Difference between revisions of "Money supply" - New World Encyclopedia

From New World Encyclopedia
m (Robot: Remove date links)
Line 4: Line 4:
 
{{globalize}}
 
{{globalize}}
  
'''Money supply''' ("monetary aggregates", "money stock"), a [[macroeconomics|macroeconomic]] concept, is the quantity of [[money]] available within the economy to purchase [[good (economics)|good]]s, [[service]]s, and [[security (finance)|securities]].
+
'''Money supply''', "monetary aggregates" or "money stock" is a [[macroeconomic]] concept defining the quantity of [[money]] available within a nation’s economy used to purchase economic [[goods]], [[service]]s, and [[financial securities]]. The monetary sector of a nation’s economy, as opposed to its [[real sector]], concerns the money ''market''. The same tools of analysis can be applied to this market as can be applied to other goods markets: supply and demand result in an equilibrium price, which defines the [[interest rate]] and quantity of real money balances.
  
==Introduction==
 
The monetary sector, as opposed to the [[real sector]], concerns the money ''market''. The same tools of analysis can be applied as to other markets: supply and demand result in an equilibrium price (the [[interest rate]]) and quantity (of real money balances).
 
  
When thinking about the "supply" of money, it is natural to think of the total of [[banknote]]s and [[coin]]s in an economy. That, however, is incomplete. In the [[United States]], coins are ''minted'' by the [[United States Mint]], part of the [[United States Department of the Treasury|Department of the Treasury]], ''outside of'' the [[Federal Reserve]]. Banknotes are ''printed'' by the Bureau of Engraving & Printing ''on behalf of'' the Federal Reserve as symbolic tokens of electronic credit-based money that has already been created or more precisely, ''issued'' by [[bank|private banks]]<ref name="footnote_1">The term ''private bank'' is here used as a bank that is not government owned, not as a bank for high net worth individuals.</ref> through [[fractional reserve banking]].
+
==Banknotes and Coinage==
 +
When thinking about a nation’s "supply" of money, it is natural to think of the total of [[banknote]]s and [[coin]]s in an economy. However in many countries, these do not calculate into a nation’s total money supply. For instance, in the [[United States]], coins are ''minted'' by the [[United States Mint]], part of the [[United States Department of the Treasury]], which lies ''outside of'' the [[U.S. Federal Reserve]]. Banknotes are ''printed'' by the Bureau of Engraving & Printing ''on behalf of'' the Federal Reserve as symbolic tokens of electronic credit-based money that has already been created or ''issued'' by [[private banks]]. The term ''private bank'' as used here refers to a bank that is not government owned.  
  
In this respect, all banknotes in existence are systematically linked to the expansion of the electronic credit-based money supply. However, coinage can be increased or decreased outside this system by Legal Mandate or Legislative Acts. However, at present the coin base is held in check and used as a complementary system rather than a competitive system with private bank issue of electronic credit-based money. The common practice is to include printed and minted money supply in the same metric '''M0'''.
+
In this respect, all banknotes in existence are systematically linked to the expansion of the electronic credit-based money supply. However, coinage can be increased or decreased outside this system by [[Legal Mandate]] or [[Legislative Acts]]. During most periods the coin base is held in check and used as a complementary system rather than a competitive system with private bank issues of electronic credit-based money. The common practice is to include printed and minted money supply in the same metric, define as '''M0'''.
  
The more accurate starting point for the concept of money supply is the total of all electronic credit-based deposit balances in bank (and other financial) accounts (for more precise definitions, see below) plus all the minted coins and printed paper. The M1 money supply is M0, plus the total of (non-paper or coin) deposit balances without any withdrawal restrictions (restricted accounts that you can't write checks on are put in the next level of liquidity, M2).
+
==Money Supply==
 +
The more accurate starting point for the concept of the money supply is the total of all electronic credit-based deposit balances held in financial accounts plus all the minted coins and printed paper. The M1 money supply consists of all noted and minted monies, or M0, plus the total of non-paper or coin deposit balances without any withdrawal restrictions. Restricted accounts of which one cannot write checks on are put in the next level of liquidity, defined by money supply M2.
  
The relationship between the M0 and M1 money supplies is the '''money multiplier''' &mdash; basically, the ratio of cash and coin in people's wallets and bank vaults and ATMs to Total balances in their financial accounts. The gap and lag between the two (M0 and M1 - M0) occurs because of the system of fractional reserve banking.
+
The relationship between the M0 and M1 money supplies is the '''money multiplier''' which defines the ratio of cash and coin in people's wallets and bank vaults and ATMs to total balances in their financial accounts. The gap and lag between the two money supplies occurs because of the system of fractional reserve banking, referring to a banking practice where more money is issued than what is held by the central bank in reserves. The U.S. Federal Reserve Board maintains such a system.  
  
==Scope==
+
Because, in principle, money is anything that can be used in the settlement of a [[debt]], there are varying measures of the money supply. The most restrictive measures count only those forms of money available for immediate transactions, while broader measures include money held as a store of value.
Because (in principle) money is anything that can be used in settlement of a [[debt]], there are varying measures of money supply. The narrowest (i.e., most restrictive) measures count only those forms of money available for immediate transactions, while broader measures include money held as a store of value  
 
  
===United States===
+
==The United States==
[[Image:Money-supply.png|thumb|right|U.S. Money Supply from 1959-2006]]The most common measures are named M0 (narrowest), M1, M2, and M3. In the United States they are defined by the Federal Reserve as follows:
+
[[Image:Money-supply.png|thumb|right|U.S. Money Supply from 1959-2006]]
 +
Under the U.S. Federal Reserve, the most common measures of money supply are termed M0, M1, M2, and M3. The Federal Reserve defines such measures as follows:
 
* '''M0''': The total of all physical [[currency]], plus accounts at the central bank which can be exchanged for physical currency.
 
* '''M0''': The total of all physical [[currency]], plus accounts at the central bank which can be exchanged for physical currency.
* '''M1''': M0 + the amount in [[demand account]]s ("checking" or "current" accounts).
+
* '''M1''': Measure M0 + the amount in [[demand account]]s, including "checking" or "current" accounts.
* '''M2''': M1 + most [[savings account]]s, [[money market account]]s, and [[certificate of deposit]] accounts (CDs) of under $100,000.
+
* '''M2''': Measure M1 + most [[savings account]]s, [[money market account]]s, and [[certificate of deposit]] accounts, or CDs, of under $100,000.
* '''M3''': M2 + all other CDs, deposits of [[eurodollars]] and [[repurchase agreement]]s.
+
* '''M3''': Measure M2 + all other CDs, deposits of [[eurodollars]] and [[repurchase agreement]]s.
  
