Difference between revisions of "Historical school of economics" - New World Encyclopedia

From New World Encyclopedia
(Claimed)
(update & fixed)
Line 3: Line 3:
 
{{Claimed}}
 
{{Claimed}}
  
The '''Historical school of economics''' was a mainly [[Germany|German]] school of [[economics|economic]] thought which held that a study of [[history]] was the key source of knowledge about human actions and economic matters, since economics would be [[culture-specific]] and not generalizable over space and time. This was a rejection of the idea that economic [[theorem]]s could be held as universally valid. They saw economics as being the work of rigorous analysis and not of logical philosophy. Characteristic of the historical school is a concern with [[reality]] rather than with [[self-referential]] [[Mathematical model|mathematical modelling]]; most protagonists of the school were also [[Kathedersozialismus|Kathedersozialisten]], i.e. concerned with social reform and the improvement of the masses during the times of heavy [[industrialization]].
+
The '''Historical school of economics''' was an approach to academic [[economics]] and to public administration that emerged in 19th century in [[Germany]], and held sway there until well into the 20th century.
  
==History==
+
The Historical school held that [[history]] was the key source of knowledge about human actions and economic matters, since economics was culture-specific, and hence not generalizable over space and time. The School rejected the universal validity of economic [[theorem]]s. They saw economics as resulting from careful empirical and historical analysis instead of from logic and mathematics. The School also preferred [[reality]], historical, political, and social as well as economic, to [[self-referential]] [[Mathematical model|mathematical modelling]]. Most members of the school were also [[Kathedersozialismus|Kathedersozialisten]], i.e. concerned with social reform and improved conditions for the common man during a period of heavy [[industrialization]]. 
The Historical School can be divided into three sequences:
+
 
 +
The Historical School can be divided into three tendencies:
 
* the Older, led by [[Wilhelm Roscher]], [[Karl Knies]], and [[Bruno Hildebrand]];
 
* the Older, led by [[Wilhelm Roscher]], [[Karl Knies]], and [[Bruno Hildebrand]];
* the Younger, led by [[Gustav von Schmoller]], and also including [[Etienne Laspeyres]], [[Karl Bücher]], and to some extent [[Lujo Brentano]]; and
+
* the Younger, led by [[Gustav von Schmoller]], and also including [[Etienne Laspeyres]], [[Karl Bücher]], and to some extent [[Lujo Brentano]];
 
* the Youngest, led by [[Werner Sombart]] and including, to a very large extent, [[Max Weber]].
 
* the Youngest, led by [[Werner Sombart]] and including, to a very large extent, [[Max Weber]].
  
The Historical School was involved in the [[Methodenstreit]] (method war) with the [[Austrian School]]. The German historical school largely controlled academia in Germany, as many of the advisors of [[Friedrich Althoff]], head of the university department in the [[Prussia|Prussian]] Ministry of Education from [[1882]] to [[1907]]. Prussia was the intellectual powerhouse of Germany and so dominated academia throughout the German speaking world, but also in the [[United States]] until about [[1900]], where the economics profession was led by men who had studied in Germany.
+
The Historical school largely controlled appointments to Chairs of Economics in German universities, as many of the advisors of [[Friedrich Althoff]], head of the university department in the [[Prussia|Prussian]] Ministry of Education 1882-1907, had studied under members of the School. Moreover, Prussia was the intellectual powerhouse of Germany and so dominated academia, not only in central Europe, but also in the [[United States]] until about 1900, because the American economics profession was led by holders of German Ph.Ds. The Historical school was involved in the [[Methodenstreit]] ("strife over method") with the [[Austrian School]], whose orientation was more theoretical and a prioristic.
  
The Historical School is perhaps the most abused theory in the [[history of economic thought]], because it fits so badly with the now completely-dominating Anglo-American view(s); it is perhaps also the school that is the least known in English-speaking countries. And yet, clearly it is the Historical School which forms the basis - both theoretically and factually - of the [[social market economy]] which is dominant in almost all countries of [[Europe]], as well as of all dynamic, change-oriented and especially [[innovation]]-based economics (through the transmission of [[Joseph Schumpeter]], who in spite of criticism of the School was, especially in his innovation-focused work, building on von Schmoller and Sombart).
+
In English speaking countries, the Historical school is perhaps the least known and least understood approach to the [[history of economic thought|study of economics]], because it differs radically from the now-dominant Anglo-American analytical point of view. Yet the Historical school forms the basis - both in theory and in practice - of the [[social market economy]], for many decades the dominant economic paradigm in most countries of continental [[Europe]]. The Historical school is also a source of [[Joseph Schumpeter]]'s dynamic, change-oriented, and [[innovation]]-based economics. Although his writings could be critical of the School, Schumpeter's work on the role of innovation and entrepreneurship can be seen as a continuation of ideas originated by the Historical School, especially the work of von Schmoller and Sombart.
  
==English Historical School==
+
Although not nearly as famous as its German counterpart, there was also an [[English historical school of economics|English Historical School]], whose figures included [[Francis Bacon]], [[Auguste Comte]], and [[Herbert Spencer]]. It was this school that heavily critiqued the deductive approach of the classical economists, especially the writings of [[David Ricardo]]. This school revered the inductive process and called for the merging of historical fact with those of the present period. Included in this school are: [[William Whewell]], [[Richard Jones (economist)|Richard Jones]], [[Walter Bagehot]], [[Thorold Rogers]], [[Arnold Toynbee]], and [[William Cunningham]] just to name a few.  
Although not nearly as famous, there was also an English Historical School. This school was highly influenced by the likes of [[Francis Bacon]], [[Auguste Comte]], and [[Herbert Spencer]].It was this school that heavily critiqued the deductive nature of the classical economists, with several of the thinkers associated with this school selecting [[David Ricardo]] as the focus of their attack. This school revered the inductive process and called for the merging of historical fact with those of the present period. Included in this school are: [[William Whewell]], [[Richard Jones (economist)|Richard Jones]], [[Walter Bagehot]], [[Arnold Toynbee]], and [[William Cunningham]] just to name a few.  
 
