Difference between revisions of "Austrian school of economics" - New World Encyclopedia

From New World Encyclopedia
({{Contracted}})
Line 3: Line 3:
 
{{Claimed}}{{Started}}{{Contracted}}
 
{{Claimed}}{{Started}}{{Contracted}}
  
The '''Austrian School''', also known as “the Vienna School” and as “the Psychological School,” is a school of [[history of economic thought|economic thought]] that advocates adherence to strict [[methodological individualism]]. As a result Austrians hold that the only valid economic theory is logically derived from basic principles of human action.  Alongside the formal approach to theory, often called [[praxeology]], the school has traditionally advocated an interpretive approach to history. The praxeological method allows for the discovery of economic laws valid for all human action, while the interpretive approach addresses specific historical events.
 
  
This [[Aristotelian]]/[[rationalist]] approach differs both from the currently dominant [[Platonic idealism|Platonic]]/[[logical positivism|positivist]] approach of contemporary [[neo-classical economics]] and the once dominant [[Historicism|historical approach]] of the German [[historical school of economics|historical school]] and the American [[institutional economics|institutionalists]].
 
While the praxeological method differs from the current method advocated by the majority of contemporary economists, the Austrian method is essentially identical with the traditional approach to economics used by the British [[Classical economics|classical economists]], the early continental economists, and the [[Scholasticism|Late Scholastics]]. The Austrian methodology is, therefore, a continuation of a long line of economic thought stretching from the 15th century to the modern era and including such major economists as [[Richard Cantillon]], [[David Hume]], [[Anne Robert Jacques Turgot, Baron de Laune|A.R.J. Turgot]], [[Adam Smith]], [[Jean-Baptiste Say]], [[David Ricardo]], [[Nassau Senior]], [[John Elliott Cairnes]], and [[Claude Frédéric Bastiat]].
 
  
The most famous Austrian adherents are [[Carl Menger]], [[Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk]], [[Friedrich von Wieser]], [[Ludwig von Mises]], [[Friedrich Hayek]], [[Joseph Schumpeter]], [[Gottfried von Haberler]], [[Murray Rothbard]], [[Israel Kirzner]], [[George Reisman]], [[Henry Hazlitt]], and [[Hans-Hermann Hoppe]]. While often controversial, and standing to some extent outside of the mainstream of neoclassical theory — as well as being staunchly opposed to much of [[John Maynard Keynes|Keynes]]' [[Keynesian economics|theory]] and its results — the Austrian School has been widely influential because of its emphasis on the creative phase  (i.e. the time element) of economic productivity and its questioning of the basis of the behavioral theory underlying [[neoclassical economics]].
+
==Historical Overview==
  
Because many of the policy recommendations of Austrian theorists call for [[minarchism|small government]], strict protection of private property, and support for [[individualism]] in general, they are often cited by [[laissez-faire liberal]], [[libertarian]], and [[Objectivism (Ayn Rand)|Objectivist]] groups for support, although Austrian School economists, like Ludwig von Mises, insist that ''praxeology'' must be [[positive economics|value-free]].  They do not answer the question "should this policy be implemented?," but rather "if this policy is implemented, will it have the effects you intend?."
+
=== Main Personalities and their Ideals ===
  
==History==
+
The story of the Austrian School begins in the fifteenth century, when the followers of St. Thomas Aquinas, writing and teaching at the University of Salamanca in Spain, sought to explain the full range of human action and social organization.
[[Classical economics]] focused on the exchange theory of value. In the late 19th century, however, attention was focused on the concepts of “marginal” cost and value (see [[Marginalism]]). Carl Menger's 1871 book, ''[[Principles of Economics]]'', is considered one of the crucial works that began the period known as [[neoclassical economics]]. While marginalism was generally influential, there was also a more specific school that grew up around Menger, which came to be known as the “Vienna School,” “Austrian School,” or “Psychological School.
 
  
Austrian economics is currently closely associated with the advocacy of ''[[laissez-faire]]'' views. Earlier Austrian economists were more skeptical compared to later economists such as [[Ludwig von Mises]] and [[Karel Engliš]], with [[Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk]] saying that he feared unbridled competition would lead to “anarchism in production and consumption.” However, the Austrian School, especially through the works of [[Friedrich Hayek]], would be influential in the revival of ''laissez-faire'' thought in the 1980s.
+
These Late Scholastics observed the existence of economic law, inexorable forces of cause and effect that operate very much as other natural laws. Over the course of several generations, they discovered and explained the laws of supply and demand, the cause of inflation, the operation of foreign exchange rates, and the subjective nature of economic value—all reasons [[Joseph Schumpeter]] celebrated them as the first real economists.
  
The school originated in [[Vienna]] and owes its name to members of the [[Historical School]] of [[economics]], who argued against the Austrians during the ''[[Methodenstreit]]'', in which the Austrians defended the reliance that [[classical economics|classical economists]] placed upon deductive logic. Their Prussian opponents derisively named them the “Austrian School” to emphasize a departure from mainstream German thought and to suggest a provincial approach. (The name “Psychological School” derived from the effort to found marginalism upon prior considerations, largely psychological.)
+
The Late Scholastics were advocates of property rights and the freedom to contract and trade. They celebrated the contribution of business to society, while doggedly opposing taxes, price controls, and regulations that inhibited enterprise. As moral theologians, they urged governments to obey ethical strictures against theft and murder. And they lived up to [[Ludwig von Mises]]'s rule: the first job of an economist is to tell governments what they cannot do.
  
Menger was closely followed by [[Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk]] and [[Friedrich von Wieser]]. [[Austria]]n economists developed a sense of themselves as a school distinct from [[neoclassical economics]] during the [[economic calculation debate]], with [[Ludwig von Mises]] and [[Friedrich von Hayek]] representing the Austrian position, where they contended that without monetary prices and private property, meaningful economic calculation is impossible.
+
The dominant British-French tradition   Jevons and Richard Cantillon  ( Essay on the Nature of Commerce, 1730) who were followed by Anne Robert Jacques Turgot, the pro-market French aristocrat whose paper "Value and Money" spelled out the origins of money, and the nature of economic choice  received its first serious challenge in many years when [[Carl Menger]]'s Principles of Economics was published in 1871.
  