As of March 23, 2006, information regarding M3 will no longer be published by the Federal Reserve. The other three money supply measures will continue to be provided in detail. On March 7th, 2006, Congressman [[Ron Paul]] introduced H.R. 4892 in an effort to reverse this change.<ref>http://thomas.loc.gov/cgi-bin/query/z?c109:H.R.4892:</ref>
+
The [[U.S. government]] can control the growth of M3 through the issuance of new Government [[treasury securities|debt instruments]]. Money which is re-invested back into U.S. Government debt, including treasury bonds and treasury bills, ceases to be part of M3. Thus, if a government wishes to slow the growth of M3, it can raise interest rates, therefore withdrawing money from M3 and transferring it into Government debt.
  
=== United Kingdom ===
+
==The United Kingdom==
There are just two official UK measures.  M0 is referred to as the "wide monetary base" or "narrow money" and M4 is referred to as "broad money" or simply "the money supply".   
+
Within the United Kingdom, there are just two official money supply measures.  M0, which is referred to as the "wide monetary base" or "narrow money", and M4, which is referred to as "broad money" or simply "the money supply".  These measures are defined as such:
* '''M0''': Cash outside Bank of England + Banks' operational deposits with Bank of England.   
+
* '''M0''': All cash outside the Bank of England + private banks' operational deposits with the Bank of England.   
* '''M4''': Cash outside banks (ie. in circulation with the public and non-bank firms) + private-sector retail bank and building society deposits + Private-sector wholesale bank and building society deposits and CDs.v
+
* '''M4''': All cash outside banking institutes, either in circulation with the public and non-bank firms, + private-sector retail bank and building society deposits + private-sector wholesale bank and building society deposits and certificates of deposits.
  
==Link with inflation==
+
== Monetary Exchange Equation==
=== Monetary exchange equation ===
+
A nation’s money supply is important because it is linked to price [[inflation]] by the "monetary exchange equation", which follows:
 
 
Money supply is important because it is linked to [[inflation]] by the "monetary exchange equation":
 
  
 
:<math>
 
:<math>
Line 43: Line 41:
 
</math>
 
</math>
  
where:
+
Within this equation:
*[[income velocity of money|velocity]] = the number of times per year that money changes hands (if it is a number it is always simply nominal GDP / money supply)
+
*[[income velocity of money|Velocity]] = The number of times per year that money changes hands.
*real GDP = nominal [[Gross Domestic Product]] / GDP deflator
+
*Real GDP = Nominal [[Gross Domestic Product]] / GDP deflator.
*[[GDP deflator]] = measure of inflation. Money supply may be less than or greater than the demand of money in the economy
+
*[[GDP Deflator]] = A Measure of inflation, whereas the money supply may be less than or greater than the demand of money in the economy.  
 
 
In other words, if the money supply grows faster than real GDP growth (described as "unproductive debt expansion"), inflation is likely to follow ("inflation is always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon"). This statement must be qualified slightly, due to changes in velocity. While the [[monetarists]] presume that velocity is relatively stable, in fact velocity exhibits variability at business-cycle frequencies, so that the velocity equation is not particularly useful as a short run tool. Moreover, in the US, velocity has grown at an average of slightly more than 1% a year between 1959 and 2005.
 
 
 
=== Percentage ===
 
  
(excerpted from "Breaking Monetary Policy into Pieces", May 24 2004, http://www.hussmanfunds.com/wmc/wmc040524.htm)
+
If the money supply grows faster than the growth of real GDP, described as "unproductive debt expansion", inflation is likely to follow. While followers of the [[monetarist]] school of economics presume that velocity is relatively stable, velocity in fact exhibits variability at business-cycle frequencies, so that the velocity equation is not particularly useful as a short run tool. Moreover, in the U.S., velocity has grown at an average of slightly more than 1% per year between 1959 and 2005.
  
In terms of percentage changes (to a small approximation, the percentage change in a product, say XY is equal to the sum of the percentage changes %X + %Y). So:
+
==Basic Inflation Identity==
 +
Inflation is inherently linked with the percentage change of both the rate of money growth and the change in velocity. It also accounts for the rate of output growth. In analyzing percentage changes, a percentage change in product XY is equal to the sum of the percentage changes %X + %Y. This follows:
  
 
:%P + %Y = %M + %V
 
:%P + %Y = %M + %V
  
That equation rearranged gives the "[[basic inflation identity]]":
+
Rearranged, this equation provides the "[[basic inflation identity]]", which follows:
  
 
:%P = %M + %V - %Y
 
:%P = %M + %V - %Y
  
Inflation (%P) is equal to the rate of money growth (%M), plus the change in velocity (%V), minus the rate of output growth (%Y).
+
According to the basic inflation identity, inflation (%P) is equal to the rate of money growth (%M), plus the change in velocity (%V), minus the rate of output growth (%Y).
  
==Money Supply and Cash==
+
==Expanding the Money Supply==
In the U.S., as of July 28, 2005, M1 was about $1.4 trillion, M2 about $6.5 trillion, and M3 about $9.7 trillion. If you split all of the money equally per person in the United States, each person would end up with roughly $30,000 ($9,700,000M/300M). The amount of actual physical cash M0 was $688 billion in 2004, roughly double the $328 billion in cash and cash equivalents on [[deposit]] at [[Citigroup]] as of the end of that year and roughly $ 2,125 per person in the US.<ref>http://finance.yahoo.com/q/bs?s=C&annual</ref>
+
Historically, money was defined in terms of metal, and included gold, silver, and copper. Money also constituted other objects that were difficult to duplicate, but easy to transport and divide. Later, money consisted of paper notes, which are now issued by all modern governments. With the rise of modern industrial capitalism, money has gone through several phases including but not limited to; ''bank notes'' including paper issued by banks as an interest-bearing loan that common to the 19th century, and ''paper notes'' consisting of coins with varying amounts of precious metal, termed [[legal tender]], that are issued by various governments. There is also a near-money in the form of interest bearing bonds issued by governments with solid credit ratings. Money has also consisted of bank credit through the creation of checkable deposits in the granting of various loans to business, government and individuals.  
  
==The Central Bank==
+
Thus, all debt denominated in dollars, including mortgages, money markets, credit card debt, and travelers checke, is money. However, the creation of dollar-denominated debt, or any generic obligation, creates money only when a bank is granting the debt. "High powered" money, or M0, is created when the elected government spends money into the economy.  The money created in the bank loan process is termed [[bank money]]. These forms of money trade at par one with the other. Banks are limited in the amount of loans they can grant and thus in the amount of bank money or credit they can create by both the net assets of the bank and by reserve requirements. For most intents and purposes the aggregate of M0 multiplied by the reserve requirement will be an indicator of the aggregate of loans.  If additional money is needed in the banking system to allow more loans, the central bank will create money by purchasing [[bonds]] or [[T-bills]] with money created from the other. No matter who sells the bonds the money will end up in the banking system as M0.
The United States supply of money, outside of coins minted by the [[United States Mint]], can increase only if the private banks issue more by loaning into circulation through Fractional Reserve Bank Lending Practices. Subsequently paper notes are increased only as they are printed by the BEP on behalf of the Federal Reserve Fractional Banking System and are swapped at par value by the Federal Reserve Bank with Private Banks for their already issued electronic credits, which are then expunged (some believe retained) from the system by the Federal Reserve Bank. Thus, these printed money tokens (notes) merely replace already issued electronic credits on a one-for-one basis.
 
