Difference between revisions of "Value added tax" - New World Encyclopedia

From New World Encyclopedia
({{Contracted}})
Line 3: Line 3:
 
[[Category:Economics]]
 
[[Category:Economics]]
  
'''Value added tax''' ('''VAT'''), or '''goods and services tax''' ('''GST'''), is [[tax]] on exchanges. It is levied on the added value that results from each exchange. It differs from a [[sales tax]] because a sales tax is levied on the total value of the exchange. For this reason, a VAT is neutral with respect to the number of passages that there are between the producer and the final consumer.  A VAT is an [[indirect tax]], in that the tax is collected from someone other than the person who actually bears the cost of the tax (namely the seller rather than the consumer). To avoid double taxation on final consumption, exports (which by definition, are ''consumed'' abroad) are usually not subject to VAT and VAT charged under such circumstances is usually refundable. 
+
'''The Value Added Tax''' (VAT) taxes all business profit and labor. Profit being gross receipts minus all business expenses including the 'tax' on labor which is considered a cost of doing business. Profit and labor could be lumped together by subtracting all other business expenses from gross receipts and then taxing the remainder at a uniform VAT tax rate.
 +
 
 +
The cost of materials, subcomponents, tools, equipment, facilities, supplies, etc, and any services purchased from other businesses isn't taxed (again) under the VAT. Those purchases would have already been subjected to the VAT by the supplying businesses.
 +
 
 +
==VAT in more details==
  
 
The VAT was invented by a French economist in 1954. [[Maurice Lauré]], joint director of the French tax authority, the ''Direction générale des impôts'', as ''taxe sur la valeur ajoutée'' ([[:fr:Taxe sur la valeur ajoutée|TVA]] in [[French language|French]]) was first to introduce VAT with effect from 10 April 1954 for large businesses, and extended over time to all business sectors. In [[France]], it is the most important source of state finance, accounting for approximately 45% of state revenues.
 
The VAT was invented by a French economist in 1954. [[Maurice Lauré]], joint director of the French tax authority, the ''Direction générale des impôts'', as ''taxe sur la valeur ajoutée'' ([[:fr:Taxe sur la valeur ajoutée|TVA]] in [[French language|French]]) was first to introduce VAT with effect from 10 April 1954 for large businesses, and extended over time to all business sectors. In [[France]], it is the most important source of state finance, accounting for approximately 45% of state revenues.
  
Personal end-consumers of products, consumers and services cannot recover VAT on purchases, but businesses are able to recover VAT on the materials and services that they buy to make further supplies or services directly or indirectly sold to end-users. In this way, the total tax levied at each stage in the economic chain of supply is a constant fraction of the value added by a business to its products, and most of the cost of collecting the tax is borne by business, rather than by the state. VAT was invented because very high sales taxes and tariffs encourage cheating and smuggling. It has been criticized on the grounds that it is a [[regressive tax]].
+
The value-added tax ( VAT ) that extends through the retail level is levied on each firm in the production and distribution chain, from the extraction of raw materials through the manufacturing and distribution processes, to the last sale to final customers. Thus, under a comprehensive value-added tax, all businesses, not just those that sell at retail, would pay tax on their sales. An important characteristic of a value-added tax is that tax is applied only to the value added by the firm, that is, to the excess of its sales over its purchases of goods from other business firms.
 +
 
 +
The VAT is usually collected by the tax credit method; each firm applies the tax rate to its taxable sales, but is allowed a credit for value-added tax paid on its purchases of goods and services for business use, including the tax paid on purchases of  capital equipment under a consumption-type value-added tax. As a result, the only tax for which no credit would be allowed would be that collected on sales made to households, rather than to businesses.
 +
 
 +
 
 +
Since the sum of the values added at all stages in the production and distribution of a good are equal to the retail selling price of the good, the revenue base of a retail sales tax and a value-added tax with the same coverage are theoretically identical, and a given tax  rate will yield the same amount of tax revenue under either approach and under equal conditions of implementation, e.g., no exceptions, exemptions, etc.
 +
 
 +
Thus, despite its multistage character, a value-added tax is very much like a retail sales tax in that it is a tax on expenditures by consumers or, in other words, it is just another type of consumption tax.
 +
 
 +
==Comparison of VAT with a Sales tax==
 +
 
 +
'''Retail sales tax''', the familiar percentage tax on retail sales, is one type of consumption tax. Of the various forms of consumption taxes, the sales tax surely has the great advantage for most of tax-payers of eliminating the despotic power of the government over the life of every individual, as in the income tax, or over each business firm, as we shall see the VAT might do. Sales tax also does not distort the production structure as would the VAT, and it would not skew individual preferences as would specific excise taxes ( Rothbard, 1994 ).
 +
 
 +
 
 +
'''The VAT  consumption tax''',  proposed in the U.S., imposes a bit of hierarchical tax on the "value added" by each firm and business.  
  
==Comparison with a sales tax==
+
Here, instead of every individual, every business firm would be subjected to intense bureaucratic scrutiny, for each firm would be obliged to report its income and its expenditures, paying a designated tax on the net income.  
VAT differs from a conventional [[sales tax]] in that VAT is levied on ''every'' business as a ''fraction'' of the price of each taxable sale they make, but they are in turn reimbursed VAT on their purchases, so the VAT is applied to the value added to the goods at each stage of production.  
 
  
Sales taxes are normally only charged on final sales to consumers: because of reimbursement, VAT has the same overall economic effect on final prices. The main difference is the extra accounting required by those in the middle of the supply chain; this disadvantage of VAT is balanced by application of the same tax to each member of the production chain regardless of its position in it and the position of its customers, reducing the effort required to check and certify their status. When the VAT has few, if any exemptions such as with [[Goods and Services Tax (New Zealand)|GST in New Zealand]], payment of VAT is even simpler.
 
  
A general economic idea is that if sales taxes exceed 10%, people start engaging in widespread tax evading activity (like buying over the Internet, pretending to be a business, buying at wholesale, buying products through an employer etc.) On the other hand, total VAT rates can rise above 10% without widespread evasion because of the novel collection mechanism.{{Fact|date=February 2007}} However because of its particular mechanism of collection, VAT becomes quite easily the target of specific frauds like [[Missing trader fraud|carousel fraud]] which can be very expensive in terms of loss of tax incomes for states.
+
This would tend to distort the structure of business. For one thing, there would be an incentive for uneconomic vertical integration, since the fewer the number of times a sale takes place, the fewer the imposed taxes. Also, as has been happening in European countries with experience of the VAT, a flourishing industry may arise in issuing phony vouchers, so that businesses can over-inflate their alleged expenditures, and reduce their reported value added.  
  
=== Collection Mechanism ===
+
Surely a sales tax, other things being equal, seems to be both simpler, less distorting of resources, and enormously less bureaucratic and despotic than the VAT. Indeed the VAT seems to have no clear advantage over the sales tax, except of course, if multiplying bureaucracy and bureaucratic power is considered a benefit ( ibid., 1994 ).
The standard way to implement a VAT is to say a business owes some percentage on the price of the product minus all taxes previously paid on the good. If VAT rates were 10%, an orange juice maker would pay 10% of the $5 per gallon price ($0.50) minus taxes previously paid by the orange farmer (maybe $0.20). In this example, the orange juice maker would have a $0.30 tax liability. Each business has a strong incentive for its suppliers to pay their taxes, allowing VAT rates to be higher with less tax evasion than a retail sales tax. </sup>
 
  
===Example===
 
Consider the manufacture and sale of any item, which in this case we will call a [[Placeholder name|widget]].
 
  
====Without any sales tax====
+
===Several possible disadvantages of VAT===
* A widget manufacturer spends $1 on raw materials and uses them to make a widget.
 
* The widget is sold wholesale to a widget retailer for $1.20, making a profit of $0.20.
 
* The widget retailer then sells the widget to a widget consumer for $1.50, making a profit of $0.30
 
  
====With a North American (Canadian Provincial and U.S. State) sales tax====
+
*Growth of government ( see also “Administrative Costs”):
With a 10% sales tax:
 
* The manufacturer pays $1.00 for the raw materials, certifying it is not a final consumer.
 
* The manufacturer charges the retailer $1.20, checking that the retailer is not a consumer, leaving the same profit of $0.20.
 
* The retailer charges the consumer $1.65 ($1.50 + 10%) and pays the government $0.15, leaving the same profit of $0.30.
 
So the consumer has paid 10% ($0.15) extra, compared to the no taxation scheme, and the government has collected this amount in taxation. The retailers have not lost anything directly to the tax, but they do have the extra paperwork to do so that they correctly pass on to the government the sales tax they collect. Suppliers and manufacturers have the administrative burden of supplying correct certifications, and checking that their customers (retailers) aren't consumers.
 
  
====With a value added tax====
+
The United States stands almost alone among the developed countries of the free world in not levying a national sales tax. Virtually all of the members of the European Economic Community (EEC) employ a national value-added tax. Of the twenty-three ( original ) members of  Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), only two countries — Japan and Turkey — use neither a value-added tax nor a general sales tax. In Canada, there is a bit similar national tax ---- apart from bewildering array of, by no means harmonized, provincial sales taxes --- called  GST or General Sales tax.
With a 10% VAT:
 
* The manufacturer pays $1.10 ($1 + 10%) for the raw materials, and the seller of the raw materials pays the government $0.10.
 
* The manufacturer charges the retailer $1.32 ($1.20 + $1.20x10%) and pays the government $0.02 ($0.12 ''minus'' $0.10), leaving the same profit of $0.20.
 
* The retailer charges the consumer $1.65 ($1.50 + $1.50x10%) and pays the government $0.03 ($0.15 ''minus'' $0.12), leaving the same profit of $0.30.
 
So the consumer has paid 10% ($0.15) extra, compared to the no taxation scheme, and the government has collected this amount in taxation. The businesses have not lost anything directly to the tax, but they do have the extra paperwork to do so that they correctly pass on to the government the difference between what they collect in VAT (output VAT, an 11th of their income) and what they spend in VAT (input VAT, an 11th of their expenditure).
 
  
Note that in each case the VAT paid is equal to 10% of the profit, or 'value added'.
 
  
The advantage of the VAT system over the sales tax system is that businesses cannot hide consumption (such as wasted materials) by certifying it is not a consumer.
+
The lack of a national sales tax ( e.g. VAT ) in the United States is reflected closely in the percentage of Gross Domestic Product (GDP) devoted to public use in the United States and in other countries. In 1982 total tax revenues at all levels of government averaged 30.5 percent of GDP in the United States. The comparable figure for the EEC countries was 40.1 percent and for the countries of the OECD, exclusive of the United States, it was 37.1 percent.  
  