The Austrian economists were the first liberal economists to systematically challenge the [[Marxist]] school. This was partly a reaction to the ''[[Methodenstreit]]'' when they attacked the [[Georg Wilhelm Friedrich Hegel|Hegelian]] doctrines of the [[Historical School]]. Though many Marxist authors have attempted to portray the Austrian school as a ''[[bourgeois]]'' reaction to Marx, such an interpretation is implausible: Menger wrote his ''[[Principles of Economics]]'' at almost the same time as [[Karl Marx|Marx]] was working upon ''[[Das Kapital]]'', whose second and third volumes were published more than ten and twenty years, respectively, after ''Principles''. (However, this does not refute the weaker claim that marginalism received the attention it did in the 1880s, and not earlier, in part because it was seen as an answer to Marx.) The Austrian economists were, nonetheless, amongst the first to clash directly with Marxism, since both dealt with such subjects as money, [[capital (economics)|capital]], [[business cycle]]s, and economic processes. Böhm-Bawerk wrote extensive critiques of Marx in the 1880s and 1890s, and several prominent Marxists — including [[Rudolf Hilferding]] — attended his seminar in 1905–6. In contrast, the classical economists had shown little interest in such topics, and many of them did not even gain familiarity with Marx's ideas until well into the twentieth century.
+
==Austrian School Proper==
  
The school was no longer centered in Austria after [[Hitler]] came to power. Austrian economics was ill-thought of by most economists after [[World War II]] because it rejected observational methods. Its reputation has lately risen with work by students of [[Israel Kirzner]] and [[Ludwig Lachmann]], as well as a renewed interest in Hayek after he won the [[Bank of Sweden Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel]]. However, it remains a distinctly minority position, even in such areas as capital value.{{Fact|date=February 2007}}
+
===History===
 +
 +
By way of general fascination over Principles of Economics, Menger (1840-1921) then became the founder of the Austrian School proper, resurrected the Scholastic-French approach to economics, and put it on firmer ground.
  
Austrian economics can be broken into two general trends. One, exemplified by Hayek, while distrusting many neoclassical concepts, generally accepts the neoclassical formulations; the other, exemplified by the [[Ludwig von Mises Institute]], seeks a different formalism for [[economics]]. The first primary area of contention between neoclassical theory and the Austrian school is over the possibility of consumer indifference — neoclassical theory says it is possible, whereas Mises rejected it as being “impossible to observe in practice.” The second major dispute arose when Mises and his students argued that utility functions are [[ordinal number|ordinal]], and not [[cardinal number|cardinal]]; that is, the Austrians contend that one can only rank preferences and cannot measure their intensity, in direct opposition to the neoclassical view. Finally there are a host of questions about uncertainty raised by Mises and other Austrians, who argue for a different means of [[risk assessment]].
+
In addition, Menger showed how money originates in a free market when the most marketable commodity is desired, not for consumption, but for use in trading for other goods.
  
The influence that Austrian school ideas have had on Keynesian [[macroeconomics]] is often overlooked. Keynes himself acknowledged being exposed to the Misesian notion that “nominal” values could have “real” effects. A further source of this influence is the period of time when the [[London School of Economics]] brought in Hayek and other “continental” economists. While their students, though initially receptive, ultimately were drawn to the new Keynesian doctrines, many of the Hayekian concepts, particularly those relating time to the value of capital and its importance, would find their way into the work of Keynesians, especially by way of [[John Hicks]] (who, while distancing himself from Keynesianism, nonetheless made the most influential attempt to formalize it).
+
Menger's book was a pillar of the "marginalist revolution" in the history of economic science. When Mises said it "made an economist" out of him, he was not only referring to Menger's theory of money and prices, but also his approach to the discipline itself. Like his predecessors in the tradition, Menger was a classical liberal and methodological individualist, viewing economics as the science of individual choice. His Investigations, which came out twelve years later, battled the German Historical School, which rejected theory and saw economics as the accumulation of data in service of the state.
  
[[Alan Greenspan]], speaking of the originators of the School, said in 2000, “the Austrian school have reached far into the future from when most of them practiced and have had a profound and, in my judgment, probably an irreversible effect on how most mainstream economists think in this country.” The long-time [[U.S. Federal Reserve]] Chairman said he attended a seminar hosted by Ludwig von Mises.[http://www.usagold.com/gildedopinion/greenspan-gold.html]
+
As professor of economics at the University of Vienna, Menger restored economics as the science of human action based on deductive logic, and prepared the way for later theorists to counter the influence of socialist thought. Indeed, his student [[Friederich von Wiese]] (1851-1926) strongly influenced Friedrich von Hayek's later writings. Menger's work remains an excellent introduction to the economic way of thinking. At some level, every Austrian since has seen himself as a student of Menger.
  
==Analytical framework==
+
The "First" Generation of the Austrian School was thus composed of a pair Austrian professors who, although not directly students of Menger, were nonetheless heavily influenced by him: [[Friedrich von Wieser]] and [[Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk]] (1851-1914). Boehm-Bawerk's Positive Theory of Capital demonstrated that the normal rate of business profit is the interest rate. Capitalists save money, pay laborers, and wait until the final product is sold to receive profit. In addition, he demonstrated that capital is not homogeneous but an intricate and diverse structure that has a time dimension. A growing economy is not just a consequence of increased capital investment, but also of longer and longer processes of production. His History and Critique of Interest Theories, appearing in 1884, is a sweeping account of fallacies in the history of thought and a firm defense of the idea that the interest rate is not an artificial construct but an inherent part of the market. It reflects the universal fact of "time preference," the tendency of people to prefer satisfaction of wants sooner rather than later .  
Austrian economists reject statistical methods and artificially constructed experiments as tools applicable to economics, saying that while it is appropriate in the natural sciences where factors can be isolated in laboratory conditions, acting human beings are too complex for this treatment. Instead one should isolate the logical processes of human action - a discipline named "[[praxeology]]" by [[Alfred Espinas]].
 
  
Austrians view [[entrepreneurship]] as the driving force in [[economic development]], see [[private property]] as essential to the efficient use of resources, and usually (if not always) see [[government]] interference in market processes as counterproductive.
+
Boehm-Bawerk and von Wiesel, for the most part, spread the Austrian School gospel throughout the Austro-Hungarian Empire and trained the next two generations. These later generations were dominated by the figures of [[Ludwig von Mises]] (1881-1973) in the second generation  of “Austrian School of Economics” and, in the third generation, by [[Friedrich von Hayek]] (1889-1992).
  