  
The larger definitions of the money supply, M1, M2, and M3, are types of [[deposit account]]s. The first balance sheet item in a bank is usually deposits. Of the money in a bank deposit, depending on [[reserve requirements]], either the whole sum or some fraction of it can immediately be lent out. The borrower can buy an asset and the seller of that asset can place the proceeds in another money supply constituent [[deposit]]. The money supply has just increased, because both the original and secondary deposits count as part of the money supply. That money can therefore continue to increase many times over. The [[Federal Reserve]] decides the level of "[[reserves of depository institutions]]".
+
==Shrinking the Money Supply==
 +
Perhaps the most obvious way money can be destroyed is if paper bills are burned or taken out of circulation by the central bank. But, it should be remembered that legal tender usually constitutes less than 4% of the broad [[money supply]].
  
[[Monetary policy]] has effects on employment and output in the short run, but in the long run, it primarily affects prices.
+
Current banking systems are based on fractional reserves so money can be destroyed if depositors withdraw funds from a bank. When money is withdrawn it can no longer be used for lending and just as the fractional reserve system gives leverage to the creation of money, it also gives leverage to the destruction of money. Bank [[savings]] are actually a kind of loans; savers loan their money to a  bank at a low interest rate or merely in exchange for the benefit of convenience or its security, accepting that they lose a small amount of value to inflation. The bank may use this loan to manage its deposit liabilities.
  
===The balance sheets===
+
Another way money can be destroyed is when any bank loan is paid off or any government bond or T-Bill is purchased by the private sector. The money value of the contract or bond is destroyed when taken out of circulation. If a bank loan is defaulted upon then the "interest" paid by other borrowers will be employed to cover the default. A very large part of the "interest" paid on bank loans is actually a finance charge employed to cover bad loans.  A group of good borrowers pay the loan instead of the original borrower.  In cases where the default is large such as loans to foreign governments Federal intervention has, in the past, rescued the banks. In this instance it would seem that the taxpayers and/or money holders will pay the debt.  The effects on the money supply will be controlled, again, by the level of bond purchase or redemption or the level of T-Bill sales or purchases by the Treasury.
This is what money supply growth may look like starting with 1 new dollar of [[deposits]]. The money is moving from left to right. The Central Bank injects money from its reserve into the economy by buying a government bond from Bank 1 for $1, Bank 1 lends the proceeds to Person 1, who buys an asset from Person 2, who deposits the proceeds at Bank 2, who loans it to Person 3, who buys a service from Person 4, who deposits the proceeds in Bank 1, and the money supply becomes $3.<ref>See, for example, the [[balance sheet]] from [[Citigroup]] Inc. at http://www.citigroup.com/citigroup/fin/ar.htm</ref>
 
  
{| border="0" cellpadding="0" cellspacing="2" align="center" width="" height=""
+
In extreme forms, a [[bank run]] or panic may drive a bank into [[insolvency]] and, if uninsured, the savings of all its [[deposit]]ors are lost. Such bank failures were a major cause of the tremendous contraction in the money supply that occurred during the [[Great Depression]], particularly in the United States. In that country many [[bank reform|banking reforms]] were subsequently enacted during the [[New Deal]], including the creation of the [[Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation]] to guarantee private bank deposits.
|-
 
|
 
{| border="1" cellpadding="2" cellspacing="0" align="center" width="140px"
 
|+''' Central Bank '''
 
|-
 
! style="background:#efefef;" colspan="2" | Assets
 
|-
 
| Gov. debt (to B1) || align="right"| $1
 
|-
 
! style="background:#efefef;" colspan="2" | Liabilities
 
|-
 
| - || align="right"| -
 
|}
 
||
 
{| border="1" cellpadding="2" cellspacing="0" align="center" width="140px"
 
|+'''Bank 1'''
 
|-
 
! style="background:#efefef;" colspan="2" | Assets
 
|-
 
| Loan (to P1) || align="right"| $1
 
|-
 
! style="background:#efefef;" colspan="2" | Liabilities
 
|-
 
| Deposit (from P4) || align="right"| $1
 
|}
 
||
 
{| border="1" cellpadding="2" cellspacing="0" align="center" width="140px"
 
|+''' Person 1'''
 
|-
 
! style="background:#efefef;" colspan="2" | Assets
 
|-
 
| Investment (to P2) || align="right"| $1
 
|-
 
! style="background:#efefef;" colspan="2" | Liabilities
 
|-
 
| Loan (from B1) || align="right"| $1
 
|}
 
||
 
{| border="1" cellpadding="2" cellspacing="0" align="center" width="140px"
 
|+''' Person 2'''
 
|-
 
! style="background:#efefef;" colspan="2" | Assets
 
|-
 
| Deposit (to B2) || align="right"| $1
 
|-
 
! style="background:#efefef;" colspan="2" | Liabilities
 
|-
 
| - || align="right"| -
 
|}
 
||
 
{| border="1" cellpadding="2" cellspacing="0" align="center" width="140px"
 
|+'''Bank 2'''
 
|-
 
! style="background:#efefef;" colspan="2" | Assets
 
|-
 
| Loan (to P3) || align="right"| $1
 
|-
 
! style="background:#efefef;" colspan="2" | Liabilities
 
|-
 
| Deposit (from P2) || align="right"| $1
 
|}
 
|}
 
  
==Bank reserves at Central Bank==
+
==Central Bank Policies==
When a [[central bank]] is "easing", it triggers an increase in money supply by purchasing [[government bond|government securities]] on the open market thus increasing available funds for private banks to loan through fractional reserve banking (the issue of new money through loans) and thus grows the money supply. When the central bank is "tightening", it slows the process of private bank issue by selling securities on the open market and pulling money (that could be loaned) out of the private banking sector. It reduces or increases the supply of short term government debt, and inversely increases or reduces the supply of lending funds and thereby the ability of private banks to issue new money through debt.
+
When a [[central bank]] is "easing", it triggers an increase in money supply by purchasing [[government bonds]], or [[securities]], on the open market thus increasing available funds for private banks to loan through fractional reserve banking , which is the issue of new money through loans. This proves to increase the money supply. When the central bank is "tightening", it slows the process of private bank issue by selling securities on the open market and pulling money out of the private banking sector. It reduces or increases the supply of short term government debt, and inversely increases or reduces the supply of lending funds and thereby the ability of private banks to issue new money through debt.
  