  
 
==Important books on the HSE in English:==
 
==Important books on the HSE in English:==
Line 38: Line 38:
 
*[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/frenchist.htm French Historic School]
 
*[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/frenchist.htm French Historic School]
  
+
 
{{Credit1|Historical_school_of_economics|67920418|}}
+
 
 +
 
 +
 
 +
{{Credits|Historical_school_of_economics|130004226|}}

Revision as of 20:40, 9 July 2007


The Historical school of economics was an approach to academic economics and to public administration that emerged in 19th century in Germany, and held sway there until well into the 20th century.

The Historical school held that history was the key source of knowledge about human actions and economic matters, since economics was culture-specific, and hence not generalizable over space and time. The School rejected the universal validity of economic theorems. They saw economics as resulting from careful empirical and historical analysis instead of from logic and mathematics. The School also preferred reality, historical, political, and social as well as economic, to self-referential mathematical modelling. Most members of the school were also Kathedersozialisten, i.e. concerned with social reform and improved conditions for the common man during a period of heavy industrialization.

The Historical School can be divided into three tendencies:

  • the Older, led by Wilhelm Roscher, Karl Knies, and Bruno Hildebrand;
  • the Younger, led by Gustav von Schmoller, and also including Etienne Laspeyres, Karl Bücher, and to some extent Lujo Brentano;
  • the Youngest, led by Werner Sombart and including, to a very large extent, Max Weber.

The Historical school largely controlled appointments to Chairs of Economics in German universities, as many of the advisors of Friedrich Althoff, head of the university department in the Prussian Ministry of Education 1882-1907, had studied under members of the School. Moreover, Prussia was the intellectual powerhouse of Germany and so dominated academia, not only in central Europe, but also in the United States until about 1900, because the American economics profession was led by holders of German Ph.Ds. The Historical school was involved in the Methodenstreit ("strife over method") with the Austrian School, whose orientation was more theoretical and a prioristic.

In English speaking countries, the Historical school is perhaps the least known and least understood approach to the study of economics, because it differs radically from the now-dominant Anglo-American analytical point of view. Yet the Historical school forms the basis - both in theory and in practice - of the social market economy, for many decades the dominant economic paradigm in most countries of continental Europe. The Historical school is also a source of Joseph Schumpeter's dynamic, change-oriented, and innovation-based economics. Although his writings could be critical of the School, Schumpeter's work on the role of innovation and entrepreneurship can be seen as a continuation of ideas originated by the Historical School, especially the work of von Schmoller and Sombart.

Although not nearly as famous as its German counterpart, there was also an English Historical School, whose figures included Francis Bacon, Auguste Comte, and Herbert Spencer. It was this school that heavily critiqued the deductive approach of the classical economists, especially the writings of David Ricardo. This school revered the inductive process and called for the merging of historical fact with those of the present period. Included in this school are: William Whewell, Richard Jones, Walter Bagehot, Thorold Rogers, Arnold Toynbee, and William Cunningham just to name a few.

Important books on the HSE in English:

  • Bücher, Karl (1927). Industrial Evolution. 6th ed. New York, NY: Holt.
  • Backhaus, Jürgen G. (1994), ed. Gustav Schmoller and the Problems of Today = History of Economic Ideas, vol.s I/1993/3, II/1994/1.
  • Backhaus, Jürgen G. (1997), ed. Essays in Social Security and Taxation. Gustav von Schmoller and Adolph Wagner Reconsidered. Marburg: Metropolis.
  • Backhaus, Jürgen G. (2000), ed. Karl Bücher: Theory - History - Anthropology - Non Market Economies. Marburg: Metropolis.
  • Balabkins, Nicholas W. (1988). Not by theory alone...: The Economics of Gustav von Schmoller and Its Legacy to America. Berlin: Duncker & Humblot.
  • Chang, Ha-Joon (2002). Kicking Away the Ladder. Development Strategy in Historical Perspective. London: Anthem.
  • Hodgson, Geoffrey M. (2001). How economics forgot history. The problem of historical specificity in social science. London – New York: Routledge.
  • Roscher, Wilhelm (1878). Principles of Political Economy. 2 vols. From the 13th (1877) German edition. Chicago: Callaghan.
  • Seligman, Edwin A. (1925). Essays in Economics. New York: Macmillan.
  • Shionoya, Yuichi (2001), ed. The German Historical School: The Historical and Ethical Approach to Economics. London etc.: Routledge.
  • Tribe, Keith (1988) "Governing Economy. The Reformation of German Economic Discourse" (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
  • Tribe, Keith (1995) "Strategies of Economic Order. German Economic Discourse 1750-1950" (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press) (Republished 2006)

External links


Credits

New World Encyclopedia writers and editors rewrote and completed the Wikipedia article in accordance with New World Encyclopedia standards. This article abides by terms of the Creative Commons CC-by-sa 3.0 License (CC-by-sa), which may be used and disseminated with proper attribution. Credit is due under the terms of this license that can reference both the New World Encyclopedia contributors and the selfless volunteer contributors of the Wikimedia Foundation. To cite this article click here for a list of acceptable citing formats.The history of earlier contributions by wikipedians is accessible to researchers here:

The history of this article since it was imported to New World Encyclopedia:

Note: Some restrictions may apply to use of individual images which are separately licensed.