As with neoclassical economists, Austrians reject [[classical economics|classical]] cost of production theories, most famously the [[labor theory of value]]. Instead they [[Subjective theory of value|explain value by reference to the subjective preferences of individuals]]. This psychological aspect to Menger's economics has been attributed to the school's birth in turn of the century [[Vienna]]. [[Supply and demand]] are explained by aggregating over the decisions of individuals, following the precepts of [[methodological individualism]], which asserts that only individuals and not collectives make decisions, and [[marginalist]] arguments, which compare the costs and benefits for incremental changes.
+
One area where Boehm-Bawerk had not elaborated on the analysis of Menger was money, the institutional intersection of the "micro" and "macro" approach. This time, young Mises, economic advisor to the Austrian Chamber of Commerce, took on the challenge. The result of Mises's research was The Theory of Money and Credit, published in 1912. He spelled out how the theory of marginal utility applies to money, and laid out his "regression theorem," showing that money not only originates in the market, but must always do so. Drawing on the British Currency School, Knut Wicksell's theory of interest rates, and Boehm-Bawerk's theory of the structure of production, Mises presented the broad outline of the Austrian theory of the business cycle.
  
Contemporary neo-Austrian economists claim to adopt [[economic subjectivism]] more consistently than any other school of economics and reject many neoclassical formalisms. For example, while neoclassical economics formalizes the economy as an [[economic equilibrium|equilibrium]] system with supply and demand in balance, Austrian economists emphasize its dynamic, perpetually dis-equilibrated nature.
 
  
The core of the Austrian framework can be summarized as taking a subjectivist approach to marginal economics, and a focus on the idea that logical consistency of a theory is more important that any interpretation of empirical observations. Austrians focus completely on the [[opportunity cost]] of goods, as opposed to balancing downside or disutility costs. It is an Austrian assertion that everyone is ''better'' off in a mutually voluntary exchange, or they would not have carried it out. A fuller explanation of this in more exact terms is [http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/margrev/oppcost.htm available at the New School's economic pages].
+
==Major Features of the Austrian School as the Opposition to other Economic Theories==
 +
===Methodological Subjectivism===
 +
A radically "subjectivist" strain of  [[Neoclassical marginalist economics]] (versus [[Classical School]]) : An individual's actions and choices are based upon a unique value scale known only to that individual. It is this subjective valuation of goods that creates economic value. Like other economists, the Austrian does not judge or criticize these subjective values but instead takes them as given data. But unlike other economists, the Austrian never attempts to measure or put these values in mathematical form. The idea that an individual's values, plans, expectations, and understanding of reality are all subjective permeates the Austrian tradition and, along with an emphasis on change or processes, is the basis for their notion of economic efficiency.
 +
===Methodologogical Individualism===
 +
A dedication to a prioristic "pure" theory, with an emphasis on "methodological individualism" (versus [[German Historical School]]):
 +
Economics, to an Austrian economist, is the study of purposeful human action in its broadest sense. Since only individuals act, the focus of study for the Austrian economist is always on the individual. Although Austrian economists are not alone in their methodological individualism, they do not stress the maximizing behavior of individuals in the same way as mainstream neoclassical economists. Austrian economists believe that one can never know if humans have maximized benefits or minimized costs. Austrian economists emphasize instead the process by which market participants gain information and form their expectations in order to lead them to their own idea of a best solution.  
 +
After the 1871 presentation of his revolutionary subjective theory of value, Carl Menger was challenged by [[Gustav Schmoller]] and the recurrent debate on method (methodenstreit) which ensued between them and their followers divided the German-speaking world neatly: Austria and its universities for the Austrian School; Germany and its universities for the [[German Historical School]].  
 +
===Antitrust Behaviour===
 +
The theory of alternative cost which reduces all goods and factors, by "imputation", to the subjective valuation of consumer goods (versus [[Classical School]] and [[Marshallian Neoclassicals]]):
 +
 +
The neoclassical economic theory of perfect competition defines a competitive market as one in which there are a large number of small firms, all selling a homogeneous good and possessing perfect knowledge. The structure of the market, according to this analysis, determines the competitiveness of a market. But Austrian economists Friedrich A. Hayek and Israel M. Kirzner have rejected this theory of competition.  
  
This focus on opportunity cost alone means that their interpretation of the [[time value]] of a good has a strict relationship: since goods will be as restricted by scarcity at a later point in time as they are now, the strict relationship between investment and time must also hold. A factory making goods next year is worth as much less as the goods it is making next year are worth. This means that the business cycle is driven by miscoordination between sectors of the same economy, caused by money not carrying incentive information correct about present choices, rather than within a single economy where money causes people to make bad decisions about how to spend their time.
+
According to Hayek there is no competition in the neoclassical theory of perfect competition. Competition to an Austrian economist is defined simply as rivalrous behavior, and to compete is to attempt to offer a better deal than one's competitors.  
  
==Contributions==
+
Competition in the market arises out of one firm distinguishing its products in some way from those of other firms. And because firms in the real world do not have perfect knowledge, they do not know what a successful competitive strategy is until they try it.
Some contributions of Austrian economists:
+
 
*A theory of distribution in which factor [[price]]s result from the [[imputation (economics)|imputation]] of prices of consumer goods to goods of "higher order," that is goods used in the production of consumer goods (goods of the first order).
+
"'''''Competition is'''''", therefore, as Hayek explains, a "'''''discovery procedure'''''." As each firm attempts to do better than all other firms, the knowledge of what consumers actually want in the market is discovered.
*An emphasis on the forward-looking nature of choice, seeing time as the root of uncertainty within economics (see also [[time preference]]).
+
*A fundamental rejection of mathematical methods in economics seeing the function of economics as investigating the essences rather than the specific quantities of economic phenomena. This was seen as an evolutionary, or "genetic-causal," approach against the stresses of [[economic equilibrium|equilibrium]] and [[perfect competition]] found in mainstream Neoclassical economics (see also [[praxeology]]).
+
The next great contributions of the Austrian School were made soon. Friedrich von Wieser (1889) detailed and expanded Menger's theory of imputation in production and alternative cost, while Eugen von Boehm-Bawerk (1889) developed his own distinctive time-dependent theory of capital and interest. 
*[[Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk]]'s critique of [[Karl Marx|Marx]] centered around the untenability of the [[labor theory of value]] in the light of the [[transformation problem]]. There was also the connected argument that capitalists do not exploit workers; they accommodate workers by providing them with income well in advance of the revenue from the output they helped to produce.
+
 