The operative notion of easy money is that the central bank creates new [[bank reserves]] (in the US known as "[[federal funds]]"), which let the banks lend out more money. These loans get spent, and the proceeds get deposited at other banks. Whatever is not required to be held as reserves is then lent out again, and through the magic of the "money multiplier", loans and bank deposits go up by many times the initial injection of reserves.
+
The operative notion of easy money is that the central bank creates new [[bank reserves]] which let the banks lend out more money. These loans get spent, and the proceeds get deposited at other banks. Whatever is not required to be held as reserves is then lent out again, and through the "money multiplier", loans and bank deposits will increase by many times the initial injection of reserves.
  
However in the 1970s the reserve requirements on deposits started to fall with the emergence of [[money market funds]], which require no reserves. Then in the early 1990s, reserve requirements were dropped to zero on [[savings deposit]]s, [[Certificate of deposit|CD]]s, and [[Eurocurrency deposits]]. At present, reserve requirements apply only to "[[transactions deposits]]" - essentially [[checking accounts]]. The vast majority of funding sources used by Private Banks to create loans have nothing to do with bank reserves and in effect create what is known as "moral hazard" and speculative bubble economies.
+
In the 1970’s, central bank reserve requirements on deposit started to fall with the emergence of [[money market funds]], which require no holding of reserves. In the early 1990’s, reserve requirements were dropped to zero on [[savings deposit]]s, [[Certificate of deposit|CD]]s, and [[Eurocurrency deposits]]. At present, reserve requirements apply only to "[[transactions deposits]]", which include mainly [[checking accounts]]. The vast majority of funding sources used by private banks to create loans have nothing to do with bank reserves and in effect create what is known as "moral hazard" and speculative bubble economies.
  
 
These days, [[commercial and industrial loans]] are financed by issuing large denomination [[Certificate of deposit|CD]]s. [[Money market]] deposits are largely used to lend to corporations who issue [[commercial paper]]. Consumer loans are also made using [[savings deposit]]s which are not subject to reserve requirements. These loans can be bunched into securities and sold to somebody else, taking them off of the bank's books.
 
These days, [[commercial and industrial loans]] are financed by issuing large denomination [[Certificate of deposit|CD]]s. [[Money market]] deposits are largely used to lend to corporations who issue [[commercial paper]]. Consumer loans are also made using [[savings deposit]]s which are not subject to reserve requirements. These loans can be bunched into securities and sold to somebody else, taking them off of the bank's books.
  
The point is simple. Commercial, industrial and consumer loans no longer have any link to bank reserves. Since 1995, the volume of such loans has exploded, while bank reserves have declined.
+
Over time, commercial, industrial and consumer loans have ceased to link with bank reserves. Since 1995, the volume of such loans has exploded, while bank reserves have declined.
  
In recent years, the irrelevance of open market operations has also been argued by academic economists renown for their work on the implications of [[rational expectations]], including [[Robert Lucas, Jr.]], [[Thomas Sargent]], [[Neil Wallace]], [[Finn E. Kydland]], [[Edward C. Prescott]] and [[Scott Freeman]].
+
==Policy Criticism==
 +
One of the principal jobs of [[central bank]]s, such as the U.S. [[Federal Reserve]], the [[Bank of England]] and the [[European Central Bank]], is to keep money supply growth in line with real GDP growth. Central banks do this primarily by targeting some inter-bank interest rate. In the United States, this is the [[federal funds rate]] obtained through the use of [[open market operation]]s.
  
==Arguments and criticism==
+
A very common criticism of this target policy is that "real GDP growth" is, in fact, meaningless and since GDP can grow for many reasons including manmade disasters and crises, is not correlated with any known means of measurement well-being. The policy use of GDP figures is considered to be an abuse, and a common solution proposed by such critics is that a nation’s money supply should be kept in line with a more ecological, social and human mean of [[well-being]]. In theory, money supply would expand when well-being is improving, and contract when well-being is decreasing. Proponents believe this policy to give all parties in the economy a direct interest in improving well-being.
One of the principal jobs of [[central bank]]s (such as the [[Federal Reserve]], the [[Bank of England]] and the [[European Central Bank]]) is to keep money supply growth in line with real GDP growth. Central banks do this primarily by targeting some inter-bank interest rate (in the U.S., this is the [[federal funds rate]]) through [[open market operation]]s.
 
  
A very common criticism of this policy, originating with the creators of GDP as a measure, is that "real GDP growth" is in fact meaningless, and since GDP can grow for many reasons including manmade disasters and crises, is not correlated with any known means of [[measuring well-being]]. This use of the GDP figures is considered by its own creators to be an abuse, and dangerous. The most common solution proposed by such critics is that money supply (which determines the value of all [[financial capital]], ultimately, by diluting it) should be kept in line with some more ecological and social and human means of [[measuring well-being]]. In theory, money supply would expand when well-being is improving, and contract when well-being is decreasing, giving all parties in the economy a direct interest in improving well-being.
+
This argument must be balanced against what is nearly [[dogma]] among economists: that the control of [[inflation]] is the main job of a central bank, and that any introduction of non-financial means of [[measuring well-being]] has an inevitable [[domino effect]] of increasing [[government spending]] and diluting [[capital]].  
  
This argument must be balanced against what is nearly [[dogma]] among economists: that the control of [[inflation]] is the main (or only) job of a central bank, and that any introduction of non-financial means of [[measuring well-being]] has an inevitable [[domino effect]] of increasing [[government spending]] and diluting [[capital (economics)|capital]] and the rewards of gainfully employing capital.
+
[[Currency integration]] is thought by some economists, including [[Robert Mundell]], to alleviate this problem by ensuring that currencies become less competitive in the [[commodity markets]], and that a wider political base be employed in the setting of currency and inflation and well-being policy. This thinking is in part the basis of the [[Euro]] currency integration within the [[European Union]].
  
Currency integration is thought by some economists — [[Robert Mundell]], for example — to alleviate this problem by ensuring that currencies become less competitive in the [[commodity markets]], and that a wider political base be employed in the setting of currency and inflation and well-being policy. This thinking is in part the basis of the [[Euro]] currency integration in the [[European Union]].
+
Some economists argue for the money supply to remain constant at all times. With growth in production, this would result in falling prices. A constant money supply will keep nominal incomes constant over time; however falling prices will lead to an increase in real incomes. Due to such confliction, policy regarding a nation’s money supply remains one of the most controversial aspects of economics itself.
  
