christianity)|clergyman]]. He is famous for his criticism of [[David Ricardo]] and his insistence on the [[historical relativism]] of [[political economy]]. Jones attacked the Ricardians for their theory of [[rent]], their wages fund doctrine, and their lack of empirical content. [[inductive reasoning|Inductivist]] in his method, Jones' work may be regarded as foundational to the English Historical School, of which well-known members include [[Walter Bagehot]] and [[Thomas E. Cliffe Leslie]].
 +
{{toc}}
 +
He also worked as a commissioner on the [[Tithe Commutation Act of 1836]]. The maps of the area developed during the survey in preparation for the Act had great historical value and have been of great value to [[genealogy|genealogists]] and other [[history|historical]] researchers.
  
 
==Life==
 
==Life==
  
'''Richard Jones''' was born in Royal Tunbridge Wells in [[England]], the son of a [[law|solicitor]]. He was intended for the [[law|legal]] profession, and was educated at Gonville and Caius College, [[University of Cambridge]]. He received his B.A. in 1816 and M.A. in 1819. His university friends include [[Charles Babbage]], [[John Herschel]], and [[William Whewell]]. Due to ill-health, however, Jones abandoned the idea of the [[law]] and decided to enter [[minister (Christianity)|ministry]].  
+
Richard Jones was born in Royal Tunbridge Wells in [[England]], the son of a solicitor. He was intended for the legal profession, and was educated at Gonville and Caius College, [[University of Cambridge]]. His university friends included [[Charles Babbage]], [[John Herschel]], and [[William Whewell]]. He received his B.A. in 1816 and M.A. in 1819. Due to ill-health, however, Jones abandoned the idea of the law and decided to enter [[minister (Christianity)|ministry]].
 +
 
 +
In 1817, Jones was ordained priest of the [[Church of England]], and until 1833 he held several ministerial posts in different parishes in [[Sussex]] and [[Kent]]. During that period he wrote his famous ''The Essay on the Distribution of Wealth and on the Sources of Taxation'' (1831) which drew wide nation-wide attention.
  
In 1817, Jones was ordained priest of the [[Church of England]], and until 1833 he held several ministerial posts in different parishes in [[Sussex]] and [[Kent]]. During that period he wrote his famous ''The Essay on the Distribution of Wealth and on the Sources of Taxation'' (1831) which drew wide national attention.
+
In 1833, he was appointed professor of [[political economy]] at [[King's College London]], following the resignation of [[Nassau William Senior]]. He left this post in 1835 to succeed [[Thomas Robert Malthus]] in the chair of political economy and history at the East India College at Haileybury, Hertfordshire, [[England]].  
  
In 1833 he was appointed professor of [[political economy]] at [[King's College London]], following the resignation of [[Nassau William Senior]]. He left this post in 1835 to succeed [[Thomas Robert Malthus]] in the chair of political economy and history at the East India College at Haileybury, Hertfordshire, [[England]].  
+
Jones took an active part in the commutation of [[tithe]]s in 1836 and showed great ability as tithe commissioner, an office which he filled till 1851. He also served for some time as charity commissioner.  
  
Jones took an active part in the commutation of [[tithe]]s in 1836 and showed great ability as a tithe commissioner, an office which he filled till 1851. He also served for some time as a charity commissioner.  
+
Together with [[Thomas Robert Malthus]] he was instrumental in establishing the Statistical Society of London, later known as the Royal Statistical Society.
  
 
Jones died on January 26, 1855, in Haileybury, Hertfordshire, [[England]], shortly after he had resigned his professorship.
 
Jones died on January 26, 1855, in Haileybury, Hertfordshire, [[England]], shortly after he had resigned his professorship.
Line 19: Line 27:
 
==Work==
 
==Work==
  
===Economical theory===
+
===Economic theory===
In 1831 Jones published his ''Essay on the Distribution of Wealth and on the Sources of Taxation'', his most important work. In it he showed himself to be a thorough-going critic of the [[David Ricardo|Ricardian]] system.
+
In 1831, Jones published his ''Essay on the Distribution of Wealth and on the Sources of Taxation'', his most important work. In it he showed himself to be a thorough-going critic of the [[David Ricardo|Ricardian]] system.
 