====Limitations to example and VAT====
+
In the United States, sales taxes (state and local) took approximately 6 percentage points less of GDP than in the EEC and in the OECD (exclusive of the United States). It  is not only sales taxes that are lower in the United States; corporate income and social security taxes also are substantially lower in the figures suggest that even if a sales tax were initially imposed as a partial replacement for the income tax in a revenue-neutral change, public spending in the United States would eventually be greater with a national sales tax than without one.
In the above example, we assumed that the same number of widgets were made and sold both before and after the introduction of the tax. This is not true in real life.
 
  
The fundamentals of [[supply and demand]] suggest that any tax raises the cost of transaction for ''someone'', whether it is the seller or purchaser. In raising the cost, either the [[demand curve]] shifts leftward, or the [[supply curve]] shifts upward. The two are functionally equivalent. Consequently, the quantity of a good purchased, and/or the price for which it is sold, decrease.
+
*Regressivity:
  
This shift in supply and demand is not incorporated into the above example, for simplicity and because these effects are different for every type of good. The above example assumes the tax is ''non-distortionary''.
+
A general sales tax --- as all types of consumption taxes inclusive of  ( Retail ) sales tax ---- is often criticized as unfair  to lower income individuals and families. There are two aspects  to this equity argument: ( 1 ) The absolute burden of the tax on the lowest income groups, and the regressivity of the tax or the relatively higher burden of the tax at the lower income levels than at the higher. Simultaneously,  ( 2 ) there are several alternatives for lessening the burden of the tax on the poor. For those individuals and families that are above the poverty level of income and thus subject to the income tax, the regressivity of a sales tax can be offset through the adjustment of income tax rates or through non-refundable credits against the income tax.
  
A VAT, like most taxes, distorts what would have happened without it. Because the price for ''someone'' rises, the quantity of goods traded decreases. Correspondingly, some people are ''worse'' off by ''more'' than the government is made ''better'' off by tax income . That is, more is lost due to supply and demand shifts than is gained in tax. This is known as a [[deadweight loss]]. The income lost by the economy is greater than the government's income; the tax is inefficient. The entire amount of the government's income (the tax revenue) may not be a deadweight drag, if the tax revenue is used for productive spending or has positive externalities - in other words, governments may do more than simply ''consume'' the tax income. While distortions occur, consumption taxes like VAT are often considered superior because they distort incentives to invest, save and work ''less'' than most other types of taxation - in other words, a VAT discourages consumption rather than production. However they are still considered inferior to taxes like [[land value tax]] which neither cause deadweight losses nor distort incentives.
+
*Effect on prices:
  
<div style="float:center; width:300px; padding:2px; margin-left:1em; text-align:center">
+
Assuming an accommodating monetary policy, a sales tax would almost certainly increase the price level by roughly the percentage it represents of consumption spending. That is, a 4  percent sales tax that applied to 75 percent of consumption expenditures  would increase the general price level by about  3 percent.
[[Image:TaxWithTax.svg|200px]]<br />''A Supply-Demand Analysis of a Taxed Market''<br align="center"></div>
 
In the above diagram,
 
  
'''Deadweight loss''': the area of the triangle formed by the tax income box, the original supply curve, and the demand curve
+
Although this would be a one-time occurrence, not an annual increase,  it might cause "ripples" of wage increases, because of cost-of-living adjustments ( !  ) and these could be reflected in further price increases.  To the extent the sales tax replaced part of the income tax, there would be little offsetting reduction in prices or wages.
+
 
'''Government's tax income''': the grey area
+
*Administrative costs:
  
'''Total [[consumer surplus]] after the shift''': the green area
+
Administration of a Federal value-added  tax would require substantial additional resources. The Internal  Revenue Service estimates that once the administrative program was fully phased in, the annual administrative costs would run about $700  million (at 1984 prices), or about 0.4 percent of revenues from a 10  percent broad-based value-added tax. To administer a value-added tax, the IRS would require approximately 20,000 additional personnel.
  
'''Total [[producer surplus]] after the shift''': the yellow area
+
*Federal pre-emption:  
  
==Criticisms==
+
States, and more recently local governments, consider the sales tax base their exclusive fiscal domain. Federal imposition of a sales tax might reduce somewhat the ability of state and local governments to tax that base and would therefore be seen by those governments as an unwelcome intrusion.  
The "value added tax" has been criticized as the burden of it relies on personal end-consumers of products and is therefore a [[regressive tax]] (the poor pay more, in comparison, than the rich).  However, this calculation is derived when the tax paid is divided not by the tax base (the amount spent) but by income, which is argued to create an arbitrary relationship. The tax rate itself is proportional with higher income people paying more tax but at the same rate as they consume more.  If a value added tax is to be related to income, then the unspent income can be treated as deferred (spending savings at a later point in time), at which time it is taxed creating a [[proportional tax]] using an income base. Such taxes can have a [[progressive tax|progressive]] effect on the [[effective tax rate]] of consumption by using exemptions, rebates, or credits.
 
  
Revenues from a value added tax are frequently lower than expected because they are difficult and costly to administer and collect.{{dubious}} In many countries, however, where collection of personal income taxes and corporate profit taxes has been historically weak, VAT collection has been more successful than other types of taxes. VAT has become more important in many jurisdictions as tariff levels have fallen worldwide due to trade liberalisation, as VAT has essentially replaced lost tariff revenues. Whether the costs and distortions of value added taxes are lower than the economic inefficiencies and enforcement issues (e.g. smuggling) from high import tariffs is debated, but theory suggests value added taxes are far more efficient.
 
  
Due to the fact that exports are generally zero-rated (and VAT refunded or offset against other taxes), this is often where VAT fraud occurs. In sectors or countries where VAT fraud is prevalent, attempts by authorities to control fraud may have unintended consequences, and raise costs for ''honest'' companies. This problem is also true of other types of taxation, however.
+
This concern could be reduced if Federal adoption of a retail sales tax led to increased cooperation between the various levels of governments in tax  administration and collection. This cooperation would be much easier to achieve if the Federal Government adopted a retail sales tax than  if it adopted a value-added tax. If the state and Federal tax bases  were identical, state taxes could be collected by the Federal Government as it collected its own tax. Of course, a Federal sales tax could not simply be collected by the states, because of the  current differences in state tax bases.
  
Certain industries (small-scale services, for example) tend to have more VAT avoidance, particularly where cash transactions predominate, and VAT may be criticized for encouraging this. From the perspective of government, however, VAT may be preferable because it captures at least some of the value-added. For example, a carpenter may offer to provide services ''for cash'' (i.e. without a receipt, and without VAT) to a homeowner, who usually cannot claim input VAT back. The homeowner will hence bear lower costs and the carpenter may be able to avoid other taxes (profit or payroll taxes). The government, however, may still receive VAT for various other inputs (lumber, paint, gasoline, tools, etc) sold to the carpenter, who would be unable to reclaim the VAT on these inputs. While the total tax receipts may be lower ''compared to full compliance,'' it may not be lower than under other feasible taxation systems.
+
===Possible Advantages of VAT===
  
In Europe, the main source of problems is called 'carousel' fraud. Large quantities of valuable goods (often microchips or mobile phones) are transported from one member state to the other. During these transactions, some companies owe VAT, other acquire a right to reclaim VAT. The first companies, called 'missing traders' go bankrupt without paying. The second group of companies can 'pump' money straight out of the national treasuries.
+
One of the more interesting theoretical arguments for a VAT is that the new tax would improve economic performance by facilitating a reduction in other taxes. According to some advocates, the  additional revenue generated by a VAT—$37 billion  for every percentage point, according to the Congressional Research Service15—could be used to lower, or perhaps even eliminate, personal and corporate income taxes.
  
This kind of fraud originated in the 1970s in the Benelux-countries.  Today, the British treasury is the main victim.  The British judicial system is considered by such criminals as the weakest in the EU. Collaboration with other member states is poor, and the trial-by-jury system makes convictions difficult.
+
Hence, if the VAT was actually used to eliminate all income taxes, this theory would have considerable merit. There is no doubt that personal and corporate income taxes do more damage per dollar raised  than a VAT would.
  
==VAT systems==
+
A national sales tax ( VAT ) thus should have several major advantages over the current combination of  national  income tax and states’ ( provincial ) taxes. If it were used to replace part of the income tax, a Federal sales tax would allow even lower income tax rates. By taking pressure off the definition and measurement of taxable income, a sales tax would help reduce income tax avoidance and  evasion as well as lessen the incentive to shelter income from the income tax. Based on consumption, rather than income, a national sales tax ( VAT would not discriminate against saving the way the income tax does ( about this issue look to the below paragraph.)  
===European Union===
 
A common VAT system is compulsory for [[European Union member states|member states]] of the [[European Union]]. The EU VAT system is imposed by a series of [[European Union directive]]s, the most important of which is the Sixth VAT Directive (Directive 77/388/EC). Nevertheless, some member states have negotiated variable rates ([[Madeira]] in [[Portugal]]) or VAT exemption for regions or territories. The regions below fall out of the scope of EU VAT:<ref>[http://www.vat.gov.mt/docs/vat_comments_new_act_1_march_2004.pdf VAT Comments (Malta)]</ref>
 
  
* [[Åland Islands]] ([[Finland]])
+
Accordingly, it may increase the level of private saving and generate a corresponding increase in capital formation and economic growth. A broad-based sales tax would almost certainly distort
* [[Heligoland]] island, [[Büsingen]] territory ([[Germany]])
+
economic choices less than the income tax does. In contrast to the income tax, it would not discourage capital-intensive methods of production or risk taking and it would be neutral with regard to other major revenue sources.
* [[Guadeloupe]], [[Martinique]], [[French Guiana]], [[Réunion]] ([[France]])
 
* [[Mount Athos]] ([[Greece]])
 
* [[Ceuta]], [[Melilla]], [[The Canary Islands]] ([[Spain]])
 
* [[Livigno]], [[Campione d'Italia]], [[Lake Lugano]] ([[Italy]])
 
* [[Gibraltar]], [[The Channel Islands]] ([[United Kingdom]])
 
  
Under the EU system of VAT, where a person carrying on an economic activity supplies goods and services to another person, and the value of the supplies passes financial limits, the supplier is required to register with the local taxation authorities and charge its customers, and account to the local taxation authority for VAT (although the price may be ''inclusive'' of VAT, so VAT is included as part of the agreed price, or ''exclusive'' of VAT, so VAT is payable in addition to the agreed price).
 