Some economists argue for the money supply to remain constant at all times. With growth in production, this would result in falling prices. A constant money supply will keep nominal incomes constant over time. However, falling prices will lead to an increase in real incomes.
+
==Sources==
 
+
* Chevallier, J.P. ''On the Inverse Relation Between Excess Money Supply and Growth.'' [http://chevallier.turgot.org/a363-Monetary_creation_aggregates_and_GDP_growth.html  '''Monetary creation, aggregates and GDP growth'''].
Money supply remains one of the most controversial aspects of economics itself.
 
 
 
==United States monetary base==
 
[[United States]] [[monetary base]] at the end of September 2004.
 
 
 
{| border="1" cellpadding="2" cellspacing="0" align="center" width="400px"
 
|+''' Monetary base (billions of dollars) (not seasonally adjusted) '''
 
|-
 
! style="background:#efefef;" colspan="6" | Monetary Base
 
|-
 
| [[Reserves of depository institutions]] || align="right"| 46.4
 
|-
 
| [[Reserve balances with F.R. Banks]] || align="right"| 13.0
 
|-
 
| [[Vault cash surplus]] || align="right"| 11.4
 
|-
 
| [[Currency]]<ref name="currency">Currency outside [[U.S. Treasury]], [[Federal Reserve Banks]] and the vaults of [[depository institutions]].</ref> || align="right"| 688.2
 
|- style="background:#efefef;font-weight:bold;" |
 
! Sum || align="right"| 759.0
 
|}
 
 
 
== United States Money Supply ==
 
 
 
This table shows the United States money supply as reported by the Fed on Sep 30, 2004.
 
 
 
{| border="1" cellpadding="2" cellspacing="0" align="center" width="400px"
 
|+''' Money Supply (billions of dollars)<br/>(not seasonally adjusted) ''' <ref>http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/H3/20040930/</ref> <ref>http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h6/20040930/</ref>
 
|-
 
! style="background:#efefef;" colspan="6" | M0 (not seasonally adjusted, not adjusted for changes in reserve requirements)
 
 
 
|-
 
| [[Currency]] (The diff between total reserves and the Monetary Base as reported in H.3) <ref name="currency"/> || align="right"| 674.4
 
 
 
|-
 
| Bank's total reserves at the Fed || align="right"| 46.1
 
 
 
|- style="font-weight: bold;"
 
| M0 (Monetary Base) || align="right"| 720.5
 
 
 
|-
 
! style="background:#efefef;" colspan="6" | M1
 
|-
 
| [[Demand Deposit]]s<ref>Demand deposits at domestically chartered commercial banks, U.S. branches and agencies of foreign banks, and [[Edge Act Corporation]]s (excluding those amounts held by depository institutions, the U.S. government, and foreign banks and official institutions) less cash items in the process of collection and Federal Reserve float.</ref> || align="right"| 321.0
 
|-
 
| [[Other checkable deposits|Other Checkable Deposits]]<ref>NOW and ATS balances.</ref> || align="right"| 319.5
 
 
 
|- style="font-weight: bold;"
 
| M1 (Monetary Base) || align="right"| 1,361.0
 
 
 
|-
 
! style="background:#efefef;" colspan="6" | M2
 
|-
 
| [[Savings deposit]]s<ref>Savings deposits include [[money market deposit accounts]].</ref> || align="right"| 3,472.5
 
|-
 
| [[Small-denomination time deposits]]<ref>Small-denomination time deposits are those issued in amounts of less than $100,000. All [[Individual Retirement Account|IRA]] and [[Keogh]] account balances at [[commercial banks]] and [[thrift]] institutions are subtracted from small time deposits.</ref> || align="right"| 795.6
 
|-
 
| [[Retail money fund]]s <ref>IRA and Keogh account balances at [[money market mutual funds]] are subtracted from [[retail money funds]].</ref> || align="right"| 729.5
 
|-
 
! style="background:#efefef;" colspan="6" | M3
 
|-
 
| [[Institutional money fund]]s || align="right"| 1,071.6
 
|-
 
| [[Large-denomination time deposits]]<ref>Large-denomination time deposits at [[domestically chartered commercial bank]]s, U.S. branches and agencies of foreign banks, and Edge Act Corporations, excluding those amounts held by [[depository institution]]s, the [[U.S. government]], foreign banks and [[official institution]]s, and [[money market mutual fund]]s.</ref> || align="right"| 1,018.2
 
|-
 
| [[Repurchase agreement]]s<ref>[[Repurchase agreement|RP]] liabilities of [[depository institution]]s, in denominations of $100,000 or more, on U.S. government and [[federal agency securities]], excluding those amounts held by [[depository institution]]s, the [[U.S. government]], foreign banks and [[official institution]]s, and [[money market mutual funds]].</ref> || align="right"| 537.3
 
|-
 
| [[Eurodollar]]s<ref>Eurodollars held by U.S. addressees at foreign branches of U.S. banks worldwide and at all banking offices in the [[United Kingdom]] and [[Canada]], excluding those amounts held by depository institutions, the U.S. government, foreign banks and official institutions, and by [[money market mutual funds]].</ref> || align="right"| 322.2
 
|- style="background:#efefef;font-weight:bold;" |
 
! Sum || align="right"| 9,311.7
 
|}
 
 
 
{| border="1" cellpadding="2" cellspacing="0" align="center" width="400px"
 
|+''' Comparable numbers (billions of dollars) (not seasonally adjusted) '''
 
|- style="background:#efefef;" |
 
! GDP (seasonally adjusted)<ref>http://www.federalreserve.gov/Releases/Z1/Current/accessible/f6.htm</ref> || align="right"| 11,643.0
 
|- style="background:#efefef;" |
 
! [[Credit market]] Debt Outstanding<ref>http://www.federalreserve.gov/Releases/Z1/Current/accessible/l1.htm</ref> || align="right"| 35,181.7
 
|- style="background:#efefef;" |
 
! [[Derivative (finance)|Derivatives]] (notional)<ref>http://www.occ.treas.gov/deriv/deriv.htm</ref> || align="right"| 79,400.0
 
|}
 
 
 
The only deposits that have "[[reserve requirements]]" are the M1 "[[checking deposits]]".
 
 
 
== Discontinuance of M3 Publication Data ==
 
 
 
In a press release dated 10 November, 2005, the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System announced that it would cease publication of the M3 monetary aggregate.<ref>http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h6/discm3.htm</ref> The Board stated that M3 "does not appear to convey any additional information about economic activity that is not already embodied in M2," and that the decision was reached largely because "the costs of collecting the underlying data and publishing M3 outweigh the benefits."
 
 
 
== Latest US M3 numbers ==
 
 
 
According to the last published data from 16 March, 2005, M3 has been growing at an annual rate of over 8.22%.<ref>https://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/data/M3.txt</ref> As of 16th March 2006 M3 was $10.34 trillion.  One year earlier, on 14th March 2005 the M3 was $9.55 trillion.
 