 
Jones was influenced by the [[inductive reasoning|inductivism]] of [[Francis Bacon]], which played key role in the development of his [[economics|economic]] ideas. Jones's conclusions were founded on a wide observation of contemporary facts, aided by the study of [[history]]. He believed that economical theories needed to be rooted in real empirical facts. He thus criticized Ricardo for his [[deductive method]] and generalization of economical laws.  
 
  
The world Jones studied was not an imaginary world, inhabited by abstract "''economic men''," but the real world with the different forms which the ownership and cultivation of land, and, in general, the conditions of production and distribution, assume at different times and places. His recognition of such different systems of life in communities occupying different stages in the progress of civilization led to his proposal of what he called a "political economy of nations." This was a protest against the practice of taking the exceptional state of facts which existed in a small corner of our [[planet]] as representing the uniform type of human society, and ignoring the effects of the early history and special development of each community as influencing its [[economics|economic]] phenomena.  
+
Jones was influenced by the [[inductive reasoning|inductivism]] of [[Francis Bacon]], which played a key role in the development of his [[economics|economic]] ideas. Jones' conclusions were founded on a wide observation of contemporary facts, aided by the study of [[history]]. He believed that economic theories needed to be rooted in real empirical facts. He thus criticized Ricardo for his [[deductive method]] and generalization of laws of economics.  
  
Jones was known for his freedom from exaggeration and one-sided statement. Whilst holding [[Thomas Robert Malthus|Malthus]] in perhaps undue esteem, he declined to accept the proposition that an increase of the means of subsistence was necessarily followed by an increase of population. He also believed that with the growth of population, in all well-governed and prosperous states, the command over food, instead of diminishing, increases.
+
The world Jones studied was not an imaginary world, inhabited by abstract "economic men," but the real world with the different forms that the ownership and cultivation of land, and the conditions of production and distribution, assume at different times and places. His recognition of such different systems of life in communities occupying different stages in the progress of [[civilization]] led him to propose what he called a "political economy of nations." This was a protest against the practice of taking the exceptional state of facts which existed in a small corner of our world as representing the uniform type of human [[society]], and ignoring the effects of the early history and unique development of each community as influencing its economic phenomena.  
  
=== The Tithe Commutation Act of 1836===
+
Whilst holding [[Thomas Robert Malthus|Malthus]] in perhaps undue esteem, Jones declined to accept the proposition that an increase of the means of subsistence was necessarily followed by an increase of population. He also believed that with the growth of population in all well-governed and prosperous states, the command over [[food]], instead of diminishing, rather increases.  
Jones also played instrumental role in the [[Tithe Commutation Act of 1836]]. Being elected by [[Archbishop of Canterbury]] as his representative to the commission to help bring the act, Jones joined other two commissioners - William Balmire (chairman) and Thomas Wentworth Buller.  
 
  
Before this act, [[tithes]] were paid as 10 percent of the produce of the land, payable in [[crop]]s, [[egg]]s, [[cattle]], or other goods. They were brought to the rector as payment for his services or as [[alms]], and were stored in a tithe barn attached to a church or a monestary. However, as that became impractical for numerous reasons, other new arrangements surfaced. The commission in which Jones was a member had a goal to level the national standard for paying tithes.  
+
===Tithe Commutation Act of 1836===
 +
Jones also played an instrumental role in the [[Tithe Commutation Act of 1836]]. Being elected by the [[Archbishop of Canterbury]] as his representative to the commission to assist in preparing the act, Jones joined other two commissioners - [[William Balmire]] (chairman) and [[Thomas Wentworth Buller]].  
  
The commission identified all properties and made detailed maps of all the area that was affected by the act. A map was made for each "tithe district". After that the calculation was made on the amount of the tithe.  
+
Before this act, [[tithe]]s were ten percent of the produce of the land, payable in [[crop]]s, [[egg]]s, [[cattle]], or other goods. They were brought to the rector as payment for his services or as [[alms]], and were stored in a tithe barn attached to a [[church]] or a [[monastery]]. However, as that became impractical for numerous reasons, other new arrangements surfaced. The commission in which Jones was a member had as its goal to level the national standard for paying tithes.  
  