  
VAT that is charged by a business and paid by its customers is known as ''output'' VAT (that is, VAT on its output supplies). VAT that is paid by a business to other businesses on the supplies that it receives is known as ''input'' VAT (that is, VAT on its input supplies). A business is generally able to recover input VAT to the extent that the input VAT is attributable to (that is, used to make) its taxable outputs. Input VAT is recovered by setting it against the output VAT for which the business is required to account to the government, or, if there is an excess, by claiming a repayment from the government.  
+
Further implication of all of this means that goods and services purchased for business use are automatically freed from tax; by and large, only  goods and services sold to households are ultimately taxed under the value-added tax. Tax auditors need only to check the purchasing firm to ensure that purchases for which a credit is claimed were used for business purposes. By comparison, it is more difficult under a retail sales tax to completely exempt all business purchases. Firms must  provide exemption certificates to their suppliers to buy tax free, and  auditors must check both the supplier and purchaser in cases of doubt.
  
Different rates of VAT apply in different EU member states. The minimum standard rate of VAT throughout the EU is 15%, although reduced rates of VAT, as low as 5%, are applied in various states on various sorts of supply (for example, domestic fuel and power in the UK). The maximum rate in the EU is 25%.
 
  
The Sixth VAT Directive requires certain goods and services to be exempt from VAT (for example, postal services, medical care, lending, insurance, betting), and certain other goods and services to be exempt from VAT but subject to the ability of an EU member state to opt to charge VAT on those supplies (such as land and certain financial services). Input VAT that is attributable to exempt supplies is not recoverable, although a business can increase its prices so the customer effectively bears the cost of the 'sticking' VAT (the effective rate will be lower than the headline rate and depend on the balance between previously taxed input and labour at the exempt stage).
+
At the state level, this system of exemption certificates applies only to goods purchased for resale or goods that become component parts or  physical ingredients of produced goods; other purchases, such as  machinery and equipment, are only exempt if specifically provided in  the state statute. The end result is that not all business purchases  are free of retail sales tax; about 20 percent of sales tax revenue is from taxing business purchases.
  
Finally, some goods and services are "zero-rated." The zero-rate is a positive rate of tax calculated at 0%. Supplies subject to the zero-rate are still "taxable supplies," i.e. they have VAT charged on them. In the UK, examples include most food, books, drugs, and certain kinds of transport. The zero-rate is not featured in the EU Sixth Directive as it was intended that the minimum VAT rate throughout Europe would be 5%. However, zero-rating remains in some Member States, most notably the UK, as a legacy of pre-EU legislation. These Member States have been granted a derogation to continue existing zero-rating but cannot add new goods or services.
+
Another important advantage of the value-added form of sales tax  is the fact that tax is collected as products move from stage to stage in the production-distribution process. Thus by the time a product reaches the retail stage, much of its total value has already been taxed.  
The UK also exempts or lowers the rate on some products depending on situation; for example milk products are exempt from VAT, but if you go into a restaurant and drink a milk drink it is VAT-able. Some products such as feminine hygiene products and baby products (nappies etc) are charged at 5% VAT along with domestic fuel.
 
  
When goods are [[import]]ed into the EU from other states, VAT is generally charged at the [[border]], at the same time as [[customs duty]]. "Acquisition" VAT is payable when goods are acquired in one EU member state from another EU member state (this is done not at the border but through an accounting mechanism). EU businesses are often required to charge themselves VAT under the ''reverse charge'' mechanism where services are received from another member state or from outside of the EU.
 
  
Businesses can be required to register for VAT in EU member states, other than the one in which they are based, if they supply goods via mail order to those states, over a certain threshold. Businesses that are established in one member state but which receive supplies in another member state may be able to reclaim VAT charged in the second state under the provisions of the Eighth VAT Directive (Directive 79/1072/EC). To do so, businesses have a [[value added tax identification number]]. A similar directive, the Thirteenth VAT Directive (Directive 86/560/EC), also allows businesses established outside the EU to recover VAT in certain circumstances.
+
'''To summarize''': Theoretically, a VAT would be acceptable  if it were combined with ratification of a constitutional amendment that permanently prohibits  both the personal and corporate income taxes, but, unfortunately, this is an extremely unlikely scenario. In fact, as yet no nation has ever implemented a VAT (or a national sales tax) and used the money to eliminate all income taxes.
  
Following changes introduced on July 1, 2003, (under Directive 2002/38/EC), non-EU businesses providing digital [[electronic commerce]] and entertainment products and services to EU countries are also required to register with the tax authorities in the relevant EU member state, and to collect VAT on their sales at the appropriate rate, according to the location of the purchaser. Alternatively, under a special scheme, non-EU businesses may register and account for VAT on only one EU member state. This produces distortions as the rate of VAT is that of the member state of registration, not where the customer is located, and an alternative approach is therefore under negotiation, whereby VAT is charged at the rate of the member state where the purchaser is located.
 
  
The differences between different rates of VAT was often originally justified by certain products being "luxuries" and thus bearing high rates of VAT, whereas other items were deemed to be "essentials" and thus bearing lower rates of VAT. However, often high rates persisted long after the argument was no longer valid. For instance, [[France]] taxed cars as a luxury product (33%) up into the 1980s, when most of the French households owned one or more cars. Similarly, in the UK, clothing for children is "zero rated" whereas clothing for adults is subject to VAT at the standard rate of 17.5%.
+
==The Impossibility of Taxing Only Consumption==
  
====Rules on pricing within the EU====
+
A few arguments of why VAT, as a consumption tax,  cannot replace the income tax should be mentioned now.  
* Where most of the trade is business-to-consumer, displayed prices must include VAT and VAT must be charged.
 
* Where most of the trade is business-to-business, displayed prices do not have to include VAT. For business transactions the following rules apply:
 
** VAT must be charged if the buyer is in the same country as the seller. The buyer may be able to reclaim the VAT from the tax authorities.
 
** VAT does not need to be charged if the buyer is in a different country. The seller must record the VAT number of the buyer.
 
** Certain EU companies are VAT exempt, these companies must not be charged VAT, regardless of whether they are in the same or different country to the seller.
 
  
===Denmark, Norway, and Sweden (MOMS)===
 
'''MOMS''' ([[Danish Language|Danish]]: ''Meromsætningsafgift'', [[Norwegian language|Norwegian]]: ''merverdiavgift'' (abriviated ''MVA''), [[Swedish language|Swedish]]: ''mervärdesskatt'', earlier ''mervärdesomsättningsskatt'') is a Danish, Norwegian and Swedish [[sales tax]]. MOMS is the Danish, Norwegian and Swedish term for [[Value Added Tax|VAT]]. Like other countries' sales and VAT taxes, MOMS is a [[Regressive tax|regressive]] [[indirect tax]].
 
  
In [[Denmark]], VAT is only applied at one level, and is not split into two levels as in other countries (e.g. Germany), where VAT is split into ''VAT for foodstuffs'' and ''VAT for nonfood''. The current percentage in Denmark is 25%. That makes Denmark one of the countries with the highest value added tax, alongside [[Norway]] and [[Sweden]].
+
Orthodox neoclassical economics has long maintained that, from the point of view of the taxed themselves, an income tax is "better than" an excise tax on a particular form of consumption, since, in addition to the total revenue extracted, which is assumed to be the same in both cases, the excise tax weights the levy heavily against a particular consumer good.
  
In [[Norway]], VAT is split into three levels: 25% is the general VAT, 14% (formerly 13%, up on January 1, 2007) for foods and restaurant take-out (food eaten in a restaurant has 25%), 8% for person transport, movie tickets, and hotel stays. Most printed matters are still free of VAT.
 
  
In [[Sweden]], VAT is split into three levels: 25% for most goods and services including restaurants bills, 12% for foods and hotel stays (but breakfast at 25%) and 6% for printed matter, cultural services,and transport of private persons. Some services are not taxable for example education of children and adults if public utility, but education is taxable at 25% in case of courses for adults at a private school.  
+
But, all through the comparison of the income as compared to an excise tax one thing is well experienced by every tax-payer in the U.S. ( and many other countries ). Income taxes are collected in the course of a coercive and even brutal examination of virtually every aspect of every taxpayer's life by the all-seeing, all-powerful Internal Revenue Service.  
  
MOMS replaced OMS (Danish "''Omsætningsafgift''," Swedish "''omsättningsskatt''") in 1967, which was a tax applied exclusively for retailers.
+
An excise tax, say, on whiskey or on movie admissions, will intrude directly on no one's life and income, but only into the sales of the movie theater or liquor store. It is quite feasible that, in evaluating the "''superiority''" or "''inferiority''" of different modes of taxation, even the most determined imbiber or moviegoer would cheerfully pay far higher prices for whiskey or movies than neoclassical economists contemplate, in order to avoid the long arm of the IRS ( NOTE [1] ).
  
{|class="toccolours" border="1" cellpadding="4" cellspacing="0" style="border-collapse: collapse; margin:1 auto;"
+
|- style="text-align: Center;"
+
However, the only coherent argument offered by advocates of consumption against income taxation is that of [[Irving Fisher]], based on suggestions of [[John Stuart Mill]]. Fisher argued that, since the goal of all production is consumption, and since all capital goods are only way-stations on the way to consumption, the only genuine income is consumption spending. The conclusion is quickly drawn that therefore only consumption income, not what is generally called "income," should be subject to tax( Rothbard, 1977, pp. 98–100.)
|'''Year'''
 
|'''Tax level'''
 
|'''OMS/MOMS'''
 
<tr><td>1962</td><td>9%</td><td>OMS</td></tr>
 
<tr><td>1967</td><td>10%</td><td>MOMS</td></tr>
 
<tr><td>1968</td><td>12,5%</td><td>MOMS</td></tr>
 
<tr><td>1970</td><td>15%</td><td>MOMS</td></tr>
 
<tr><td>1977</td><td>18%</td><td>MOMS</td></tr>
 
<tr><td>1978</td><td>20.25%</td><td>MOMS</td></tr>
 
<tr><td>1980</td><td>22%</td><td>MOMS</td></tr>
 
<tr><td>1992</td><td>25%</td><td>MOMS</td></tr>
 
|}
 
  
===India===
 
{{section cleanup|July 2006}}
 
In India, VAT replaced [[sales tax]] on 1 April 2005. Of the 21 Indian states, eight did not introduce VAT. [[Haryana]] had already adopted it on 1 April 2004. The "empowered committee" of the basic framework for uniform VAT laws in the states. Due to the federal nature of the Indian constitution, the states do have the power to set their own VAT rate.
 