*[[Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk]]'s capital theory, which equates [[capital intensity]] with the degree of [[roundaboutness]] of production processes.
+
The early Austrian School  was to influence economists beyond the boundaries of the Austro-Hungarian Empire.  The alternative cost doctrine caught the fancy of Philip H. Wicksteed and Lionel Robbins in the U.K. and Herbert J. Davenport and Frank H. Knight in the United States, who used it to gleefully pound away at the Marshallian Neoclassical orthodoxy.
*[[Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk]]'s demonstration that the law of marginal utility, as formulated by [[Carl Menger|Menger]] necessarily implies the classical law of costs and hence the vast majority of the conclusions of the British [[classical economists]]. This discovery was later fully developed and its implications traced by a student of [[Ludwig von Mises|von Mises]], [[George Reisman]], in his book, ''Capitalism''.
+
 
*An emphasis on [[opportunity cost]] and reservation demand in defining [[marginal theory of value|value]], and a refusal to consider supply as an otherwise independent cause of value. (The British economist [[Philip Wicksteed]] adopted this perspective.)
+
===Monetary Overinvestment Theory of the Business Cycle===
*The Mises-Hayek [[business cycle]] theory, which explains depression as a reaction to an intertemporal production structure fostered by [[monetary policy]] setting [[interest rate]]s inconsistent with individual time preferences.
+
This focus on opportunity cost alone means that their interpretation of the time value of a good has a strict relationship: since goods will be as restricted by scarcity at a later point in time as they are now, the strict relationship between investment and time must also hold. A factory making goods next year is worth as much less as the goods it is making next year are worth. This means that the business cycle is driven by miscoordination between sectors of the same economy, caused by money not carrying incentive information correct about present choices, rather than within a single economy where money causes people to make bad decisions about how to spend their time.  
*Hayek's concept of [[intertemporal equilibrium]]. ([[John Hicks]] took over this theory in his discussion of temporary equilibrium in ''Value and Capital,'' a book very influential on the development of neoclassical economics after World War II.)
+
 
*Mises and Hayek's view of prices as permitting agents to make use of [[dispersed knowledge|dispersed tacit knowledge]].
+
A monetary overinvestment theory of the business cycle (versus Keynesians): Hayek and Mises authored many studies on the business cycle, warned of the danger of credit expansion, and predicted the coming currency crisis. This work was cited by the Nobel Prize committee in 1974 when Hayek received the award for economics. Working in England and America, Hayek later became a prime opponent of Keynesian economics with books on exchange rates, capital theory, and monetary reform. His popular book Road to Serfdom helped revive the classical liberal movement in America after the New Deal and World War II. And his series Law, Legislation, and Liberty elaborated on the Late Scholastic Late Scholastic approach to law, and applied it to criticize egalitarianism and nostrums like social justice. Support for anti-cyclical monetary policy and, later, a free banking system (versus Monetarists) :
*The [[time preference theory of interest]], which explains interest rates through [[intertemporal choice]] - the different time preferences of the borrower or lender - rather than as a price paid for a [[factor of production]].
+
 
*Stressing uncertainty in the making of economic decisions, rather than relying on "[[Homo economicus]]" or the rational man who was fully informed of all circumstances impinging on his decisions. The fact that perfect knowledge never exists, means that all economic activity implies risk.
+
Mises's New York seminar continued until two years before his death in 1973. During those years, Rothbard was his student. Indeed, Rothbard's Man, Economy, and State (1963) was patterned after Human Action, and in some areas—monopoly theory, utility and welfare, and the theory of the state—tightened and strengthened Mises's own views. Rothbard's approach to the Austrian School followed directly in the line of Late Scholastic thought by applying economic science within a framework of a natural-rights theory of property. What resulted was a full-fledged defense of a capitalistic and stateless social order, based on property and freedom of association and contract.
*Seeing the entrepreneurs' role as collecting and evaluating information and acting on risks.
+
 
*The [[economic calculation debate]] between Austrian and [[Marxist]] economists, with the Austrians claiming that Marxism is flawed because prices could not be set to recognize opportunity costs of factors of production, and so [[socialism]] could not make rational decisions.
+
 
 +
===Disorganized Competitive Market Processes===
 +
Will produce the greatest demand for his product or how many, if any, new competitors will enter his market. Offering a product on the market is always a trial-and-error, never-ending process of changing one's plans to reflect new knowledge one gains from day to day.  
 +
The importance of competitive markets and a price system in organizing a decentralized morass of economic agents with limited knowledge into a harmonious order. (versus Walrasians , Marxians and Keynesians) :
 +
The core of the Austrian framework can be summarized as taking a subjectivist approach to marginal economics, and a focus on the idea that logical consistency of a theory is more important that any interpretation of empirical observations. Austrians focus completely on the opportunity cost goods, as opposed to balancing downside or disutility costs. It is an Austrian assertion that everyone is better off in a mutually voluntary exchange, or they would not have carried it out. A fuller explanation of this in more exact terms is available at the New School's economic pages. Analyzing the time-consuming, disorganized competitive "market process" driven by specific actors in disequilibrium rather than the properties of anonymous equilibrium positions (versus Walrasians).
 +
The most important economic problem that people face, according to Austrian economists, is how to coordinate their plans with those of other people. Why, for example, when a person goes to a store to buy an apple, is the apple there to be bought? This meshing of individual plans in a world of uncertainty is, to Austrians, the basic economic problem. Austrian economists do not use mathematics in their analyses or theories because they do not think mathematics can capture the complex reality of human action. They believe that as people act, change occurs, and that quantifiable relationships are applicable only when there is no change. Mathematics can capture what has taken place, but can never capture what will take place.
 +
An individual's action takes place through time. A person decides on a desired end, chooses a means to attain that end, and then acts to attain it. But because all individuals act under the condition of uncertainty—especially uncertainty regarding the plans and actions of other individuals—people sometimes do not achieve their desired ends. The actions of one person may interfere with the actions of another. The actual consequences of any action can be known only after the action has taken place. This does not mean that people do not include in their plans expectations regarding the plans of others. But the exact outcome of a vast number of plans being executed at the same time can never be predicted. When offering a product on the market, for example, a producer can only guess as to what price it can put in.
 +
A stress on uncertainty and information in the economy, in particular the informational role of prices (versus Walrasians) : Mises and Hayek's view of prices as permitting agents to make use of dispersed tacit knowledge. The time preference theory of interest, which explains interest rates through intertemporal choice - the different time preferences of the borrower or lender - rather than as a price paid for a factor of production. Stressing uncertainty in the making of economic decisions, rather than relying on "Homo economicus" or the rational man who was fully informed of all circumstances impinging on his decisions. The fact that perfect knowledge never exists, means that all economic activity implies risk.  
  