The majority of the work was done between 1841 and 1851.
+
The commission identified all properties and made detailed maps of all the area affected by the act. A map was made for each "tithe district." Then the amounts of the tithes were calculated. The majority of this work was done between 1841 and 1851.
  
 
==Legacy==
 
==Legacy==
  
Unlike [[David Ricardo|Ricardo]], whose ideas were absolute and universal, Jones insisted on the [[historical relativism]] of [[political economy]]. He observed real economical phenomena, as occurring at different places and at different times. His ''Essay on the Distribution of Wealth'' (1831) can thus be regarded as a precursor of the [[Historical]] and [[Institutionalist]] Schools.
+
Unlike [[David Ricardo|Ricardo]], whose ideas were absolute and universal, Jones insisted on [[historical relativism]] in [[political economy]]. He observed real economic phenomena, as occurring at different places and at different times. His ''Essay on the Distribution of Wealth'' (1831) can thus be regarded as a precursor of the English Historical School of economists such as [[Walter Bagehot]] and the [[Institutionalism|Institutionalist]] school of economics.
  
The maps and apportionments that were left behind as the result of Jones’s work as a commissioner, are often used as references by [[genealogy|genealogists]] and other [[history|historical]] researchers.
+
The maps and apportionments that were the result of Jones’ work as Tithe Commissioner have continued to be used as references by [[genealogy|genealogists]] and other [[history|historical]] researchers.
  
 
==Publications==
 
==Publications==
  
*1831. Jones, Richard. ''An Essay on the Distribution of Wealth and on the Sources of Taxation''. London: J. Murray.
+
* Jones, Richard. 1831. ''An Essay on the Distribution of Wealth and on the Sources of Taxation''. London: J. Murray.
*1833. Jones, Richard. ''An introductory lecture on political economy, delivered at King's College, London, 27th February, 1833 to which is added A syllabus of a course of lectures on the wages of labor, to be delivered at King's College, London, in the month of April, 1833.'' London: John Murray.  
+
* Jones, Richard. 1833. ''An introductory lecture on political economy, delivered at King's College, London, 27th February, 1833 to which is added A syllabus of a course of lectures on the wages of labor, to be delivered at King's College, London, in the month of April, 1833.'' London: John Murray.  
*[1859] 1964. Jones, Richard and Whewell, William (ed.). ''Literary Remains, Consisting of Lectures and Tracts on Political Economy, of the late Rev. Richard Jones''. New York: Augustus M. Kelley.  
+
* Jones, Richard and Whewell, William (ed.). [1859] 1964. ''Literary Remains, Consisting of Lectures and Tracts on Political Economy, of the late Rev. Richard Jones''. New York: Augustus M. Kelley.  
*2001. Jones, Richard. ''Peasant Rents: Being the First Half of an Essay on the Distribution of Wealth and on the Sources of Taxation''. Adamant Media Corporation. ISBN 054390752X
+
* Jones, Richard. 2001. ''Peasant Rents: Being the First Half of an Essay on the Distribution of Wealth and on the Sources of Taxation''. Adamant Media Corporation. ISBN 054390752X
  
 
==References==
 
==References==
  
*Pullen, John. 2001. ''Jones, an Essay on the Distribution of Wealth and on the Sources of Taxation, 1831''. Working Paper Series in Economics. University of New England. Retrieved October 4, 2007, from <http://www.une.edu.au/economics/publications/ECONwp01-1.PDF>
+
*Pullen, John. 2001. [http://www.une.edu.au/economics/publications/ECONwp01-1.PDF ''Jones, an Essay on the Distribution of Wealth and on the Sources of Taxation, 1831''] Working Paper Series in Economics. University of New England. Retrieved November 21, 2007.  
*Reinhart, Blaise F. 1962. ''The life of Richard Jones and his contributions to economic methodology and theory''. Thesis (Ph. D.—Econ.). Catholic University of America.
+
*Reinhart, Blaise F. 1962. ''The life of Richard Jones and his contributions to economic methodology and theory''. Thesis (Ph. D.—Econ.). Catholic University of America.
 