  
====The Andhra Pradesh experience====
+
The market, in short, knows all about the productive power of savings for the future, and allocates its expenditures accordingly. Yet even though people know that savings will yield them more future consumption, why don't they save all their current income?
In the Indian state of [[Andhra Pradesh]], the Andhra Pradesh Value Added Tax Act, 2005 came into force on 1 April 2005 and contains six schedules. Schedule I contains goods generally exempted from tax. Schedule II deals with zero rated transactions like exports and Schedule III contains goods taxable at 1%, namely jewellery made from bullion and precious stones. Goods taxable at 4% are listed under Schedule IV. The majority of foodgrains and goods of national importance, like iron and steel, are listed under this head. Schedule V deals with Standard Rate Goods, taxable at 12.5%. All goods that are not listed elsewhere in the Act fall under this head. The VI Schedule contains goods taxed at special rates, such as some liquor and petroleum products.
 
  
The Act prescribes threshold limits for VAT registration - dealers with a taxable turnover of over Rs.40.00 lacs, in a tax period of 12 months, are mandatorily registered as VAT dealers. Dealers with a taxable turnover, in a tax period of 12 months, between Rs.5.00 to 40.00 lacs are registered as Turnover Tax (TOT) dealers. While the former category of dealers are eligible for input tax credit, the latter category of dealers are not. A VAT dealer pays tax at the rate specifed in the Schedules. The sales of a TOT dealer are all taxable at 1%. A VAT dealer has to file a monthly return disclosing purchases and sales. A TOT dealer has to file a quarterly return disclosing only sale turnovers. While a VAT dealer can buy goods for business from anywhere in the country, a TOT dealer is barred from buying outside the State of A.P.  
+
Clearly, because of their '''time preferences for present as against future consumption'''. These time preferences govern people's allocation between present and future. Every individual, given his money "income"---defined in conventional terms---and his value scales, will allocate that income in the most desired proportion between consumption and investment. Any other allocation of such income, any different proportions, would therefore satisfy his wants and desires to a lesser extent and lower his position on his value scale.  
  
The Act appears to be the most liberal VAT law in India. It has simplified the registration procedures and provides for across the board input tax credit (with a few exceptions) for business transactions.{{Verify source|date=April 2007}} A unique feature of registration in Andhra Pradesh is the facility of voluntary VAT registration and input tax credit for start-ups.
 
  
The Act also provides for transitional relief (TR) for goods on hand as of 1 April 2005. However, these goods ought to have been purchased from registered dealers between 1 April 2005 to 31 March 2006. This is a bold step compared to the 3 months TR provided by several developed countries.
+
It is therefore incorrect to say that an income tax levies an extra burden on savings and investment; it penalizes an individual's entire standard of living, present and future. An income tax does not penalize saving per se any more than it penalizes consumption.
  
The Act not only provides for tax refunds for exporters (refund of tax paid on inputs used in the manufacture of goods exported), it also provides for refund of tax in cases where the inputs are taxed at 12.5% and outputs are taxed at 4%.
 
  
The VAT Act in Andhra Pradesh is administered by the Commercial Taxes Department (department to collect VAT and other taxes) using a networked software package called VATIS. The personnel were trained prior to the Act coming into force. VATIS is used to process documents and forms received and to generate registration certificates and tax demand notices.
+
"......Having challenged the merits of the goal of taxing only consumption and freeing savings from taxation, we can now proceed to deny the very possibility of achieving that goal, i.e., we maintain that a consumption tax will devolve, willy-nilly, into a tax on income and therefore on savings as well. In short, that even if, for the sake of argument, we should want to tax only consumption and not income, we should not be able to do so...." ( Rothbard, 1977 ).
  
VAT, to be successful, relies on voluntary tax compliance. Since VAT believes in self assessments, dealers are required to maintain proper records, issue tax invoices, file correct tax returns etc. The opposite seems to be happening in India. Businesses are still run on traditional lines. Cash transactions are order of the day. The unorganised sector dominates the market. The hope of higher tax compliance and lesser evasion is still a far cry in Andhra Pradesh. This is reflected in the high percentage of return defaulters (14%), credit returns (35%) and nil returns (20%). That is, roughly 70% of VAT dealers are presently not paying any tax. Filing of credit returns is rampant among FMCG, Consumer Durables, Drugs and Medicines and Fertilizers. The margins are low in this sector (ranging between 2 to 5%). The value addition is not enough to yield revenue as of now. Credits offered by manufacturers compounds the problem. The question is, in a typical purchases and sales scenario, can there be more output tax than input tax? When purchases consistently exceed sales, can output tax exceed input tax? If a VAT dealer can balance his/her purchases and sales, can there be a net tax to the State? Is there a mathematical model or paradigm which can give value added tax and which can reduce the percentage of credit returns? There are no ready answers for these queries. The only remedy seems to be the restriction of input tax to the corresponding purchase value of goods put to sales. In fact a two tier system can be adopted to counter the credit returns - allow full input tax to manufacturers and restrict input tax to the purchase value of goods put to sale to traders. Restricting input tax to 4% in the case of inter state sales and in the case of products taxable at 12.5% seems to be another solution.
 
  
===Mexico===<!This section is linked from [[Vicente Fox]] >
+
We can see it on a simple example. Let us take a, seemingly straightforward, tax plan that would exempt saving and tax only consumption. Let us take Mr. Jones, who earns an annual income of $100,000. His time preferences lead him to spend 90 percent of his income on consumption, and save-and-invest the other 10 percent. On this assumption, he will spend $90,000 a year on consumption, and save-and-invest the other $10,000.
  
''Impuesto al Valor Agregado'' ('''IVA''', "[[value-added tax]]" in [[Spanish (language)|Spanish]]) is a [[tax]] applied in [[Mexico]] and other countries of [[Latin America]] and [[Spain]]. In [[Chile]] it is called ''Impuesto a las Ventas y Servicios'', in Spain ''Impuesto sobre el Valor Añadido'' and in [[Peru]] it is called ''Impuesto General a las Ventas'' or ''IGV''.
 
  
Prior to the IVA, a similar tax called ''impuesto a las ventas'' ("sales tax") had been applied in Mexico. In September, 1966, the first attempt to apply the IVA took place when revenue experts declared that the IVA should be a modern equivalent of the sales tax as it occurred in [[France]]. At the convention of the Inter-American Center of Revenue Administrators in April and May, 1967, the Mexican representation declared that the application of a value-added tax would not be possible in Mexico at the time. In November, 1967, other experts declared that although this is one of the most equitable indirect taxes, its application in Mexico could not take place.
+
Let us assume now that the government levies a 20 percent tax on Jones's income, and that his time-preference schedule remains the same. The ratio of his consumption to savings will still be 90:10, and so, after-tax income now being $80,000, his consumption spending will be $72,000 and his saving-investment $8,000 per year ( NOTE [2] ).
  
In response to these statements, direct sampling of members in the private sector took place as well as field trips to the [[Europe]]an countries this tax was applied or it was soon to be applied. In 1969, the first attempt to substitute the mercantile-revenue tax for the value-added tax took place. On December 29, 1978 the Federal government published the official application of the tax beginning on January 1, 1980 in the Official Journal of the Federation ([[Diario Oficial de la Federación]]).
 
  
===New Zealand===
+
Suppose now that instead of an income tax, the government follows the [[Irving Fisher]] scheme and levies a 20 percent annual tax on Jones's consumption. Fisher maintained that such a tax would fall only on consumption, and not on Jones's savings. '''But this claim is incorrect, since Jones's entire savings-investment is based solely on the possibility of his future consumption, which will be taxed equally'''.
  
Goods and Services Tax (GST) is a Value Added Tax introduced in [[New Zealand]] in 1986, which is currently 12.5%. It is notable for exempting few items from the tax...
+
Since future consumption will be taxed, we assume, at the same rate as consumption at present, we cannot conclude that savings in the long run receives any tax exemption or special encouragement. There will therefore be no shift by Jones in favor of savings-and-investment due to a consumption tax ( NOTE [3]).
  
===Australia===
 
  
Goods and Services Tax (GST) is a Value Added Tax introduced in [[Australia]] in 2000 which is collected by the Federal government but given to state governments.
+
In sum, any payment of taxes to the government, whether they be consumption or income, necessarily reduces Jones's net income. Since his time preference schedule remains the same, Jones will therefore reduce his consumption and his savings proportionately. The consumption tax will be shifted by Jones until it becomes equivalent to a lower rate of tax on his own income.  
  
===United States===
+
If Jones still spends 90 percent of his net income on consumption, and 10 percent on savings-investment, his net income will be reduced by $15,000, instead of $20,000, and his consumption will now total $76,000, and his savings-investment $9,000. In other words, Jones's 20 percent consumption tax will become equivalent to a 15 percent tax on his income, and he will arrange his consumption-savings proportions accordingly (NOTE [4]).
  
In the [[United States]], the state of [[Michigan]] uses a form of VAT known as the "Single Business Tax" (SBT) as its form of general business taxation. It is the only state in the U.S. to use a VAT. When it was adopted in 1975, it replaced seven business taxes, including a [[corporate income tax]]. On August 9, 2006, the Michigan legislature approved voter-initiated legislation to repeal the Single Business Tax. The repeal will be effective after December 31, 2007.<ref>[http://www.crcmich.org/TaxOutline/Business/sbt.html Single Business Tax - Outline of the Michigan Tax System], Citizens Research Council of Michigan, ''January 24, 2007''</ref>
+
===History of VAT in OECD and Tax burden comparison with USA ===
 +
Some statistical comparison between USA and EC-15 ( i.e. the original 15 European states prior to enlargement in 2004.
  