 
 
==Controlling money supply by issuing debt==
 
The government can control the growth of M3 through the issuance of new Government [[treasury securities|debt instruments]].  Money which is re-invested back into US Government debt—such as treasury bonds and treasury bills—ceases to be part of M3.  Thus, if a government wishes to slow the growth of M3, and thus prevent the economy from overheating, it can raise interest rates, and, therefore, withdraw money from M3 and transfer it into Government debt.  Between 14, March 2005 and 16, March 2006 total US National Debt rose by 6.71% from $7.75 trillion to $8.27 trillion.  These figures inform us that the actual issuance of money exceeded the increase in M3.
 
In March of 2006, the US Congress agreed to raise the [[U.S. public debt|National Debt Ceiling]] an additional $781 billion and, thus, prevent a first-ever default on US Treasury notes.<ref>http://news.yahoo.com/s/cpress/20060317/ca_pr_on_wo/us_deeper_in_debt</ref>  As of 15 April, 2006, The National Debt Ceiling stands at just under $9 trillion.
 
 
 
==ECB Target==
 
The [[European Central Bank]] has set a target rate of 4.5% for M3 growth but has overshot that target by almost double since the inception of the Euro.<ref>http://www.ecb.int/home/html/index.en.html</ref>
 
 
 
=== Expanding the paper money supply ===
 
See also [[inflation]].
 
 
 
Historically money was a metal (gold, silver, copper, etc,) or other object that was difficult to duplicate, but easy to transport and divide. Later it consisted of paper notes, now issued by all modern governments.  With the rise of modern industrial capitalism it has gone through several phases including but not limited to:
 
 
 
#Bank notes - paper issued by banks as an interest-bearing loan. (These were common in the 19th century but not seen anymore.)
 
#Paper notes, coins with varying amounts of precious metal (usually called [[legal tender]]) issued by various governments. There is also a near-money in the form of interest bearing bonds issued by governments with solid credit ratings.
 
#Bank credit through the creation of chequable deposits in the granting of various loans to business, government and individuals. (It is critical that we understand that when a bank makes a loan, that is ''new'' money and when a loan is paid off that money is destroyed.  Only the interest paid on it remains.)
 
 
 
Thus, all debt denominated in dollars — mortgages, money markets, credit card debt, travelers cheques — is money. However, the creation of dollar-denominated debt (or any generic obligation) creates money only when a bank (as opposed to a credit card
 
company) is granting the debt. "High powered" money (M0) is created when the elected government spends money
 
into the economy.  The money created in the bank loan process is bank money and these
 
two forms of money trade at par one with the other.  Banks are limited in the amount
 
of loans they can grant and thus in the amount of bank money (credit) they can
 
create by both the net assets of the bank and by reserve requirements (M0).
 
For most intents and purposes the aggregate of M0 multiplied by the reserve requirement
 
will be an indicator of (but this is somewhat greater than) the aggregate of loans.  If additional money is needed in the
 
banking system to allow more loans the Federal Reserve will create money by purchasing Bonds or
 
T-bills with money created from the other.  No matter who sells the bonds the
 
money will end up in the banking system as M0.  The Fed could purchase lolly pops
 
if that would accomplish the purpose of expansion better than a purchase of
 
Bonds.
 
 
 
=== Shrinking the paper money supply ===
 
See also [[deflation]].
 
 
 
Perhaps the most obvious way money can be destroyed is if paper bills are burned or taken out of circulation by the central bank. But, it should be remembered that legal tender usually constitutes less than 4% of the broad [[money supply]].
 
 
 
Current banking systems are based on fractional reserves so money can be destroyed if depositers withdraw funds from a bank.  When money is withdrawn it can no longer be used for lending and just as the fractional reserve system gives leverage to the creation of money, it also gives leverage to the destruction of money. Bank [[savings]] are actually a kind of loans &mdash; savers loan their money to a  bank at a low interest rate or merely in exchange for the benefit of convenience or its security (accepting that they lose a small amount of value to inflation). The bank may use this loan to manage its liabilities (its deposit liabilities created by loans).  It must be recalled that the federal reserve banking system is ''mostly'' a closed system.  A check written on bank A gets deposited in Bank B and a check written on bank B gets deposited in Bank C and a check on bank C gets deposited in bank A. On a good day very little borrowing needs to be done because a bank gets as much in new deposits as it does in paid out funds.  Even if a bank is short of reserves it can borrow the reserves from another bank at the ''discount'' rate.
 
 
 
Another way money can be destroyed is when any bank loan is paid off or any government bond or T-Bill is purchased by the private sector. The money value of the contract or bond is destroyed &mdash; taken out of circulation.  If a bank loan is [[default (finance)|defaulted]] upon then the "interest" paid by other borrowers will be employed to cover the default.  A very large part of the "interest" paid on bank loans is actually a finance charge employed to cover bad loans.  The group of good borrowers pay the loan instead of the original borrower.  In cases where the default is huge such as loans to foreign governments Fed intervention has, in the past, rescued the banks.  In this instance it would seem that the taxpayers and/or money holders (savers) will pay the debt.  The effects on the money supply will be controlled, again, by the level of bond purchase or redemption or the level of T-Bill sales or purchases by the Treasury.
 
 
 
In extreme forms, a [[bank run]] or panic may drive a bank into [[insolvency]] and, if uninsured, the savings of all its [[deposit]]ors are lost. Such bank failures were a major cause of the tremendous contraction in the money supply that occurred during the [[Great Depression]], particularly in the United States. In that country many [[bank reform|banking reforms]] were subsequently enacted during the [[New Deal]], including the creation of the [[Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation]] to guarantee private bank deposits.
 
 
 
===Articles and books===
 
* [http://chevallier.turgot.org/a363-Monetary_creation_aggregates_and_GDP_growth.html  '''Monetary creation, aggregates and GDP growth'''] On the inverse relation between Excess Money Supply and Growth. - '' J.P. Chevallier''
 
 
 
==Notes and references==
 
<div class="references-small">
 
<references />
 
</div>
 
  
 
==External links==
 
==External links==
===Data===
 
 
*[http://www.bullandbearwise.com/MoneySupplyChart.asp Trailing Five-Year U.S. Money Supply Chart]
 
*[http://www.bullandbearwise.com/MoneySupplyChart.asp Trailing Five-Year U.S. Money Supply Chart]
 
*[http://www.bullandbearwise.com/MoneySupplyChgChart.asp Trailing Five-Year U.S. Money Supply Rate of Change Chart]
 
*[http://www.bullandbearwise.com/MoneySupplyChgChart.asp Trailing Five-Year U.S. Money Supply Rate of Change Chart]
*[http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h3/Current/h3.htm Aggregate Reserves Of Depository Institutions And The Monetary Base (H.3)]
 