*Weber, Hans. 1939. ''Richard Jones; ein früher englischer abtrünniger der klassischen schule der nationalökonomie''. Zürich: H. Girsberger.
 
*Weber, Hans. 1939. ''Richard Jones; ein früher englischer abtrünniger der klassischen schule der nationalökonomie''. Zürich: H. Girsberger.
  
 
==External links==
 
==External links==
 +
All links retrieved December 13, 2022.
  
*[http://www.une.edu.au/economics/publications/ECONwp01-1.PDF R. Jones, An Essay on the Distribution of Wealth and on the Sources of Taxation, 1831] – Article by John Pullen (2001) on Jones life and work. Retrieved October 4, 2007.
+
*[http://www.litencyc.com/php/stopics.php?rec=true&UID=1452 Tithes (1000-1880)] – On the history of tithing, in Literary Encyclopedia.
*[http://www.llgc.org.uk/index.php?id=551 The Tithe Commutation Act 1836] – On the historical background of the Act. Retrieved October 4, 2007.
 
*[http://www.litencyc.com/php/stopics.php?rec=true&UID=1452 Tithes (1000-1880)] – On the history of tithing, in Literary Encyclopedia. Retrieved October 4, 2007.
 
*[http://www.amlwchhistory.co.uk/data/tithe.htm What are Tithe maps?] – On Tithe maps. Retrieved October 4, 2007.
 
  
 +
{{English historical school economists}}
 
{{Credits|Richard_Jones_(economist)|120193125|}}
 
{{Credits|Richard_Jones_(economist)|120193125|}}

Latest revision as of 01:42, 14 December 2022

Richard Jones

Richard Jones (1790 – January 26, 1855) was a British economist and a clergyman. He is famous for his criticism of David Ricardo and his insistence on the historical relativism of political economy. Jones attacked the Ricardians for their theory of rent, their wages fund doctrine, and their lack of empirical content. Inductivist in his method, Jones' work may be regarded as foundational to the English Historical School, of which well-known members include Walter Bagehot and Thomas E. Cliffe Leslie.

He also worked as a commissioner on the Tithe Commutation Act of 1836. The maps of the area developed during the survey in preparation for the Act had great historical value and have been of great value to genealogists and other historical researchers.

Life

Richard Jones was born in Royal Tunbridge Wells in England, the son of a solicitor. He was intended for the legal profession, and was educated at Gonville and Caius College, University of Cambridge. His university friends included Charles Babbage, John Herschel, and William Whewell. He received his B.A. in 1816 and M.A. in 1819. Due to ill-health, however, Jones abandoned the idea of the law and decided to enter ministry.

In 1817, Jones was ordained priest of the Church of England, and until 1833 he held several ministerial posts in different parishes in Sussex and Kent. During that period he wrote his famous The Essay on the Distribution of Wealth and on the Sources of Taxation (1831) which drew wide nation-wide attention.

In 1833, he was appointed professor of political economy at King's College London, following the resignation of Nassau William Senior. He left this post in 1835 to succeed Thomas Robert Malthus in the chair of political economy and history at the East India College at Haileybury, Hertfordshire, England.

Jones took an active part in the commutation of tithes in 1836 and showed great ability as tithe commissioner, an office which he filled till 1851. He also served for some time as charity commissioner.

Together with Thomas Robert Malthus he was instrumental in establishing the Statistical Society of London, later known as the Royal Statistical Society.

Jones died on January 26, 1855, in Haileybury, Hertfordshire, England, shortly after he had resigned his professorship.

Work

Economic theory

In 1831, Jones published his Essay on the Distribution of Wealth and on the Sources of Taxation, his most important work. In it he showed himself to be a thorough-going critic of the Ricardian system.

Jones was influenced by the inductivism of Francis Bacon, which played a key role in the development of his economic ideas. Jones' conclusions were founded on a wide observation of contemporary facts, aided by the study of history. He believed that economic theories needed to be rooted in real empirical facts. He thus criticized Ricardo for his deductive method and generalization of laws of economics.