Most states have sales taxes charged to the end buyer only. State sales taxes range from 0%-13% and municipalities often add an extra local sales tax <ref>[http://www.town-usa.com/statetax/statetaxlist.html], State Tax Rates, ''July 14, 2007''</ref>. In many stores, the price tags and/or advertised prices do not include the taxes, these will be added at the cash register before the customer pays. In many states, no sales tax is charged for services. This is a key difference between most sales taxes levied throughout the United States and the value added taxes in other countries.
+
====VATs Associated with Higher Aggregate Tax Burdens====
 +
*“Taxes as a Percent of GDP”:….  1967………………………...2002
 +
USA……………………………….25. 3%....................................29. 8 %
 +
EU-15……………………………..25. 5 %.................................. 42.1 %
 +
Source: Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development, Revenue Statistics, 1965–2003 (Paris: OECD Publications, 2004)
 +
====Burden of Government ( Spending and Debts ): the U.S. vs. Europe====
  
==Tax Rates==
+
*“Government Spending as Percent of GDP”
===EU countries===
+
USA……………………………35.7 %
{| class="wikitable"
+
EU-15………………………….47. 6 %
|-  
+
*“Government Debt  as Percent of GDP”
! rowspan=2 | Country
+
USA……………………………26. 6%
! colspan="2" | Rate
+
EU-15………………………….50.1%
! rowspan=2 | Abbr.
+
Source: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, OECD
! rowspan=2 | Name
+
in Figures, 2004 ed., at www1.oecd.org/publications/e-book/0104071E.pdf (May 9, 2005).
|-
 
! Standard
 
! Reduced
 
|-
 
| {{AUT}}
 
| 20%
 
| 12% or 10%
 
| USt.  
 
| Umsatzsteuer
 
|-
 
| {{BEL}}
 
| 21%
 
| 12% or 6%
 
| BTW <br /> TVA <br /> MWSt
 
| Belasting over de toegevoegde waarde <br /> Taxe sur la Valeur Ajoutée <br /> Mehrwertsteuer
 
|-
 
| {{BUL}}
 
| 20%
 
| 7%
 
| ДДС
 
| Данък Добавена Стойност
 
|-
 
| {{CYP}}
 
| 15%
 
| 5%
 
| ΦΠΑ
 
| Φόρος Προστιθεμένης Αξίας
 
|-
 
| {{CZE}}
 
| 19%
 
| 5%
 
| DPH
 
| Daň z přidané hodnoty
 
|-
 
| {{DEN}}
 
| 25%
 
|
 
| moms
 
| Merværdiomsætningsafgift
 
|-
 
| {{EST}}
 
| 18%
 
| 5%
 
| km
 
| käibemaks
 
|-
 
| {{FIN}}
 
| 22%
 
| 17% or 8%
 
| ALV<br />Moms
 
| Arvonlisävero<br />Mervärdesskatt
 
|-
 
| {{FRA}}
 
| 19.6%
 
| 5.5% or 2.1%
 
| TVA
 
| Taxe sur la Valeur Ajoutée
 
|-  
 
| {{DEU}}
 
| 19%
 
| 7%
 
| MwSt./USt.
 
| Mehrwertsteuer/Umsatzsteuer
 
|-
 
| {{GRE}}
 
| 19%
 
| 9% or 4.5%<br />(reduced by 30% to 13%, 6% and 3% on islands)
 
| ΦΠΑ
 
| Φόρος Προστιθέμενης Αξίας
 
|-
 
| {{HUN}}
 
| 20%
 
| 5%
 
| ÁFA
 
| általános forgalmi adó
 
|-
 
| {{IRL}}
 
| 21%
 
| 13.5%, 4.8% or 0%
 
| CBL<br />VAT
 
| Cáin Bhreisluacha<br />Value Added Tax
 
|-  
 
| {{ITA}}
 
| 20%
 
| 10%, 6%, or 4%
 
| IVA
 
| Imposta sul Valore Aggiunto
 
|-
 
| {{LAT}}
 
| 18%
 
| 5%
 
| PVN
 
| Pievienotās vērtības nodoklis
 
|-
 
| {{LTU}}
 
| 18%
 
| 9% or 5%
 
| PVM
 
| Pridėtinės vertės mokestis
 
|-
 
| {{LUX}}
 
| 15%
 
| 12%, 9%, 6%, or 3%
 
| TVA
 
| Taxe sur la Valeur Ajoutée
 
|-
 
| {{MLT}}
 
| 18%
 
| 5%
 
| TVM
 
| Taxxa tal-Valur Miżjud
 
|-
 
| {{NLD}}
 
| 19%
 
| 6%
 
| BTW
 
| Belasting over de toegevoegde waarde
 
|-
 
| {{POL}}
 
| 22%
 
| 7%, 3% or 0%
 
| PTU/VAT
 
| Podatek od towarów i usług
 
|-
 
| {{POR}}
 
| 21%
 
| 12% or 5%
 
| IVA
 
| Imposto sobre o Valor Acrescentado
 
|-
 
| {{ROM}}
 
| 19%
 
| 9%
 
| TVA
 
| Taxa pe valoarea adăugată
 
|-
 
| {{SVK}}
 
| 19%
 
| 10%
 
| DPH
 
| Daň z pridanej hodnoty
 
|-
 
| {{SLO}}
 
| 20%
 
| 8.5%
 
| DDV
 
| Davek na dodano vrednost
 
|-
 
| {{ESP}}
 
| 16%
 
| 7% or 4%
 
| IVA
 
| Impuesto sobre el valor añadido
 
|-
 
| {{SWE}}
 
| 25%
 
| 12% or 6%
 
| Moms
 
| Mervärdesskatt
 
|-
 
| {{UK}}
 
| 17.5%
 
| 5% or 0%
 
| VAT
 
| Value Added Tax
 
|}
 
  
===Non-EU countries===
+
===GST- Federal Consumption Tax in Canada===
{| class="wikitable"
+
Most of what was said above about the VAT possible, and in some countries real, problems  holds for Canada as well. The following excerpts tells it all : “…the GST ( General Sales Tax ) warrants greater scrutiny. While the GST was an advance in some respects over the manufacturers sales tax, it has significant deficiencies of its own. First, it is relatively costly to administer and places major compliance burdens on business, especially small firms, as well as on consumers. Second, its base is far from comprehensive, necessitating a higher rate, creating consumer inefficiencies, and introducing numerous practical complexities. Third, the GST adds an entirely new layer of difficulties for operation of the tax system, such as for employee fringe benefits and services sourced abroad. Fourth, the input tax credit mechanism is open to abuse, such as the recently reported evasion by fictitious exporters costing scores of millions of dollars in revenues….”( Kesselman, 1997)
|-
 
! rowspan=2 | Country
 
! colspan="2" | Rate
 
! rowspan=2 | Local name
 
|-
 
! Standard
 
! Reduced
 
|-
 
| {{ARG}}
 
| 21%
 
| 10.5% or 0%
 
| IVA = ''Impuesto al Valor Agregado''
 
|-
 
| {{AUS}}
 
| 10%
 
| 0%
 
| GST = ''[[Goods and Services Tax (Australia)|Goods and Services Tax]]''
 
|-  
 
| {{BIH}}
 
| 17%
 
|
 
| PDV = ''porez na dodatu vrijednost''
 
|-
 
| {{CAN}}
 
| 6%-14%[[#CanadaRate|<sup id=fn1>1</sup>]]
 
| 4.5%
 
| GST = ''[[Goods and Services Tax (Canada)|Goods and Services Tax]], TPS = Taxe sur les produits et services, PST = [[Taxation_in_Canada#Sales_taxes|Provincial Sales Tax]], HST = Harmonized Sales Tax''
 
|-
 
| {{CHI}}
 
| 19%
 
|
 
| IVA = ''Impuesto al Valor Agregado''
 
|-
 
| {{COL}}
 
| 16%
 
|
 
| IVA = ''Impuesto sobre el Valor Agregado''
 
|-
 
| {{PRC}}[[#Footnote2|<sup id=fn2>2</sup>]]
 
| 17%
 
| 6% or 3%
 
| {{lang|zh-s|增值税}} ([[pinyin]]:''zēng zhí shuì'')
 
|-
 
| {{HRV}}
 
| 22%
 
| 0%
 
| PDV = ''Porez na dodanu vrijednost''
 
|-
 
| {{DOM}}
 
| 6%
 
| 12% or 0%
 
|-
 
| {{ECU}}
 
| 12%
 
|
 
| IVA = ''Impuesto al Valor Agregado''
 
|-
 
| {{EGY}}
 
|10%
 
|
 
| ''GST = Goods and Sales Tax''
 
|-
 
| {{ESA}}
 
| 13%
 
|
 
| IVA = ''Impuesto al Valor Agregado''
 
|-
 
| {{GEO}}
 
| 18%
 
| 0%
 
| ''DGhG = Damatebuli Ghirebulebis gdasakhadi'' დღგ = დამატებული ღირებულების გადასახადი
 
|-
 
| {{GUY}}
 
| 16%
 
| 14%
 
|-
 
| {{ISL}}
 
| 24.5%
 
| 7%[[#IcelandChanges|<sup id=fn3>3</sup>]]
 
| VSK = ''Virðisaukaskattur''
 
|-
 
| {{IND}}[[#India|<sup id=fn4>4</sup>]]
 
| 12.5%
 
| 4%, 1%, or 0%
 
| VAT = Valued Added Tax
 
|-
 
| {{INA}}
 
| 10%
 
| 5%
 
| PPN = Pajak Pertambahan Nilai
 
|-
 
| {{ISR}}[[#Eilat|<sup id=fn10>10</sup>]]
 
| 15.5%[[#IsraelChanges|<sup id=fn5>5</sup>]]
 
|
 
| Ma'am = ''מס ערך מוסף''
 
|-
 
| {{JPN}}
 
|5%
 
|
 
| [[Consumption tax]] = 消費税
 
|-
 
| {{KOR}}
 
| 10%
 
|
 
| VAT = 부가세(附加稅, ''Bugase'') = 부가가치세(附加價値稅, ''Bugagachise'')
 
|-
 
| {{JEY}}[[#Jersey|<sup id=fn9>9</sup>]]
 
| 3%
 
| 0%
 
| ''GST = Goods and Sales Tax''
 
|-
 
| {{JOR}}
 
|16%
 
|
 
| ''GST = Goods and Sales Tax''
 
|-
 
| {{KAZ}}
 
|14%
 
|
 
|-
 
| {{KSV}}
 
|15%
 
|0%
 
|
 
|-
 
| {{LBN}}
 
|10%
 
|
 
| TVA = ''Taxe sur la valeur ajoutée''
 
|-
 
| {{MDA}}
 
| 20%
 
| 5%
 
|TVA = ''Taxa pe Valoarea Adăugată''
 
|-
 
| {{MKD}}
 
| 18%
 
| 5%
 
|ДДВ = ''Данок на Додадена Вредност''
 
|-
 
| {{MYS}}[[#MalaysiaGST|<sup id=fn6>6</sup>]]
 
| 5%
 
|
 
|-
 
| {{MEX}}
 
| 15%
 
| 0%
 
|IVA = ''Impuesto al Valor Agregado''
 
|-
 
| {{MNE}}
 
| 17%
 
|
 
| PDV = ''Porez na dodatu vrijednost''
 
|-
 
| {{NZL}}
 
| 12.5%
 
|
 
| GST = ''[[Goods and Services Tax (New Zealand)|Goods and Services Tax]]''
 
|-
 
| {{NOR}}
 
| 25%
 
| 14% or 8%
 
| MVA = ''Merverdiavgift'' (informally ''moms'')
 
|-
 
| {{PAK}}
 
| 7.5%
 
| 1% or 0%
 
|-
 
| {{PAN}}
 
| 5%
 
|
 
| ITBMS = ''Impuesto de Transferencia de Bienes Muebles y Servicios''
 
|-
 
| {{PAR}}
 
| 10%
 
| 5%
 
| GST= ''Impuesto al Valor Agregado''
 