 
==Economists affiliated with the Austrian School==
 
==Economists affiliated with the Austrian School==
{|
+
Benjamin Anderson, William Barnett II, Gérard Bramoullé , Walter Block, Peter Boettke, Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk, Gene Callahan, Tony Carilli, Jean-Pierre Centi , Christopher Coyne, Gregory Dempster, Thomas DiLorenzo, Steven Horwitz , Richard Ebeling, Karel Engliš, Frank Fetter, Jacques Garello, Roger Garrison , David Gordon, Gottfried Haberler, Friedrich Hayek, Henry Hazlitt, Hans-Hermann Hoppe, Jörg Guido Hülsmann, William Harold Hutt, Israel Kirzner , Ludwig Lachmann, Don Lavoie, Peter T. Leeson, Henri Lepage, Peter Lewin, Juan De Mariana, Ludwig von Mises, Margit von Mises, Oskar Morgenstern, Fritz Machlup, Carl Menger, Gerald O'Driscoll , Ernest C. Pasour, Ralph Raico, George Reisman,Dr. Kurt Richebächer,Mario Rizzo,Llewellyn Rockwell, Paul Rosenstein-Rodan, Murray Rothbard,Mark Thornton, Joseph Salerno, Pascal Salin, Josef Síma, Mark Skousen, Jesus Huerta de Soto, Richard von Strigl, Philip Henry Wicksteed , Friedrich von Wieser.
| valign="top" |
+
===Seminal works===
*[[Benjamin Anderson]]
+
*Boehm-Bawerk, E., Capital and Interest , Libertarian Press ( U. of C. ) 1959
*[http://business.loyno.edu/faculty/wbarnett/ William Barnett II]
+
*Boehm-Bawerk, E., "The Austrian Economists," Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 1 (1891)
*[[Gérard Bramoullé]]
+
*Boehm-Bawerk,E., Positive Theory of Capital, London: Macmillan and Co.. 1891, trans. William A. Smart, 1891
*[[Walter Block]]
+
*Hayek, F. A., Individualism and Economic Order, 1948
*[[Peter Boettke]]
+
*Hayek,F.A., The Fatal Conceit: The Errors of Socialism, 1988
*[[Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk]]
+
*Hayek, F.A.,"Economic Thought VI: The Austrian School," in David L. Sills (ed.), International Encyclopedia of the Social Sciences, New York: Macmillan and Free Press, 1968, pp. 458-459
*[[Gene Callahan]]
+
*Kirzner, I.M., Competition and Enterpreneurship , Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1973. 
*[http://www.gmu.edu/rae/archives/VOL14_4_2001/4_carilli&dempster.pdf Tony Carilli]
+
*Menger, C., Principles of Economics, first printing in German, 1871. The first English translation was copyright 1950 by the The Free Press, with an introduction by Frank H. Knight; 1976 and 1981 by the Institute for Human Studies, published by New York University Press with an introduction by F.A. Hayek; 1994 by Libertarian Press (reprint of the 1976 edition). Online version is copyright 2004 by the Ludwig von Mises Institute.
*[[Jean-Pierre Centi]]
+
*von Mises, L., Human Action, First Edition (1949), published by the von Mises Institute
*[[Christopher Coyne]]
+
*Rothbard, M.N., Man, Economy and State, 1962, revised 1970 & 1993, von Mises Institute
*[http://www.gmu.edu/rae/archives/VOL14_4_2001/4_carilli&dempster.pdf Gregory Dempster]
+
===External Links===
*[[Thomas DiLorenzo]]
+
What is Austrian Economics? Austrian School as defined by the Ludwig von Mises Institute
*[[Richard Ebeling]]
+
A Great Revolution in Economics - Vienna 1871 and after by Houmanidis and Leen
*[http://www.brno.cz/index.php?nav01=2222&nav02=2220&lan=en&nav03=2447&idosobnosti=10 Karel Engliš]
+
The Origins of the Austrian School of Economics by John Moser
 +
The Pure Logic of Choice
  
| <hspace width=40px> |
+
This page was last modified 17:13, 19 April 2007.
| valign="top" |
+
All text is available under the terms of the GNU Free Documentation License. (See Copyrights for details.)  
*[[Frank Fetter]]
+
*[[Jacques Garello]]
 
*[[Roger Garrison]]
 
*[[David Gordon (economist)|David Gordon]]
 
*[[Friedrich Hayek]]
 
*[[Henry Hazlitt]]
 
*[[Gottfried Haberler]]
 
*[[Hans-Hermann Hoppe]]
 
*[[Steven Horwitz]]
 
*[[Jorg Guido Hulsmann|Jörg Guido Hülsmann]]
 
*[[William Harold Hutt]]
 
*[[Israel Kirzner]]
 
*[[Ludwig Lachmann]]
 
*[[Don Lavoie]]
 
  
| <hspace width=40px> |
 
| valign="top" |
 
*[[Peter T. Leeson]]
 
*[[Henri Lepage]]
 
*[[Peter Lewin]]
 
*[[Juan De Mariana]]
 
*[[Ludwig von Mises]]
 
*[[Margit von Mises]]
 
*[[Oskar Morgenstern]]
 
*[[Fritz Machlup]]
 
*[[Carl Menger]]
 
*[[Gerald O'Driscoll]]
 
*[[Ernest C. Pasour]]
 
*[[Ralph Raico]]
 
*[[George Reisman]]
 
  
| <hspace width=40px> |
 
| valign="top" |
 
*[[Dr. Kurt Richebächer]]
 
*[[Mario Rizzo]]
 
*[[Llewellyn Rockwell]]
 
*[[Paul Rosenstein-Rodan]]
 
*[[Murray Rothbard]]
 
*[[Mark Thornton]]
 
*[[Joseph Salerno]]
 
*[[Pascal Salin]]
 
*[[Josef Síma]]
 
*[[Mark Skousen]]
 
*[[Jesus Huerta de Soto]]
 
*[[Richard von Strigl]]
 
*[[Philip Henry Wicksteed]]
 
*[[Friedrich von Wieser]]
 
|}
 
  
Note that the economists aligned with the Austrian School are sometimes colloquially called "the Austrians" even though not all held Austrian citizenship, and not all economists from Austria subscribe to the ideas of the Austrian School.
 