The world Jones studied was not an imaginary world, inhabited by abstract "economic men," but the real world with the different forms that the ownership and cultivation of land, and the conditions of production and distribution, assume at different times and places. His recognition of such different systems of life in communities occupying different stages in the progress of civilization led him to propose what he called a "political economy of nations." This was a protest against the practice of taking the exceptional state of facts which existed in a small corner of our world as representing the uniform type of human society, and ignoring the effects of the early history and unique development of each community as influencing its economic phenomena.

Whilst holding Malthus in perhaps undue esteem, Jones declined to accept the proposition that an increase of the means of subsistence was necessarily followed by an increase of population. He also believed that with the growth of population in all well-governed and prosperous states, the command over food, instead of diminishing, rather increases.

Tithe Commutation Act of 1836

Jones also played an instrumental role in the Tithe Commutation Act of 1836. Being elected by the Archbishop of Canterbury as his representative to the commission to assist in preparing the act, Jones joined other two commissioners - William Balmire (chairman) and Thomas Wentworth Buller.

Before this act, tithes were ten percent of the produce of the land, payable in crops, eggs, cattle, or other goods. They were brought to the rector as payment for his services or as alms, and were stored in a tithe barn attached to a church or a monastery. However, as that became impractical for numerous reasons, other new arrangements surfaced. The commission in which Jones was a member had as its goal to level the national standard for paying tithes.

The commission identified all properties and made detailed maps of all the area affected by the act. A map was made for each "tithe district." Then the amounts of the tithes were calculated. The majority of this work was done between 1841 and 1851.

Legacy

Unlike Ricardo, whose ideas were absolute and universal, Jones insisted on historical relativism in political economy. He observed real economic phenomena, as occurring at different places and at different times. His Essay on the Distribution of Wealth (1831) can thus be regarded as a precursor of the English Historical School of economists such as Walter Bagehot and the Institutionalist school of economics.

The maps and apportionments that were the result of Jones’ work as Tithe Commissioner have continued to be used as references by genealogists and other historical researchers.

Publications

  • Jones, Richard. 1831. An Essay on the Distribution of Wealth and on the Sources of Taxation. London: J. Murray.
  • Jones, Richard. 1833. An introductory lecture on political economy, delivered at King's College, London, 27th February, 1833 to which is added A syllabus of a course of lectures on the wages of labor, to be delivered at King's College, London, in the month of April, 1833. London: John Murray.
  • Jones, Richard and Whewell, William (ed.). [1859] 1964. Literary Remains, Consisting of Lectures and Tracts on Political Economy, of the late Rev. Richard Jones. New York: Augustus M. Kelley.
  • Jones, Richard. 2001. Peasant Rents: Being the First Half of an Essay on the Distribution of Wealth and on the Sources of Taxation. Adamant Media Corporation. ISBN 054390752X

References
ISBN links support NWE through referral fees

  • Pullen, John. 2001. Jones, an Essay on the Distribution of Wealth and on the Sources of Taxation, 1831 Working Paper Series in Economics. University of New England. Retrieved November 21, 2007.
  • Reinhart, Blaise F. 1962. The life of Richard Jones and his contributions to economic methodology and theory. Thesis (Ph. D.—Econ.). Catholic University of America.
  • Weber, Hans. 1939. Richard Jones; ein früher englischer abtrünniger der klassischen schule der nationalökonomie. Zürich: H. Girsberger.

External links

All links retrieved December 13, 2022.

Credits

New World Encyclopedia writers and editors rewrote and completed the Wikipedia article in accordance with New World Encyclopedia standards. This article abides by terms of the Creative Commons CC-by-sa 3.0 License (CC-by-sa), which may be used and disseminated with proper attribution. Credit is due under the terms of this license that can reference both the New World Encyclopedia contributors and the selfless volunteer contributors of the Wikimedia Foundation. To cite this article click here for a list of acceptable citing formats.The history of earlier contributions by wikipedians is accessible to researchers here:

The history of this article since it was imported to New World Encyclopedia:

Note: Some restrictions may apply to use of individual images which are separately licensed.