|-
 
| {{PER}}
 
| 19%
 
|
 
| IGV = ''Impuesto General a la Ventas''
 
|-
 
| {{PHL}}
 
| 12%[[#PhilippinesRate|<sup id=fn7>7</sup>]]
 
|
 
| RVAT = '' RVAT or Reformed Value Added Tax'', locally known as ''Karagdagang Buwis''
 
|-
 
| {{RUS}}
 
| 18%
 
| 10% or 0%
 
|НДС ''NDS'' = Налог на добавленную стоимость ''Nalog na dobavlennuyu stoimost''
 
|-
 
| {{SRB}}
 
| 18%
 
| 8% or 0%
 
| PDV = ''Porez na dodatu vrednost''
 
|-
 
| {{SIN}}
 
| 7%
 
|
 
| GST = ''[[Goods and Services Tax (Singapore)|Goods and Services Tax]]''
 
|-
 
| {{ZAF}}
 
| 14%
 
| 0%
 
| VAT = ''Valued Added Tax''
 
|-
 
| {{LKA}}
 
| 15%
 
|
 
|-
 
| {{CHE}}
 
| 7.6%
 
| 3.6% or 2.4%
 
| MWST = Mehrwertsteuer, TVA = Taxe sur la valeur ajoutée, IVA = Imposta sul valore aggiunto, VAT = Value Added Tax
 
|-
 
| {{THA}}
 
| 7%
 
|
 
|-
 
| {{TRI}}
 
| 15%
 
|
 
|
 
|-
 
| {{TUR}}
 
| 18%
 
| 8% or 1%
 
| KDV= Katma değer vergisi
 
|-
 
| {{UKR}}
 
| 20%
 
| 0%
 
|ПДВ= ''Податок на додану вартість''
 
|-
 
| {{URU}}
 
| 23%
 
| 14%
 
| IVA = ''Impuesto al Valor Agregado''
 
|-
 
| {{VIE}}
 
| 10%
 
| 5% or 0%
 
| GTGT = ''Gia Tri Gia Tang''
 
|-
 
| {{VEN}}
 
| 9%
 
| 8%
 
| IVA = ''Impuesto al Valor Agregado''
 
|}
 
<div class="references-small">
 
<cite id=CanadaRate>[[#fn1|Note 1]]</cite>: Some Canadian provinces collect 14% for [[harmonized sales tax]], a combined federal/provincial VAT. In the rest, the federal GST is 6% and if the province charges sales tax it is separate and is not a VAT. No real "reduced rate" but rebates are generally available for new housing effectively reducing the tax to 4.5%
 
  
<cite id="Footnote2">[[#fn2|Note 2]]</cite>: These taxes do not apply in [[Hong Kong]] and [[Macau]], which are [[public finance|financially]] independent as [[special administrative region]]s.
+
Under the above comments and  some of the statistics on the tax burden differentials in OECD vs. USA, there is not much hope for lowering Canadian over-all tax  level at least to the U.S. one anytime soon. Even if --- and maybe because of it --- the latest recommendations call for: (1) repealing GST and substituting it with VAT, (2) harmonizing provincial sales taxes with GST , or (3) combining GST with VAT.
  
<cite id="IcelandChanges">[[#fn3|Note 3]]</cite>: The reduced rate was 14% until 1 March 2007, when it was lowered to 7%. The reduced rate applies to heating costs, printed matter, restaurant bills, hotel stays, and most food.
 
  
<cite id="India">[[#fn4|Note 4]]</cite>: VAT is not implemented in 2 of India's 28 states.
+
==Conclusion==
 +
There are obviously two contradicting views on the very basics of  VAT. Let us seek a help to this conundrum from a genuine free-market approach to Jean-Baptiste Say, who contributed considerably more to economics than [[Say's Law]]. Say was under no illusion that taxation is voluntary nor that government spending contributes productive services to the economy. Say pointed out that, in taxation, "……The government exacts from a taxpayer the payment of a given tax in the shape of money. To meet this demand, the taxpayer exchanges part of the products at his disposal for coin, which he pays to the tax-gatherers….." ( Say,  1880 ).
 +
Eventually, the government spends the money on its own needs, so that "in the end . . . this value is consumed; and then the portion of wealth, which passes from the hands of the taxpayer into those of the tax-gatherer, is destroyed and annihilated." Note, that as in the case of the later Calhoun, Say sees that taxation creates two conflicting classes, the taxpayers and the tax-gatherers. Were it not for taxes, the taxpayer would have spent his money on his own consumption. As it is, "….The state . . . enjoys the satisfaction resulting from that consumption….."( ibid. ).
 +
Taxation, then, for Say is the transfer of a portion of the national products from the hands of individuals to those of the government, for the purpose of meeting the public consumption of expenditure.” . . . It is virtually a burthen imposed upon individuals, either in a separate or corporate character, by the ruling power . . . for the purpose of supplying the consumption it may think proper to make at their expense…..”( ibid, p. 446 ). 
 +
But taxation, for Say, is not merely a zero-sum game. By levying a burden on the producers, he points out, taxes, over time, 'cripple production itself. Writes Say:
 +
“…..Taxation deprives the producer of a product, which he would otherwise have the option of deriving a personal gratification from, if consumed . . . or of turning to profit, if he preferred to devote it to an useful employment. . . Therefore, the subtraction of a product must needs diminish, instead of augmenting, productive power……( ibid,  p. 447 ).
 +
J. B. Say's policy recommendation was crystal clear and consistent with his analysis and that of  our VAT treatise: "…..The best scheme of [public] finance is, to spend as little as possible; and the best tax is always the lightest….."( ibid. ,1880 ). To this, there is nothing more to add.
  
<cite id=IsraelChanges>[[#fn5|Note 5]]</cite>: The VAT in Israel is in the process of being gradually reduced. It was reduced from 18% to 17% on March 2004, to 16.5% on September 2005, and was set to its current rate on July 1, 2006. There are plans to further reduce it in the near future, but they depend on political changes in the Israeli parliament.
 
  
<cite id="MalaysiaGST">[[#fn6|Note 6]]</cite>: In the 2005 Budget, the government announced that GST would be introduced in January 2007. Many details have not yet been confirmed but it has been stated that essential goods and small businesses would be exempted or zero rated. Rates have not yet been established as of June 2007.
+
===Notes and Reference===
  
<cite id=PhilippinesRate>[[#fn7|Note 7]]</cite>: The [[President of the Philippines]] has the power to raise the tax to 12% after January 1, 2006. The tax was raised to 12% on February 1.
+
*Kesselman, J., “Public Policies To Combat Child Poverty: Goals and Options,” in A New Social Vision for Canada? Perspectives on the Federal Discussion Paper on Social Policy Reform, Keith Banting and Ken Battle, eds. Queen’s University, School of Policy Studies, Kingston, Ont. 1994, pp. 73-97
  
<cite id="Jersey">[[#fn9|Note 9]]</cite>: The [[States of Jersey]] has for the few years, preparing for the introduction of a goods and sales tax to plug a large budget deficit in the island's government budget. It will be held at a flat rate of 3%, with possible exceptions to local food (food not subject to an “island tax” of 5%) and children's clothing.
+
*Kesselman, JGeneral Payroll Taxes: Economics, Politics, and Design, Canadian Tax  Foundation Toronto, 1997
  
<cite id="Eilat">[[#fn10|Note 10]]</cite>: Except Eilat, where VAT is not raised.<ref>[http://www.eccb06.org/new_pages/general_info/gen_info_fqs.html#taxRefund VAT in Eilat], ECCB</ref>
 
</div>
 
  
==VAT registered ==
+
*Rothbard, Murray,  “Consumption  Tax : A Critique” , Review of Austrian Economics, Volume 7, No. 2, , 1994, pp. 75–90.
''VAT registered'' means registered for [[VAT]] purposes, i.e. entered into an official VAT payers register of a country. Both natural persons and legal entities can be VAT registered. Countries that use VAT have established different thresholds for remuneration derived by natural persons/legal entities during a calendar year (or a different period) by exceeding which the VAT registration is compulsory. Natural persons/legal entities that are VAT registered are obliged to calculate VAT on certain goods/services that they supply and pay VAT into particular state budget. VAT registered persons/entities are entitled to VAT deduction under legislatory regulations of particular country. The introduction of a VAT can reduce the cash economy because businesses that wish to buy and sell with other VAT registered businesses must themselves be VAT registered.
 
  
==Notes==
+
* Rothbard, Murray, Power and Market: Government and the Economy, 2nd ed. Sheed Andrews & McMeel, Kansas City, 1977
<references/>
+
*[1] It is particularly poignant, on or near any April 15, to contemplate the dictum of Father Navarrete, that "the only agreeable country is the one where no one is afraid of tax collectors," Chafuen, Christians for Freedom, p. 73. Also see Murray N. Rothbard, "Review of A. Chafuen, Christians for Freedom: Late Scholastic Economics," International Philosophical Quarterly 28 (March 1988): 112–14. For a fuller treatment, and a discussion of who is being robbed by whom, see Murray N. Rothbard, Power and Market: Government and the Economy, 2nd ed. (Kansas City: Sheed Andrews & McMeel, 1977), pp. 120–21
 +
*[2] We set aside the fact that, at the lower amount of money assets left to him, Jones's time preference rate, given his time preference schedule, will be higher, so that his consumption will be higher, and his savings lower, than we have assumed.
 +
*[3] In fact, per note [2], supra, there will be a shift in favor of consumption because a diminished amount of money will shift the taxpayer's time preference rate in the direction of consumption. Hence, paradoxically, a pure tax on consumption will and up taxing savings more than consumption! See Rothbard, Power and Market, pp. 108–11.
 +
*[4] lf net income is defined as gross income minus amount paid in taxes, and for Jones, consumption is 90 percent of net income, a 20 percent consumption tax on $100,000 income will be tantamount to a 15 percent tax on this income. Rothbard, Power and Market, pp. 108–11. The basic formula is that net income,
 +
 +
where G=gross income, t=the tax rate on consumption, and c, consumption as percent of net income, are givens of the problem, and N = G – T by definition, where T is the amount paid in consumption tax.
 +
*Say, Jean-Baptiste A Treatise on Political Economy, 6th ed. (Philadelphia: Claxton, Remsen & Heffelfinger, 1880), pp. 412–415, 446; also see Murray N. Rothbard, "The Myth of Neutral Taxation," Cato Journal 1 (Fall 1981): 551–54.
  
==References==
 
>
 
* '''MOMS''', Politikens Nudansk Leksikon 2002, ISBN 87-604-1578-9
 
* [http://www.pdicai.org/vatap/APVATACT_2005.pdf Andhra Pradesh Value Added Tax Act, 2005], Andhra Pradesh Gazette Extraordinary, 25 March 2005, retrieved on 16 March 2007.
 