 
*[http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h6/hist/h6hist1.txt U.S. M1,M2 Money Supply Historical Table]
 
*[http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h6/hist/h6hist1.txt U.S. M1,M2 Money Supply Historical Table]
 
*[http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h6/current/h6.htm Money Stock Measures (H.6)]
 
*[http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h6/current/h6.htm Money Stock Measures (H.6)]
*[http://www.rba.gov.au/Statistics/AlphaListing/alpha_listing_m.html Data on Monetary Aggregates in Australia]
 
 
===Articles===
 
 
*[http://www.frbsf.org/education/activities/drecon/2001/0111.html Do all banks hold reserves, and, if so, where do they hold them? (11/2001)]
 
*[http://www.frbsf.org/education/activities/drecon/2001/0111.html Do all banks hold reserves, and, if so, where do they hold them? (11/2001)]
 
*[http://www.frbsf.org/education/activities/drecon/2001/0108.html What effect does a change in the reserve requirement have on the money supply? (08/2001)]
 
*[http://www.frbsf.org/education/activities/drecon/2001/0108.html What effect does a change in the reserve requirement have on the money supply? (08/2001)]
*[http://research.stlouisfed.org/aggreg/ St. Louis Fed: Monetary Aggregates]
 
 
*[http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/MoneySupply.html Anna J. Schwartz on money supply]
 
*[http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/MoneySupply.html Anna J. Schwartz on money supply]
*[http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h6/discm3.htm Discontinuance of M3 Publication]
 
 
 
  
 
{{credit1|Money_supply|87810786|}}
 
{{credit1|Money_supply|87810786|}}

Revision as of 19:58, 19 December 2006


Money supply, "monetary aggregates" or "money stock" is a macroeconomic concept defining the quantity of money available within a nation’s economy used to purchase economic goods, services, and financial securities. The monetary sector of a nation’s economy, as opposed to its real sector, concerns the money market. The same tools of analysis can be applied to this market as can be applied to other goods markets: supply and demand result in an equilibrium price, which defines the interest rate and quantity of real money balances.


Banknotes and Coinage

When thinking about a nation’s "supply" of money, it is natural to think of the total of banknotes and coins in an economy. However in many countries, these do not calculate into a nation’s total money supply. For instance, in the United States, coins are minted by the United States Mint, part of the United States Department of the Treasury, which lies outside of the U.S. Federal Reserve. Banknotes are printed by the Bureau of Engraving & Printing on behalf of the Federal Reserve as symbolic tokens of electronic credit-based money that has already been created or issued by private banks. The term private bank as used here refers to a bank that is not government owned.

In this respect, all banknotes in existence are systematically linked to the expansion of the electronic credit-based money supply. However, coinage can be increased or decreased outside this system by Legal Mandate or Legislative Acts. During most periods the coin base is held in check and used as a complementary system rather than a competitive system with private bank issues of electronic credit-based money. The common practice is to include printed and minted money supply in the same metric, define as M0.

Money Supply

The more accurate starting point for the concept of the money supply is the total of all electronic credit-based deposit balances held in financial accounts plus all the minted coins and printed paper. The M1 money supply consists of all noted and minted monies, or M0, plus the total of non-paper or coin deposit balances without any withdrawal restrictions. Restricted accounts of which one cannot write checks on are put in the next level of liquidity, defined by money supply M2.

The relationship between the M0 and M1 money supplies is the money multiplier which defines the ratio of cash and coin in people's wallets and bank vaults and ATMs to total balances in their financial accounts. The gap and lag between the two money supplies occurs because of the system of fractional reserve banking, referring to a banking practice where more money is issued than what is held by the central bank in reserves. The U.S. Federal Reserve Board maintains such a system.

Because, in principle, money is anything that can be used in the settlement of a debt, there are varying measures of the money supply. The most restrictive measures count only those forms of money available for immediate transactions, while broader measures include money held as a store of value.

The United States

U.S. Money Supply from 1959-2006

Under the U.S. Federal Reserve, the most common measures of money supply are termed M0, M1, M2, and M3. The Federal Reserve defines such measures as follows:

  • M0: The total of all physical currency, plus accounts at the central bank which can be exchanged for physical currency.
  • M1: Measure M0 + the amount in demand accounts, including "checking" or "current" accounts.
  • M2: Measure M1 + most savings accounts, money market accounts, and certificate of deposit accounts, or CDs, of under $100,000.
  • M3: Measure M2 + all other CDs, deposits of eurodollars and repurchase agreements.

The U.S. government can control the growth of M3 through the issuance of new Government debt instruments. Money which is re-invested back into U.S. Government debt, including treasury bonds and treasury bills, ceases to be part of M3. Thus, if a government wishes to slow the growth of M3, it can raise interest rates, therefore withdrawing money from M3 and transferring it into Government debt.

The United Kingdom

Within the United Kingdom, there are just two official money supply measures. M0, which is referred to as the "wide monetary base" or "narrow money", and M4, which is referred to as "broad money" or simply "the money supply". These measures are defined as such:

  • M0: All cash outside the Bank of England + private banks' operational deposits with the Bank of England.
  • M4: All cash outside banking institutes, either in circulation with the public and non-bank firms, + private-sector retail bank and building society deposits + private-sector wholesale bank and building society deposits and certificates of deposits.

Monetary Exchange Equation

A nation’s money supply is important because it is linked to price inflation by the "monetary exchange equation", which follows:

Within this equation:

  • Velocity = The number of times per year that money changes hands.
  • Real GDP = Nominal Gross Domestic Product / GDP deflator.
  • GDP Deflator = A Measure of inflation, whereas the money supply may be less than or greater than the demand of money in the economy.

If the money supply grows faster than the growth of real GDP, described as "unproductive debt expansion", inflation is likely to follow. While followers of the monetarist school of economics presume that velocity is relatively stable, velocity in fact exhibits variability at business-cycle frequencies, so that the velocity equation is not particularly useful as a short run tool. Moreover, in the U.S., velocity has grown at an average of slightly more than 1% per year between 1959 and 2005.

Basic Inflation Identity

Inflation is inherently linked with the percentage change of both the rate of money growth and the change in velocity. It also accounts for the rate of output growth. In analyzing percentage changes, a percentage change in product XY is equal to the sum of the percentage changes %X + %Y. This follows:

%P + %Y = %M + %V

Rearranged, this equation provides the "basic inflation identity", which follows:

%P = %M + %V - %Y

According to the basic inflation identity, inflation (%P) is equal to the rate of money growth (%M), plus the change in velocity (%V), minus the rate of output growth (%Y).