  
==Other related economists==
 
*[[Richard Cantillon]]
 
*[[Frédéric Bastiat]] (precursor)
 
*[[Henry Hazlitt]] (introduced the Austrian School to the USA)
 
*[[School of Salamanca]] (Renaissance precursors)
 
*[[Étienne Bonnot de Condillac]]
 
*[[Louis Say]]
 
*[[Jean-Baptiste Say]]
 
*[[Léon Walras]]
 
*[[Jules Dupuit]]
 
*[[Lionel Robbins]]
 
*[[Wilhelm Röpke]]
 
*[[Joseph Schumpeter]]
 
*[[Anne Robert Jacques Turgot, Baron de Laune|A.R.J. Turgot]]
 
*[[Knut Wicksell]]
 
  
==Critics==
 
*[[Bryan Caplan]]
 
*[[David D. Friedman]]
 
*[[Tyler Cowen]]
 
  
==Seminal works==
 
*''[[Principles of Economics]]'' by [[Carl Menger]]
 
*''[[Capital and Interest]]'' by [[Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk]]
 
*''[[Human Action]]'' by [[Ludwig von Mises]]
 
*''[[Individualism and Economic Order]]'' by [[Friedrich Hayek]]
 
*''[[Man, Economy, and State]]'' by [[Murray Rothbard|Murray N. Rothbard]]
 
*''[[Competition and Entrepreneurship]]'' by [[Israel Kirzner|Israel M. Kirzner]]
 
  
  
==External links==
+
*Moser, J., "The Origins of the Austrian School of Economics," Humane Studies Review, 11: 1 (Spring 1997)
*[http://www.mises.org/etexts/austrian.asp What is Austrian Economics?] Austrian School as defined by the [[Ludwig von Mises Institute]].
 
*[http://www.mises.org The Mises Institute - A large selection of online books, video/audio, journal archives, and research on Austrian economics]
 
*[http://it.stlawu.edu/sdae Society for the Development of Austrian Economics] Largest professional organization of Austrian economists
 
*[http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/AustrianEconomics.html Austrian Economics] ''[[Concise encyclopedia of economics]]'' on [[Econlib]]
 
*[http://homepage.newschool.edu/het/schools/austrian.htm Austrian School on newschool.edu] &ndash; compare Austrian versus other Schools
 
*[http://socserv2.socsci.mcmaster.ca/~econ/ugcm/3ll3/bawerk/austrian The Austrian Economists by Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk 1891]
 
*[http://library.wur.nl/way/catalogue/documents/A%20Great%20Revolution%20in%20Economics.htm A Great Revolution in Economics - Vienna 1871 and after] by Houmanidis and Leen
 
*[http://www.montpelerin.org/ The Mont Pelerin Society]
 
*[http://www.liberty-page.com/issues/austrian/main.html/ Austrian School Economists]  from Mark Valenti's Liberty Page
 
*[http://www.gmu.edu/departments/ihs/hsr/s97hsr.html#austrian The Origins of the Austrian School of Economics by John Moser]
 
*{{dmoz|Science/Social_Sciences/Economics/Schools_of_Thought/Austrian_School/}}
 
*[http://austrianecon.com Austrian Economics Forum] Discussion message board concerning Austrian economic theory
 
*[http://austrianeconomists.typepad.com/ The Austrian Economists]
 
*[http://austrianaddiction.rationalmind.net Austrian Addiction]
 
*[http://www.lewrockwell.com Lew Rockwell]
 
*[http://www.purelogic.us The Pure Logic of Choice]
 
===Critical ===
 
*[http://www.againstpolitics.com/austrian_economics/ A list of academic critiques of Austrian economics]
 
*[http://www.gmu.edu/departments/economics/bcaplan/whyaust.htm Why I Am Not An Austrian Economist]
 
*[http://world.std.com/~mhuben/austrian.html Austrian Economics]
 
  
  
  
 
{{Credits|Austrian_School|120656842|}}
 
{{Credits|Austrian_School|120656842|}}

Revision as of 20:25, 19 April 2007


Historical Overview

Main Personalities and their Ideals

The story of the Austrian School begins in the fifteenth century, when the followers of St. Thomas Aquinas, writing and teaching at the University of Salamanca in Spain, sought to explain the full range of human action and social organization.

These Late Scholastics observed the existence of economic law, inexorable forces of cause and effect that operate very much as other natural laws. Over the course of several generations, they discovered and explained the laws of supply and demand, the cause of inflation, the operation of foreign exchange rates, and the subjective nature of economic value—all reasons Joseph Schumpeter celebrated them as the first real economists.

The Late Scholastics were advocates of property rights and the freedom to contract and trade. They celebrated the contribution of business to society, while doggedly opposing taxes, price controls, and regulations that inhibited enterprise. As moral theologians, they urged governments to obey ethical strictures against theft and murder. And they lived up to Ludwig von Mises's rule: the first job of an economist is to tell governments what they cannot do.

The dominant British-French tradition  Jevons and Richard Cantillon ( Essay on the Nature of Commerce, 1730) who were followed by Anne Robert Jacques Turgot, the pro-market French aristocrat whose paper "Value and Money" spelled out the origins of money, and the nature of economic choice  received its first serious challenge in many years when Carl Menger's Principles of Economics was published in 1871.

Austrian School Proper

History

By way of general fascination over Principles of Economics, Menger (1840-1921) then became the founder of the Austrian School proper, resurrected the Scholastic-French approach to economics, and put it on firmer ground.

In addition, Menger showed how money originates in a free market when the most marketable commodity is desired, not for consumption, but for use in trading for other goods.

Menger's book was a pillar of the "marginalist revolution" in the history of economic science. When Mises said it "made an economist" out of him, he was not only referring to Menger's theory of money and prices, but also his approach to the discipline itself. Like his predecessors in the tradition, Menger was a classical liberal and methodological individualist, viewing economics as the science of individual choice. His Investigations, which came out twelve years later, battled the German Historical School, which rejected theory and saw economics as the accumulation of data in service of the state.

As professor of economics at the University of Vienna, Menger restored economics as the science of human action based on deductive logic, and prepared the way for later theorists to counter the influence of socialist thought. Indeed, his student Friederich von Wiese (1851-1926) strongly influenced Friedrich von Hayek's later writings. Menger's work remains an excellent introduction to the economic way of thinking. At some level, every Austrian since has seen himself as a student of Menger.