  
  

Revision as of 15:03, 3 September 2007


The Value Added Tax (VAT) taxes all business profit and labor. Profit being gross receipts minus all business expenses including the 'tax' on labor which is considered a cost of doing business. Profit and labor could be lumped together by subtracting all other business expenses from gross receipts and then taxing the remainder at a uniform VAT tax rate.

The cost of materials, subcomponents, tools, equipment, facilities, supplies, etc, and any services purchased from other businesses isn't taxed (again) under the VAT. Those purchases would have already been subjected to the VAT by the supplying businesses.

VAT in more details

The VAT was invented by a French economist in 1954. Maurice Lauré, joint director of the French tax authority, the Direction générale des impôts, as taxe sur la valeur ajoutée (TVA in French) was first to introduce VAT with effect from 10 April 1954 for large businesses, and extended over time to all business sectors. In France, it is the most important source of state finance, accounting for approximately 45% of state revenues.

The value-added tax ( VAT ) that extends through the retail level is levied on each firm in the production and distribution chain, from the extraction of raw materials through the manufacturing and distribution processes, to the last sale to final customers. Thus, under a comprehensive value-added tax, all businesses, not just those that sell at retail, would pay tax on their sales. An important characteristic of a value-added tax is that tax is applied only to the value added by the firm, that is, to the excess of its sales over its purchases of goods from other business firms.

The VAT is usually collected by the tax credit method; each firm applies the tax rate to its taxable sales, but is allowed a credit for value-added tax paid on its purchases of goods and services for business use, including the tax paid on purchases of capital equipment under a consumption-type value-added tax. As a result, the only tax for which no credit would be allowed would be that collected on sales made to households, rather than to businesses.


Since the sum of the values added at all stages in the production and distribution of a good are equal to the retail selling price of the good, the revenue base of a retail sales tax and a value-added tax with the same coverage are theoretically identical, and a given tax rate will yield the same amount of tax revenue under either approach and under equal conditions of implementation, e.g., no exceptions, exemptions, etc.

Thus, despite its multistage character, a value-added tax is very much like a retail sales tax in that it is a tax on expenditures by consumers or, in other words, it is just another type of consumption tax.

Comparison of VAT with a Sales tax

Retail sales tax, the familiar percentage tax on retail sales, is one type of consumption tax. Of the various forms of consumption taxes, the sales tax surely has the great advantage for most of tax-payers of eliminating the despotic power of the government over the life of every individual, as in the income tax, or over each business firm, as we shall see the VAT might do. Sales tax also does not distort the production structure as would the VAT, and it would not skew individual preferences as would specific excise taxes ( Rothbard, 1994 ).


The VAT consumption tax, proposed in the U.S., imposes a bit of hierarchical tax on the "value added" by each firm and business.

Here, instead of every individual, every business firm would be subjected to intense bureaucratic scrutiny, for each firm would be obliged to report its income and its expenditures, paying a designated tax on the net income.


This would tend to distort the structure of business. For one thing, there would be an incentive for uneconomic vertical integration, since the fewer the number of times a sale takes place, the fewer the imposed taxes. Also, as has been happening in European countries with experience of the VAT, a flourishing industry may arise in issuing phony vouchers, so that businesses can over-inflate their alleged expenditures, and reduce their reported value added.

Surely a sales tax, other things being equal, seems to be both simpler, less distorting of resources, and enormously less bureaucratic and despotic than the VAT. Indeed the VAT seems to have no clear advantage over the sales tax, except of course, if multiplying bureaucracy and bureaucratic power is considered a benefit ( ibid., 1994 ).


Several possible disadvantages of VAT

  • Growth of government ( see also “Administrative Costs”):

The United States stands almost alone among the developed countries of the free world in not levying a national sales tax. Virtually all of the members of the European Economic Community (EEC) employ a national value-added tax. Of the twenty-three ( original ) members of Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), only two countries — Japan and Turkey — use neither a value-added tax nor a general sales tax. In Canada, there is a bit similar national tax ---- apart from bewildering array of, by no means harmonized, provincial sales taxes --- called GST or General Sales tax.


The lack of a national sales tax ( e.g. VAT ) in the United States is reflected closely in the percentage of Gross Domestic Product (GDP) devoted to public use in the United States and in other countries. In 1982 total tax revenues at all levels of government averaged 30.5 percent of GDP in the United States. The comparable figure for the EEC countries was 40.1 percent and for the countries of the OECD, exclusive of the United States, it was 37.1 percent.

In the United States, sales taxes (state and local) took approximately 6 percentage points less of GDP than in the EEC and in the OECD (exclusive of the United States). It is not only sales taxes that are lower in the United States; corporate income and social security taxes also are substantially lower in the figures suggest that even if a sales tax were initially imposed as a partial replacement for the income tax in a revenue-neutral change, public spending in the United States would eventually be greater with a national sales tax than without one.

  • Regressivity:

A general sales tax --- as all types of consumption taxes inclusive of ( Retail ) sales tax ---- is often criticized as unfair to lower income individuals and families. There are two aspects to this equity argument: ( 1 ) The absolute burden of the tax on the lowest income groups, and the regressivity of the tax or the relatively higher burden of the tax at the lower income levels than at the higher. Simultaneously, ( 2 ) there are several alternatives for lessening the burden of the tax on the poor. For those individuals and families that are above the poverty level of income and thus subject to the income tax, the regressivity of a sales tax can be offset through the adjustment of income tax rates or through non-refundable credits against the income tax.

  • Effect on prices:

Assuming an accommodating monetary policy, a sales tax would almost certainly increase the price level by roughly the percentage it represents of consumption spending. That is, a 4 percent sales tax that applied to 75 percent of consumption expenditures would increase the general price level by about 3 percent.

Although this would be a one-time occurrence, not an annual increase, it might cause "ripples" of wage increases, because of cost-of-living adjustments ( ! ) and these could be reflected in further price increases. To the extent the sales tax replaced part of the income tax, there would be little offsetting reduction in prices or wages.

  • Administrative costs:

Administration of a Federal value-added tax would require substantial additional resources. The Internal Revenue Service estimates that once the administrative program was fully phased in, the annual administrative costs would run about $700 million (at 1984 prices), or about 0.4 percent of revenues from a 10 percent broad-based value-added tax. To administer a value-added tax, the IRS would require approximately 20,000 additional personnel.

  • Federal pre-emption:

States, and more recently local governments, consider the sales tax base their exclusive fiscal domain. Federal imposition of a sales tax might reduce somewhat the ability of state and local governments to tax that base and would therefore be seen by those governments as an unwelcome intrusion.


This concern could be reduced if Federal adoption of a retail sales tax led to increased cooperation between the various levels of governments in tax administration and collection. This cooperation would be much easier to achieve if the Federal Government adopted a retail sales tax than if it adopted a value-added tax. If the state and Federal tax bases were identical, state taxes could be collected by the Federal Government as it collected its own tax. Of course, a Federal sales tax could not simply be collected by the states, because of the current differences in state tax bases.

Possible Advantages of VAT

One of the more interesting theoretical arguments for a VAT is that the new tax would improve economic performance by facilitating a reduction in other taxes. According to some advocates, the additional revenue generated by a VAT—$37 billion for every percentage point, according to the Congressional Research Service15—could be used to lower, or perhaps even eliminate, personal and corporate income taxes.

Hence, if the VAT was actually used to eliminate all income taxes, this theory would have considerable merit. There is no doubt that personal and corporate income taxes do more damage per dollar raised than a VAT would.

A national sales tax ( VAT ) thus should have several major advantages over the current combination of national income tax and states’ ( provincial ) taxes. If it were used to replace part of the income tax, a Federal sales tax would allow even lower income tax rates. By taking pressure off the definition and measurement of taxable income, a sales tax would help reduce income tax avoidance and evasion as well as lessen the incentive to shelter income from the income tax. Based on consumption, rather than income, a national sales tax ( VAT ) would not discriminate against saving the way the income tax does ( about this issue look to the below paragraph.)

Accordingly, it may increase the level of private saving and generate a corresponding increase in capital formation and economic growth. A broad-based sales tax would almost certainly distort economic choices less than the income tax does. In contrast to the income tax, it would not discourage capital-intensive methods of production or risk taking and it would be neutral with regard to other major revenue sources.


Further implication of all of this means that goods and services purchased for business use are automatically freed from tax; by and large, only goods and services sold to households are ultimately taxed under the value-added tax. Tax auditors need only to check the purchasing firm to ensure that purchases for which a credit is claimed were used for business purposes. By comparison, it is more difficult under a retail sales tax to completely exempt all business purchases. Firms must provide exemption certificates to their suppliers to buy tax free, and auditors must check both the supplier and purchaser in cases of doubt.


At the state level, this system of exemption certificates applies only to goods purchased for resale or goods that become component parts or physical ingredients of produced goods; other purchases, such as machinery and equipment, are only exempt if specifically provided in the state statute. The end result is that not all business purchases are free of retail sales tax; about 20 percent of sales tax revenue is from taxing business purchases.

Another important advantage of the value-added form of sales tax is the fact that tax is collected as products move from stage to stage in the production-distribution process. Thus by the time a product reaches the retail stage, much of its total value has already been taxed.


To summarize: Theoretically, a VAT would be acceptable if it were combined with ratification of a constitutional amendment that permanently prohibits both the personal and corporate income taxes, but, unfortunately, this is an extremely unlikely scenario. In fact, as yet no nation has ever implemented a VAT (or a national sales tax) and used the money to eliminate all income taxes.


The Impossibility of Taxing Only Consumption

A few arguments of why VAT, as a consumption tax, cannot replace the income tax should be mentioned now.


Orthodox neoclassical economics has long maintained that, from the point of view of the taxed themselves, an income tax is "better than" an excise tax on a particular form of consumption, since, in addition to the total revenue extracted, which is assumed to be the same in both cases, the excise tax weights the levy heavily against a particular consumer good.


But, all through the comparison of the income as compared to an excise tax one thing is well experienced by every tax-payer in the U.S. ( and many other countries ). Income taxes are collected in the course of a coercive and even brutal examination of virtually every aspect of every taxpayer's life by the all-seeing, all-powerful Internal Revenue Service.

An excise tax, say, on whiskey or on movie admissions, will intrude directly on no one's life and income, but only into the sales of the movie theater or liquor store. It is quite feasible that, in evaluating the "superiority" or "inferiority" of different modes of taxation, even the most determined imbiber or moviegoer would cheerfully pay far higher prices for whiskey or movies than neoclassical economists contemplate, in order to avoid the long arm of the IRS ( NOTE [1] ).