Expanding the Money Supply

Historically, money was defined in terms of metal, and included gold, silver, and copper. Money also constituted other objects that were difficult to duplicate, but easy to transport and divide. Later, money consisted of paper notes, which are now issued by all modern governments. With the rise of modern industrial capitalism, money has gone through several phases including but not limited to; bank notes including paper issued by banks as an interest-bearing loan that common to the 19th century, and paper notes consisting of coins with varying amounts of precious metal, termed legal tender, that are issued by various governments. There is also a near-money in the form of interest bearing bonds issued by governments with solid credit ratings. Money has also consisted of bank credit through the creation of checkable deposits in the granting of various loans to business, government and individuals.

Thus, all debt denominated in dollars, including mortgages, money markets, credit card debt, and travelers checke, is money. However, the creation of dollar-denominated debt, or any generic obligation, creates money only when a bank is granting the debt. "High powered" money, or M0, is created when the elected government spends money into the economy. The money created in the bank loan process is termed bank money. These forms of money trade at par one with the other. Banks are limited in the amount of loans they can grant and thus in the amount of bank money or credit they can create by both the net assets of the bank and by reserve requirements. For most intents and purposes the aggregate of M0 multiplied by the reserve requirement will be an indicator of the aggregate of loans. If additional money is needed in the banking system to allow more loans, the central bank will create money by purchasing bonds or T-bills with money created from the other. No matter who sells the bonds the money will end up in the banking system as M0.

Shrinking the Money Supply

Perhaps the most obvious way money can be destroyed is if paper bills are burned or taken out of circulation by the central bank. But, it should be remembered that legal tender usually constitutes less than 4% of the broad money supply.

Current banking systems are based on fractional reserves so money can be destroyed if depositors withdraw funds from a bank. When money is withdrawn it can no longer be used for lending and just as the fractional reserve system gives leverage to the creation of money, it also gives leverage to the destruction of money. Bank savings are actually a kind of loans; savers loan their money to a bank at a low interest rate or merely in exchange for the benefit of convenience or its security, accepting that they lose a small amount of value to inflation. The bank may use this loan to manage its deposit liabilities.

Another way money can be destroyed is when any bank loan is paid off or any government bond or T-Bill is purchased by the private sector. The money value of the contract or bond is destroyed when taken out of circulation. If a bank loan is defaulted upon then the "interest" paid by other borrowers will be employed to cover the default. A very large part of the "interest" paid on bank loans is actually a finance charge employed to cover bad loans. A group of good borrowers pay the loan instead of the original borrower. In cases where the default is large such as loans to foreign governments Federal intervention has, in the past, rescued the banks. In this instance it would seem that the taxpayers and/or money holders will pay the debt. The effects on the money supply will be controlled, again, by the level of bond purchase or redemption or the level of T-Bill sales or purchases by the Treasury.

In extreme forms, a bank run or panic may drive a bank into insolvency and, if uninsured, the savings of all its depositors are lost. Such bank failures were a major cause of the tremendous contraction in the money supply that occurred during the Great Depression, particularly in the United States. In that country many banking reforms were subsequently enacted during the New Deal, including the creation of the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation to guarantee private bank deposits.

Central Bank Policies

When a central bank is "easing", it triggers an increase in money supply by purchasing government bonds, or securities, on the open market thus increasing available funds for private banks to loan through fractional reserve banking , which is the issue of new money through loans. This proves to increase the money supply. When the central bank is "tightening", it slows the process of private bank issue by selling securities on the open market and pulling money out of the private banking sector. It reduces or increases the supply of short term government debt, and inversely increases or reduces the supply of lending funds and thereby the ability of private banks to issue new money through debt.

The operative notion of easy money is that the central bank creates new bank reserves which let the banks lend out more money. These loans get spent, and the proceeds get deposited at other banks. Whatever is not required to be held as reserves is then lent out again, and through the "money multiplier", loans and bank deposits will increase by many times the initial injection of reserves.

In the 1970’s, central bank reserve requirements on deposit started to fall with the emergence of money market funds, which require no holding of reserves. In the early 1990’s, reserve requirements were dropped to zero on savings deposits, CDs, and Eurocurrency deposits. At present, reserve requirements apply only to "transactions deposits", which include mainly checking accounts. The vast majority of funding sources used by private banks to create loans have nothing to do with bank reserves and in effect create what is known as "moral hazard" and speculative bubble economies.

These days, commercial and industrial loans are financed by issuing large denomination CDs. Money market deposits are largely used to lend to corporations who issue commercial paper. Consumer loans are also made using savings deposits which are not subject to reserve requirements. These loans can be bunched into securities and sold to somebody else, taking them off of the bank's books.

Over time, commercial, industrial and consumer loans have ceased to link with bank reserves. Since 1995, the volume of such loans has exploded, while bank reserves have declined.

Policy Criticism

One of the principal jobs of central banks, such as the U.S. Federal Reserve, the Bank of England and the European Central Bank, is to keep money supply growth in line with real GDP growth. Central banks do this primarily by targeting some inter-bank interest rate. In the United States, this is the federal funds rate obtained through the use of open market operations.

A very common criticism of this target policy is that "real GDP growth" is, in fact, meaningless and since GDP can grow for many reasons including manmade disasters and crises, is not correlated with any known means of measurement well-being. The policy use of GDP figures is considered to be an abuse, and a common solution proposed by such critics is that a nation’s money supply should be kept in line with a more ecological, social and human mean of well-being. In theory, money supply would expand when well-being is improving, and contract when well-being is decreasing. Proponents believe this policy to give all parties in the economy a direct interest in improving well-being.

This argument must be balanced against what is nearly dogma among economists: that the control of inflation is the main job of a central bank, and that any introduction of non-financial means of measuring well-being has an inevitable domino effect of increasing government spending and diluting capital.

Currency integration is thought by some economists, including Robert Mundell, to alleviate this problem by ensuring that currencies become less competitive in the commodity markets, and that a wider political base be employed in the setting of currency and inflation and well-being policy. This thinking is in part the basis of the Euro currency integration within the European Union.

Some economists argue for the money supply to remain constant at all times. With growth in production, this would result in falling prices. A constant money supply will keep nominal incomes constant over time; however falling prices will lead to an increase in real incomes. Due to such confliction, policy regarding a nation’s money supply remains one of the most controversial aspects of economics itself.

Sources

External links

Credits

New World Encyclopedia writers and editors rewrote and completed the Wikipedia article in accordance with New World Encyclopedia standards. This article abides by terms of the Creative Commons CC-by-sa 3.0 License (CC-by-sa), which may be used and disseminated with proper attribution. Credit is due under the terms of this license that can reference both the New World Encyclopedia contributors and the selfless volunteer contributors of the Wikimedia Foundation. To cite this article click here for a list of acceptable citing formats.The history of earlier contributions by wikipedians is accessible to researchers here:

The history of this article since it was imported to New World Encyclopedia:

Note: Some restrictions may apply to use of individual images which are separately licensed.