The "First" Generation of the Austrian School was thus composed of a pair Austrian professors who, although not directly students of Menger, were nonetheless heavily influenced by him: Friedrich von Wieser and Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk (1851-1914). Boehm-Bawerk's Positive Theory of Capital demonstrated that the normal rate of business profit is the interest rate. Capitalists save money, pay laborers, and wait until the final product is sold to receive profit. In addition, he demonstrated that capital is not homogeneous but an intricate and diverse structure that has a time dimension. A growing economy is not just a consequence of increased capital investment, but also of longer and longer processes of production. His History and Critique of Interest Theories, appearing in 1884, is a sweeping account of fallacies in the history of thought and a firm defense of the idea that the interest rate is not an artificial construct but an inherent part of the market. It reflects the universal fact of "time preference," the tendency of people to prefer satisfaction of wants sooner rather than later .

Boehm-Bawerk and von Wiesel, for the most part, spread the Austrian School gospel throughout the Austro-Hungarian Empire and trained the next two generations. These later generations were dominated by the figures of Ludwig von Mises (1881-1973) in the second generation of “Austrian School of Economics” and, in the third generation, by Friedrich von Hayek (1889-1992).

One area where Boehm-Bawerk had not elaborated on the analysis of Menger was money, the institutional intersection of the "micro" and "macro" approach. This time, young Mises, economic advisor to the Austrian Chamber of Commerce, took on the challenge. The result of Mises's research was The Theory of Money and Credit, published in 1912. He spelled out how the theory of marginal utility applies to money, and laid out his "regression theorem," showing that money not only originates in the market, but must always do so. Drawing on the British Currency School, Knut Wicksell's theory of interest rates, and Boehm-Bawerk's theory of the structure of production, Mises presented the broad outline of the Austrian theory of the business cycle.


Major Features of the Austrian School as the Opposition to other Economic Theories

Methodological Subjectivism

A radically "subjectivist" strain of Neoclassical marginalist economics (versus Classical School) : An individual's actions and choices are based upon a unique value scale known only to that individual. It is this subjective valuation of goods that creates economic value. Like other economists, the Austrian does not judge or criticize these subjective values but instead takes them as given data. But unlike other economists, the Austrian never attempts to measure or put these values in mathematical form. The idea that an individual's values, plans, expectations, and understanding of reality are all subjective permeates the Austrian tradition and, along with an emphasis on change or processes, is the basis for their notion of economic efficiency.

Methodologogical Individualism

A dedication to a prioristic "pure" theory, with an emphasis on "methodological individualism" (versus German Historical School): Economics, to an Austrian economist, is the study of purposeful human action in its broadest sense. Since only individuals act, the focus of study for the Austrian economist is always on the individual. Although Austrian economists are not alone in their methodological individualism, they do not stress the maximizing behavior of individuals in the same way as mainstream neoclassical economists. Austrian economists believe that one can never know if humans have maximized benefits or minimized costs. Austrian economists emphasize instead the process by which market participants gain information and form their expectations in order to lead them to their own idea of a best solution. After the 1871 presentation of his revolutionary subjective theory of value, Carl Menger was challenged by Gustav Schmoller and the recurrent debate on method (methodenstreit) which ensued between them and their followers divided the German-speaking world neatly: Austria and its universities for the Austrian School; Germany and its universities for the German Historical School.

Antitrust Behaviour

The theory of alternative cost which reduces all goods and factors, by "imputation", to the subjective valuation of consumer goods (versus Classical School and Marshallian Neoclassicals):

The neoclassical economic theory of perfect competition defines a competitive market as one in which there are a large number of small firms, all selling a homogeneous good and possessing perfect knowledge. The structure of the market, according to this analysis, determines the competitiveness of a market. But Austrian economists Friedrich A. Hayek and Israel M. Kirzner have rejected this theory of competition.

According to Hayek there is no competition in the neoclassical theory of perfect competition. Competition to an Austrian economist is defined simply as rivalrous behavior, and to compete is to attempt to offer a better deal than one's competitors.

Competition in the market arises out of one firm distinguishing its products in some way from those of other firms. And because firms in the real world do not have perfect knowledge, they do not know what a successful competitive strategy is until they try it.

"Competition is", therefore, as Hayek explains, a "discovery procedure." As each firm attempts to do better than all other firms, the knowledge of what consumers actually want in the market is discovered.

The next great contributions of the Austrian School were made soon. Friedrich von Wieser (1889) detailed and expanded Menger's theory of imputation in production and alternative cost, while Eugen von Boehm-Bawerk (1889) developed his own distinctive time-dependent theory of capital and interest.

The early Austrian School was to influence economists beyond the boundaries of the Austro-Hungarian Empire. The alternative cost doctrine caught the fancy of Philip H. Wicksteed and Lionel Robbins in the U.K. and Herbert J. Davenport and Frank H. Knight in the United States, who used it to gleefully pound away at the Marshallian Neoclassical orthodoxy.

Monetary Overinvestment Theory of the Business Cycle

This focus on opportunity cost alone means that their interpretation of the time value of a good has a strict relationship: since goods will be as restricted by scarcity at a later point in time as they are now, the strict relationship between investment and time must also hold. A factory making goods next year is worth as much less as the goods it is making next year are worth. This means that the business cycle is driven by miscoordination between sectors of the same economy, caused by money not carrying incentive information correct about present choices, rather than within a single economy where money causes people to make bad decisions about how to spend their time.

A monetary overinvestment theory of the business cycle (versus Keynesians): Hayek and Mises authored many studies on the business cycle, warned of the danger of credit expansion, and predicted the coming currency crisis. This work was cited by the Nobel Prize committee in 1974 when Hayek received the award for economics. Working in England and America, Hayek later became a prime opponent of Keynesian economics with books on exchange rates, capital theory, and monetary reform. His popular book Road to Serfdom helped revive the classical liberal movement in America after the New Deal and World War II. And his series Law, Legislation, and Liberty elaborated on the Late Scholastic Late Scholastic approach to law, and applied it to criticize egalitarianism and nostrums like social justice. Support for anti-cyclical monetary policy and, later, a free banking system (versus Monetarists) :

Mises's New York seminar continued until two years before his death in 1973. During those years, Rothbard was his student. Indeed, Rothbard's Man, Economy, and State (1963) was patterned after Human Action, and in some areas—monopoly theory, utility and welfare, and the theory of the state—tightened and strengthened Mises's own views. Rothbard's approach to the Austrian School followed directly in the line of Late Scholastic thought by applying economic science within a framework of a natural-rights theory of property. What resulted was a full-fledged defense of a capitalistic and stateless social order, based on property and freedom of association and contract.