However, the only coherent argument offered by advocates of consumption against income taxation is that of Irving Fisher, based on suggestions of John Stuart Mill. Fisher argued that, since the goal of all production is consumption, and since all capital goods are only way-stations on the way to consumption, the only genuine income is consumption spending. The conclusion is quickly drawn that therefore only consumption income, not what is generally called "income," should be subject to tax( Rothbard, 1977, pp. 98–100.)


The market, in short, knows all about the productive power of savings for the future, and allocates its expenditures accordingly. Yet even though people know that savings will yield them more future consumption, why don't they save all their current income?

Clearly, because of their time preferences for present as against future consumption. These time preferences govern people's allocation between present and future. Every individual, given his money "income"---defined in conventional terms---and his value scales, will allocate that income in the most desired proportion between consumption and investment. Any other allocation of such income, any different proportions, would therefore satisfy his wants and desires to a lesser extent and lower his position on his value scale.


It is therefore incorrect to say that an income tax levies an extra burden on savings and investment; it penalizes an individual's entire standard of living, present and future. An income tax does not penalize saving per se any more than it penalizes consumption.


"......Having challenged the merits of the goal of taxing only consumption and freeing savings from taxation, we can now proceed to deny the very possibility of achieving that goal, i.e., we maintain that a consumption tax will devolve, willy-nilly, into a tax on income and therefore on savings as well. In short, that even if, for the sake of argument, we should want to tax only consumption and not income, we should not be able to do so...." ( Rothbard, 1977 ).


We can see it on a simple example. Let us take a, seemingly straightforward, tax plan that would exempt saving and tax only consumption. Let us take Mr. Jones, who earns an annual income of $100,000. His time preferences lead him to spend 90 percent of his income on consumption, and save-and-invest the other 10 percent. On this assumption, he will spend $90,000 a year on consumption, and save-and-invest the other $10,000.


Let us assume now that the government levies a 20 percent tax on Jones's income, and that his time-preference schedule remains the same. The ratio of his consumption to savings will still be 90:10, and so, after-tax income now being $80,000, his consumption spending will be $72,000 and his saving-investment $8,000 per year ( NOTE [2] ).


Suppose now that instead of an income tax, the government follows the Irving Fisher scheme and levies a 20 percent annual tax on Jones's consumption. Fisher maintained that such a tax would fall only on consumption, and not on Jones's savings. But this claim is incorrect, since Jones's entire savings-investment is based solely on the possibility of his future consumption, which will be taxed equally.

Since future consumption will be taxed, we assume, at the same rate as consumption at present, we cannot conclude that savings in the long run receives any tax exemption or special encouragement. There will therefore be no shift by Jones in favor of savings-and-investment due to a consumption tax ( NOTE [3]).


In sum, any payment of taxes to the government, whether they be consumption or income, necessarily reduces Jones's net income. Since his time preference schedule remains the same, Jones will therefore reduce his consumption and his savings proportionately. The consumption tax will be shifted by Jones until it becomes equivalent to a lower rate of tax on his own income.

If Jones still spends 90 percent of his net income on consumption, and 10 percent on savings-investment, his net income will be reduced by $15,000, instead of $20,000, and his consumption will now total $76,000, and his savings-investment $9,000. In other words, Jones's 20 percent consumption tax will become equivalent to a 15 percent tax on his income, and he will arrange his consumption-savings proportions accordingly (NOTE [4]).

History of VAT in OECD and Tax burden comparison with USA

Some statistical comparison between USA and EC-15 ( i.e. the original 15 European states prior to enlargement in 2004.

VATs Associated with Higher Aggregate Tax Burdens

  • “Taxes as a Percent of GDP”:…. 1967………………………...2002

USA……………………………….25. 3%....................................29. 8 % EU-15……………………………..25. 5 %.................................. 42.1 % Source: Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development, Revenue Statistics, 1965–2003 (Paris: OECD Publications, 2004)

Burden of Government ( Spending and Debts ): the U.S. vs. Europe

  • “Government Spending as Percent of GDP”

USA……………………………35.7 % EU-15………………………….47. 6 %

  • “Government Debt as Percent of GDP”

USA……………………………26. 6% EU-15………………………….50.1% Source: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, OECD in Figures, 2004 ed., at www1.oecd.org/publications/e-book/0104071E.pdf (May 9, 2005).

GST- Federal Consumption Tax in Canada

Most of what was said above about the VAT possible, and in some countries real, problems holds for Canada as well. The following excerpts tells it all : “…the GST ( General Sales Tax ) warrants greater scrutiny. While the GST was an advance in some respects over the manufacturers sales tax, it has significant deficiencies of its own. First, it is relatively costly to administer and places major compliance burdens on business, especially small firms, as well as on consumers. Second, its base is far from comprehensive, necessitating a higher rate, creating consumer inefficiencies, and introducing numerous practical complexities. Third, the GST adds an entirely new layer of difficulties for operation of the tax system, such as for employee fringe benefits and services sourced abroad. Fourth, the input tax credit mechanism is open to abuse, such as the recently reported evasion by fictitious exporters costing scores of millions of dollars in revenues….”( Kesselman, 1997)

Under the above comments and some of the statistics on the tax burden differentials in OECD vs. USA, there is not much hope for lowering Canadian over-all tax level at least to the U.S. one anytime soon. Even if --- and maybe because of it --- the latest recommendations call for: (1) repealing GST and substituting it with VAT, (2) harmonizing provincial sales taxes with GST , or (3) combining GST with VAT.


Conclusion

There are obviously two contradicting views on the very basics of VAT. Let us seek a help to this conundrum from a genuine free-market approach to Jean-Baptiste Say, who contributed considerably more to economics than Say's Law. Say was under no illusion that taxation is voluntary nor that government spending contributes productive services to the economy. Say pointed out that, in taxation, "……The government exacts from a taxpayer the payment of a given tax in the shape of money. To meet this demand, the taxpayer exchanges part of the products at his disposal for coin, which he pays to the tax-gatherers….." ( Say, 1880 ). Eventually, the government spends the money on its own needs, so that "in the end . . . this value is consumed; and then the portion of wealth, which passes from the hands of the taxpayer into those of the tax-gatherer, is destroyed and annihilated." Note, that as in the case of the later Calhoun, Say sees that taxation creates two conflicting classes, the taxpayers and the tax-gatherers. Were it not for taxes, the taxpayer would have spent his money on his own consumption. As it is, "….The state . . . enjoys the satisfaction resulting from that consumption….."( ibid. ). Taxation, then, for Say is the transfer of a portion of the national products from the hands of individuals to those of the government, for the purpose of meeting the public consumption of expenditure.” . . . It is virtually a burthen imposed upon individuals, either in a separate or corporate character, by the ruling power . . . for the purpose of supplying the consumption it may think proper to make at their expense…..”( ibid, p. 446 ). But taxation, for Say, is not merely a zero-sum game. By levying a burden on the producers, he points out, taxes, over time, 'cripple production itself. Writes Say: “…..Taxation deprives the producer of a product, which he would otherwise have the option of deriving a personal gratification from, if consumed . . . or of turning to profit, if he preferred to devote it to an useful employment. . . Therefore, the subtraction of a product must needs diminish, instead of augmenting, productive power……( ibid, p. 447 ). J. B. Say's policy recommendation was crystal clear and consistent with his analysis and that of our VAT treatise: "…..The best scheme of [public] finance is, to spend as little as possible; and the best tax is always the lightest….."( ibid. ,1880 ). To this, there is nothing more to add.


Notes and Reference

  • Kesselman, J., “Public Policies To Combat Child Poverty: Goals and Options,” in A New Social Vision for Canada? Perspectives on the Federal Discussion Paper on Social Policy Reform, Keith Banting and Ken Battle, eds. Queen’s University, School of Policy Studies, Kingston, Ont. 1994, pp. 73-97
  • Kesselman, JGeneral Payroll Taxes: Economics, Politics, and Design, Canadian Tax Foundation Toronto, 1997


  • Rothbard, Murray, “Consumption Tax : A Critique” , Review of Austrian Economics, Volume 7, No. 2, , 1994, pp. 75–90.
  • Rothbard, Murray, Power and Market: Government and the Economy, 2nd ed. Sheed Andrews & McMeel, Kansas City, 1977
  • [1] It is particularly poignant, on or near any April 15, to contemplate the dictum of Father Navarrete, that "the only agreeable country is the one where no one is afraid of tax collectors," Chafuen, Christians for Freedom, p. 73. Also see Murray N. Rothbard, "Review of A. Chafuen, Christians for Freedom: Late Scholastic Economics," International Philosophical Quarterly 28 (March 1988): 112–14. For a fuller treatment, and a discussion of who is being robbed by whom, see Murray N. Rothbard, Power and Market: Government and the Economy, 2nd ed. (Kansas City: Sheed Andrews & McMeel, 1977), pp. 120–21
  • [2] We set aside the fact that, at the lower amount of money assets left to him, Jones's time preference rate, given his time preference schedule, will be higher, so that his consumption will be higher, and his savings lower, than we have assumed.
  • [3] In fact, per note [2], supra, there will be a shift in favor of consumption because a diminished amount of money will shift the taxpayer's time preference rate in the direction of consumption. Hence, paradoxically, a pure tax on consumption will and up taxing savings more than consumption! See Rothbard, Power and Market, pp. 108–11.
  • [4] lf net income is defined as gross income minus amount paid in taxes, and for Jones, consumption is 90 percent of net income, a 20 percent consumption tax on $100,000 income will be tantamount to a 15 percent tax on this income. Rothbard, Power and Market, pp. 108–11. The basic formula is that net income,

where G=gross income, t=the tax rate on consumption, and c, consumption as percent of net income, are givens of the problem, and N = G – T by definition, where T is the amount paid in consumption tax.

  • Say, Jean-Baptiste A Treatise on Political Economy, 6th ed. (Philadelphia: Claxton, Remsen & Heffelfinger, 1880), pp. 412–415, 446; also see Murray N. Rothbard, "The Myth of Neutral Taxation," Cato Journal 1 (Fall 1981): 551–54.


External links


Credits

New World Encyclopedia writers and editors rewrote and completed the Wikipedia article in accordance with New World Encyclopedia standards. This article abides by terms of the Creative Commons CC-by-sa 3.0 License (CC-by-sa), which may be used and disseminated with proper attribution. Credit is due under the terms of this license that can reference both the New World Encyclopedia contributors and the selfless volunteer contributors of the Wikimedia Foundation. To cite this article click here for a list of acceptable citing formats.The history of earlier contributions by wikipedians is accessible to researchers here:

The history of this article since it was imported to New World Encyclopedia:

Note: Some restrictions may apply to use of individual images which are separately licensed.