Disorganized Competitive Market Processes

Will produce the greatest demand for his product or how many, if any, new competitors will enter his market. Offering a product on the market is always a trial-and-error, never-ending process of changing one's plans to reflect new knowledge one gains from day to day. The importance of competitive markets and a price system in organizing a decentralized morass of economic agents with limited knowledge into a harmonious order. (versus Walrasians , Marxians and Keynesians) : The core of the Austrian framework can be summarized as taking a subjectivist approach to marginal economics, and a focus on the idea that logical consistency of a theory is more important that any interpretation of empirical observations. Austrians focus completely on the opportunity cost goods, as opposed to balancing downside or disutility costs. It is an Austrian assertion that everyone is better off in a mutually voluntary exchange, or they would not have carried it out. A fuller explanation of this in more exact terms is available at the New School's economic pages. Analyzing the time-consuming, disorganized competitive "market process" driven by specific actors in disequilibrium rather than the properties of anonymous equilibrium positions (versus Walrasians). The most important economic problem that people face, according to Austrian economists, is how to coordinate their plans with those of other people. Why, for example, when a person goes to a store to buy an apple, is the apple there to be bought? This meshing of individual plans in a world of uncertainty is, to Austrians, the basic economic problem. Austrian economists do not use mathematics in their analyses or theories because they do not think mathematics can capture the complex reality of human action. They believe that as people act, change occurs, and that quantifiable relationships are applicable only when there is no change. Mathematics can capture what has taken place, but can never capture what will take place. An individual's action takes place through time. A person decides on a desired end, chooses a means to attain that end, and then acts to attain it. But because all individuals act under the condition of uncertainty—especially uncertainty regarding the plans and actions of other individuals—people sometimes do not achieve their desired ends. The actions of one person may interfere with the actions of another. The actual consequences of any action can be known only after the action has taken place. This does not mean that people do not include in their plans expectations regarding the plans of others. But the exact outcome of a vast number of plans being executed at the same time can never be predicted. When offering a product on the market, for example, a producer can only guess as to what price it can put in. A stress on uncertainty and information in the economy, in particular the informational role of prices (versus Walrasians) : Mises and Hayek's view of prices as permitting agents to make use of dispersed tacit knowledge. The time preference theory of interest, which explains interest rates through intertemporal choice - the different time preferences of the borrower or lender - rather than as a price paid for a factor of production. Stressing uncertainty in the making of economic decisions, rather than relying on "Homo economicus" or the rational man who was fully informed of all circumstances impinging on his decisions. The fact that perfect knowledge never exists, means that all economic activity implies risk.

Economists affiliated with the Austrian School

Benjamin Anderson, William Barnett II, Gérard Bramoullé , Walter Block, Peter Boettke, Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk, Gene Callahan, Tony Carilli, Jean-Pierre Centi , Christopher Coyne, Gregory Dempster, Thomas DiLorenzo, Steven Horwitz , Richard Ebeling, Karel Engliš, Frank Fetter, Jacques Garello, Roger Garrison , David Gordon, Gottfried Haberler, Friedrich Hayek, Henry Hazlitt, Hans-Hermann Hoppe, Jörg Guido Hülsmann, William Harold Hutt, Israel Kirzner , Ludwig Lachmann, Don Lavoie, Peter T. Leeson, Henri Lepage, Peter Lewin, Juan De Mariana, Ludwig von Mises, Margit von Mises, Oskar Morgenstern, Fritz Machlup, Carl Menger, Gerald O'Driscoll , Ernest C. Pasour, Ralph Raico, George Reisman,Dr. Kurt Richebächer,Mario Rizzo,Llewellyn Rockwell, Paul Rosenstein-Rodan, Murray Rothbard,Mark Thornton, Joseph Salerno, Pascal Salin, Josef Síma, Mark Skousen, Jesus Huerta de Soto, Richard von Strigl, Philip Henry Wicksteed , Friedrich von Wieser.

Seminal works

  • Boehm-Bawerk, E., Capital and Interest , Libertarian Press ( U. of C. ) 1959
  • Boehm-Bawerk, E., "The Austrian Economists," Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 1 (1891)
  • Boehm-Bawerk,E., Positive Theory of Capital, London: Macmillan and Co.. 1891, trans. William A. Smart, 1891
  • Hayek, F. A., Individualism and Economic Order, 1948
  • Hayek,F.A., The Fatal Conceit: The Errors of Socialism, 1988
  • Hayek, F.A.,"Economic Thought VI: The Austrian School," in David L. Sills (ed.), International Encyclopedia of the Social Sciences, New York: Macmillan and Free Press, 1968, pp. 458-459
  • Kirzner, I.M., Competition and Enterpreneurship , Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1973.
  • Menger, C., Principles of Economics, first printing in German, 1871. The first English translation was copyright 1950 by the The Free Press, with an introduction by Frank H. Knight; 1976 and 1981 by the Institute for Human Studies, published by New York University Press with an introduction by F.A. Hayek; 1994 by Libertarian Press (reprint of the 1976 edition). Online version is copyright 2004 by the Ludwig von Mises Institute.
  • von Mises, L., Human Action, First Edition (1949), published by the von Mises Institute
  • Rothbard, M.N., Man, Economy and State, 1962, revised 1970 & 1993, von Mises Institute

External Links

What is Austrian Economics? Austrian School as defined by the Ludwig von Mises Institute A Great Revolution in Economics - Vienna 1871 and after by Houmanidis and Leen The Origins of the Austrian School of Economics by John Moser The Pure Logic of Choice

This page was last modified 17:13, 19 April 2007. All text is available under the terms of the GNU Free Documentation License. (See Copyrights for details.)


  • Moser, J., "The Origins of the Austrian School of Economics," Humane Studies Review, 11: 1 (Spring 1997)


Credits

New World Encyclopedia writers and editors rewrote and completed the Wikipedia article in accordance with New World Encyclopedia standards. This article abides by terms of the Creative Commons CC-by-sa 3.0 License (CC-by-sa), which may be used and disseminated with proper attribution. Credit is due under the terms of this license that can reference both the New World Encyclopedia contributors and the selfless volunteer contributors of the Wikimedia Foundation. To cite this article click here for a list of acceptable citing formats.The history of earlier contributions by wikipedians is accessible to researchers here:

The history of this article since it was imported to New World Encyclopedia:

Note: Some restrictions may apply to use of individual images which are separately licensed.